Respondent, a private utility that is the sole supplier of
electricity in southeastern Michigan, also furnishes its
residential customers, without additional charge, with almost 50%
of the most frequently used standard-size light bulbs under a
longstanding practice antedating state regulation of electric
utilities. This marketing practice for light bulbs is approved, as
part of respondent's rate structure, by the Michigan Public Service
Commission, and may not be changed unless and until respondent
files, and the Commission approves, a new tariff. Petitioner, a
retail druggist selling light bulbs, brought an action against
respondent, claiming that it was using its monopoly power in the
distribution of electricity to restrain competition in the sale of
light bulbs in violation of the Sherman Act. The District Court
entered a summary judgment against petitioner, holding on the
authority of
Parker v. Brown, 317 U.
S. 341, that the Commission's approval of respondent's
light bulb marketing practices exempted the practices from the
federal antitrust laws, and the Court of Appeals affirmed.
Held: Neither Michigan's approval of respondent's
present tariff nor the fact that the light bulb exchange program
may not be terminated until a new tariff is filed, is sufficient
basis for implying an exemption from the federal antitrust laws for
that program. Pp.
428 U. S.
592-598.
(a) The State's participation in the decision to have a light
bulb exchange program is not so dominant that it is unfair to hold
a private party responsible for its conduct in implementing the
decision, but rather the respondent's participation in the decision
is sufficiently significant to require that its conduct, like
comparable conduct by unregulated businesses, conform to applicable
federal law. Pp.
428 U. S.
592-595.
(b) Michigan's regulation of respondent's distribution of
electricity poses no necessary conflict with a federal requirement
that respondent's activities in competitive markets satisfy
antitrust
Page 428 U. S. 580
standards. Merely because certain conduct may be subject to
state regulation and to the federal antitrust laws does not
necessarily mean that it must satisfy inconsistent standards, but,
even assuming inconsistency, this would not mean that the federal
interest must inevitably be subordinated to the State's; moreover,
even assuming that Congress did not intend the antitrust laws to
apply to areas of the economy primarily regulated by a State, the
enforcement of the antitrust laws would not be foreclosed in an
essentially unregulated area such as the electric light bulb
market. Pp.
428 U. S.
595-598.
513 F.2d 630, reversed and remanded.
STEVENS, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
BRENNAN, WHITE, and MARSHALL, JJ., joined, and in which (except as
to Parts II and IV) BURGER, C.J., joined. BURGER, C.J., filed an
opinion concurring in the judgment, and concurring in part,
post, p.
428 U. S. 603.
BLACKMUN, J., filed an opinion concurring in the judgment,
post, p.
428 U. S. 605.
STEWART, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which POWELL and
REHNQUIST, JJ., joined,
post, p.
428 U. S.
614.
Page 428 U. S. 581
MR. JUSTICE STEVENS delivered the opinion of the Court.
*
In
Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341, the
Court held that the Sherman Act was not violated by state action
displacing competition in the marketing of raisins. In this case,
we must decide whether the
Parker rationale immunizes
private action which has been approved by a State and which must be
continued while the state approval remains effective.
The Michigan Public Service Commission pervasively regulates the
distribution of electricity within the State, and also has given
its approval to a marketing practice which has a substantial impact
on the otherwise unregulated business of distributing electric
light bulbs. Assuming,
arguendo, that the approved
practice has unreasonably restrained trade in the light bulb
market, the District Court [
Footnote 1] and the Court of Appeals [
Footnote 2] held, on the authority of
Parker, that the Commission's approval exempted the
practice from the federal antitrust laws. Because we questioned the
applicability of
Parker to this situation, we granted
certiorari, 423 U.S. 821. We now reverse.
Petitioner, a retail druggist selling light bulbs, claims that
respondent is using its monopoly power in the distribution of
electricity to restrain competition in the sale of bulbs in
violation of the Sherman Act. [
Footnote 3] Discovery
Page 428 U. S. 582
and argument in connection with defendant's motion for summary
judgment were limited by stipulation to the issue raised by the
Commission's approval of respondent's light bulb exchange program.
We state only the facts pertinent to that issue, and assume,
without opining, that, without such approval, an antitrust
violation would exist. To the extent that the facts are disputed,
we must resolve doubts in favor of the petitioner, since summary
judgment was entered against him. We first describe respondent's
"lamp exchange program," we next discuss the holding in
Parker
v. Brown, and then we consider whether that holding should be
extended to cover this case. Finally, we comment briefly on
additional authorities on which respondent relies.
I
Respondent, the Detroit Edison Co., distributes electricity and
electric light bulbs to about five million people in southeastern
Michigan. In this marketing area, respondent is the sole supplier
of electricity, and supplies consumers with almost 50% of the
standard-size light bulbs they use most frequently. [
Footnote 4] Customers are billed for the
electricity they consume, but pay no separate charge for light
bulbs. Respondent's rates, including the omission of any separate
charge for bulbs, have been approved by the Michigan Public Service
Commission, and may not be changed without the Commission's
approval. Respondent must, therefore, continue
Page 428 U. S. 583
its lamp exchange program until it files a new tariff and that
new tariff is approved by the Commission.
Respondent, or a predecessor, has been following the practice of
providing limited amounts of light bulbs to its customers without
additional charge since 1886. [
Footnote 5] In 1909, the State of Michigan began
regulation of electric utilities. [
Footnote 6] In 1916, the Michigan Public Service
Commission first approved a tariff filed by respondent setting
forth the lamp supply program. Thereafter, the Commission's
approval of respondent's tariffs has included implicit approval of
the lamp exchange program. In 1964, the Commission also approved
respondent's decision to eliminate the program for large commercial
customers. [
Footnote 7] The
elimination of the service for such customers became effective as
part of a general rate reduction for those customers.
In 1972, respondent provided its residential customers with
18,564,381 bulbs at a cost of $2,835,000. [
Footnote 8] In its accounting to the Michigan Public
Service Commission, respondent included this amount as a portion of
its cost of providing service to its customers. Respondent's
accounting records reflect no direct profit as a result of the
Page 428 U. S. 584
distribution of bulbs. The purpose of the program, according to
respondent's executives, is to increase the consumption of
electricity. The effect of the program, according to petitioner, is
to foreclose competition in a substantial segment of the light bulb
market. [
Footnote 9]
The distribution of electricity in Michigan is pervasively
regulated by the Michigan Public Service Commission. A Michigan
statute [
Footnote 10] vests
the Commission with "complete power and jurisdiction to regulate
all public utilities in the state. . . ." The statute confers
express power on the Commission
"to regulate all rates, fares, fees, charges, services, rules,
conditions of service, and all other matters pertaining to the
formation, operation, or direction of such public utilities."
Respondent advises us that the heart of the Commission's
function is to regulate the "
furnishing . . . [of] electricity
for the production of light, heat or power. . . .'" [Footnote 11]
The distribution of electric light bulbs in Michigan is
unregulated. The statute creating the Commission contains no direct
reference to light bulbs. Nor, as far as we have been advised, does
any other Michigan statute authorize the regulation of that
business. Neither the Michigan Legislature nor the Commission has
ever made any specific investigation of the desirability of a lamp
exchange program or of its possible effect on competition in the
light bulb market. Other utilities regulated by the Michigan Public
Service Commission do not follow the practice of providing bulbs to
their customers at no
Page 428 U. S. 585
additional charge. The Commission's approval of respondent's
decision to maintain such a program does not, therefore, implement
any state-wide policy relating to light bulbs. We infer that the
State's policy is neutral on the question whether a utility should,
or should not, have such a program.
Although there is no statute, Commission rule, or policy which
would prevent respondent from abandoning the program merely by
filing a new tariff providing for a proper adjustment in its rates,
it is nevertheless apparent that, while the existing tariff remains
in effect, respondent may not abandon the program without violating
a Commission order, and therefore without violating state law. It
has, therefore, been permitted by the Commission to carry out the
program, and also is required to continue to do so until an
appropriate filing has been made and has received the approval of
the Commission.
Petitioner has not named any public official as a party to this
litigation, and has made no claim that any representative of the
State of Michigan has acted unlawfully.
II
In
Parker v. Brown, the Court considered whether the
Sherman Act applied to state action. The way the Sherman Act
question was presented and argued in that case sheds significant
light on the character of the state action concept embraced by the
Parker holding.
The plaintiff, Brown, was a producer and packer of raisins; the
defendants were the California Director of Agriculture and other
public officials charged by California statute with responsibility
for administering a program for the marketing of the 1940 crop of
raisins. The express purpose of the program was to restrict
competition among the growers and maintain prices in the
distribution
Page 428 U. S. 586
of raisins to packers. [
Footnote 12] Nevertheless, in the District Court, Brown
did not argue that the defendants had violated the Sherman Act. He
sought an injunction against the enforcement of the program on the
theory that it interfered with his constitutional right to engage
in interstate commerce. Because he was attacking the
constitutionality of a California statute and regulations having
state-wide applicability, a three-judge District Court was
convened. [
Footnote 13] With
one judge dissenting, the District Court held that the program
violated the Commerce Clause, and granted injunctive relief.
[
Footnote 14]
The defendant state officials took a direct appeal to this
Court. Probable jurisdiction was noted on April 6, 1942, and the
Court heard oral argument on the Commerce
Page 428 U. S. 587
Clause issue on May 5, 1942. In the meantime, on April 27, 1942,
the Court held that the State of Georgia is a "person" within the
meaning of § 7 of the Sherman Act, and therefore entitled to
maintain an action for treble damages.
Georgia v. Evans,
316 U. S. 159.
Presumably because the Court was then concerned with the
relationship between the sovereign States and the antitrust laws,
it immediately set
Parker v. Brown for reargument,
[
Footnote 15] and, on its
own motion, requested the Solicitor General of the United States to
file a brief as
amicus curiae and directed the parties to
discuss the question whether the California statute was rendered
invalid by the Sherman Act. [
Footnote 16]
In his supplemental brief, the Attorney General of
Page 428 U. S. 588
California [
Footnote 17]
advanced three arguments against using the Sherman Act as a basis
for upholding the injunction entered by the District Court. He
contended (1) that even though a State is a "person" entitled to
maintain a treble damage action as a plaintiff, Congress never
intended to subject a sovereign State to the provisions of the
Sherman Act; (2) that the California program did not, in any event,
violate the federal statute; and (3) that, since no evidence or
argument pertaining to the Sherman Act had been offered or
considered in the District Court, the injunction should not be
sustained on an antitrust theory. [
Footnote 18]
In his brief for the United States as
amicus curiae,
the Solicitor General did not take issue with the appellants' first
argument. He contended that the California program was inconsistent
with the policy of the Sherman Act, but expressly disclaimed any
argument that the State of California or its officials had violated
federal law. [
Footnote 19]
Later in his brief, the Solicitor General drew an
Page 428 U. S. 589
important distinction between economic action taken by the State
itself and private action taken pursuant to a state statute
permitting or requiring individuals to engage in conduct prohibited
by the Sherman Act. The Solicitor General contended that the
private conduct would clearly be illegal, but recognized that a
different problem existed with respect to the State itself.
[
Footnote 20] It was the
latter problem that was presented in the
Parker case.
This Court set aside the injunction entered by the District
Court. In the portion of his opinion for the Court discussing the
Sherman Act issue, Mr. Chief Justice Stone addressed only the first
of the three arguments advanced by the California Attorney General.
The Court held that, even though comparable programs organized by
private persons would be illegal, the action taken by state
officials pursuant to express legislative command did not violate
the Sherman Act. [
Footnote
21]
Page 428 U. S. 590
This narrow holding made it unnecessary for the Court to agree
or to disagree with the Solicitor General's view that a state
statute permitting or requiring private conduct prohibited by
federal law "would clearly be void." [
Footnote 22] The Court's narrow holding also avoided any
question about the applicability of the antitrust laws to private
action taken under color of state law.
Unquestionably the term "state action" may be used broadly to
encompass individual action supported to some extent by state law
or custom. Such a broad use of the term, which is familiar in civil
rights litigation, [
Footnote
23] is not,
Page 428 U. S. 591
however, what Mr. Chief Justice Stone described in his
Parker opinion. He carefully selected language which
plainly limited the Court's holding to official action taken by
state officials. [
Footnote
24]
In this case, unlike
Parker, the only defendant is a
private utility. No public officials or agencies are named as
parties, and there is no claim that any state action violated the
antitrust laws. Conversely, in
Parker, there was no claim
that any private citizen or company had violated the law. The only
Sherman Act issue decided was whether the sovereign State itself,
which had been held to be a person within the meaning of § 7 of the
statute, was also subject to its prohibitions. Since the case now
before us does not call into question the legality of any
Page 428 U. S. 592
act of the State of Michigan or any of its officials or agents,
it is not controlled by the
Parker decision.
III
In this case, we are asked to hold that private conduct required
by state law is exempt from the Sherman Act. Two quite different
reasons might support such a rule. First, if a private citizen has
done nothing more than obey the command of his state sovereign, it
would be unjust to conclude that he has thereby offended federal
law. Second, if the State is already regulating an area of the
economy, it is arguable that Congress did not intend to superimpose
the antitrust laws as an additional, and perhaps conflicting,
regulatory mechanism. We consider these two reasons separately.
We may assume,
arguendo, that it would be unacceptable
ever to impose statutory liability on a party who had done nothing
more than obey a state command. Such an assumption would not decide
this case, if, indeed, it would decide any actual case. For
typically cases of this kind involve a blend of private and public
decisionmaking. [
Footnote
25] The Court has already decided that state authorization,
[
Footnote 26] approval,
[
Footnote 27] encouragement,
[
Footnote 28] or
Page 428 U. S. 593
participation [
Footnote
29] in restrictive private conduct confers no antitrust
immunity. And in
Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Corp.,
341 U. S. 384, the
Court invalidated the plaintiff's entire resale price maintenance
program even though it was effective throughout the State only
because the Louisiana statute imposed a direct restraint on
retailers who had not signed fair trade agreements. [
Footnote 30]
In each of these cases, the initiation and enforcement of the
program under attack involved a mixture of private and public
decisionmaking. In each case, notwithstanding the state
participation in the decision, the private party exercised
sufficient freedom of choice to enable the Court to conclude that
he should be held responsible for the consequences of his
decision.
The case before us also discloses a program which is the product
of a decision in which both the respondent and the
Page 428 U. S. 594
Commission participated. Respondent could not maintain the lamp
exchange program without the approval of the Commission, and now
may not abandon it without such approval. Nevertheless, there can
be no doubt that the option to have, or not to have, such a program
is primarily respondent's, not the Commission's. [
Footnote 31] Indeed, respondent initiated
the program years before the regulatory agency was even created.
There is nothing unjust in a conclusion that respondent's
participation in the decision is sufficiently significant to
require that its conduct implementing the decision, like comparable
conduct by unregulated businesses, conform to applicable federal
law. [
Footnote 32]
Accordingly, even though there may be cases in which the State's
participation in a decision is so dominant
Page 428 U. S. 595
that it would be unfair to hold a private party responsible for
his conduct in implementing it, this record discloses no such
unfairness.
Apart from the question of fairness to the individual who must
conform not only to state regulation, but to the federal antitrust
laws as well, we must consider whether Congress intended to
superimpose antitrust standards on conduct already being regulated
under a different standard.
Amici curiae forcefully
contend that the competitive standard imposed by antitrust
legislation is fundamentally inconsistent with the "public
interest" standard widely enforced by regulatory agencies, and that
the essential teaching of
Parker v. Brown is that the
federal antitrust laws should not be applied in areas of the
economy pervasively regulated by state agencies.
There are at least three reasons why this argument is
unacceptable. First, merely because certain conduct may be subject
both to state regulation and to the federal antitrust laws does not
necessarily mean that it must satisfy inconsistent standards;
second, even assuming inconsistency, we could not accept the view
that the federal interest must inevitably be subordinated to the
State's; and finally, even if we were to assume that Congress did
not intend the antitrust laws to apply to areas of the economy
primarily regulated by a State, that assumption would not foreclose
the enforcement of the antitrust laws in an essentially unregulated
area such as the market for electric light bulbs.
Unquestionably there are examples of economic regulation in
which the very purpose of the government control is to avoid the
consequences of unrestrained competition. Agricultural marketing
programs, such as that involved in
Parker, were of that
character. But all economic regulation does not necessarily
suppress competition. On the contrary, public utility regulation
typically
Page 428 U. S. 596
assumes that the private firm is a natural monopoly, and that
public controls are necessary to protect the consumer from
exploitation. [
Footnote 33]
There is no logical inconsistency between requiring such a firm to
meet regulatory criteria insofar as it is exercising its natural
monopoly powers and also to comply with antitrust standards to the
extent that it engages in business activity in competitive areas of
the economy. [
Footnote 34]
Thus, Michigan's regulation of respondent's distribution of
electricity poses no necessary conflict with a federal requirement
that respondent's activities in competitive markets satisfy
antitrust standards. [
Footnote
35]
The mere possibility of conflict between state regulatory policy
and federal antitrust policy is an insufficient basis for implying
an exemption from the federal antitrust laws. Congress could hardly
have intended state regulatory agencies to have broader power than
federal agencies to exempt private conduct from the antitrust laws.
[
Footnote 36] Therefore,
assuming that there are situations in
Page 428 U. S. 597
which the existence of state regulation should give rise to an
implied exemption, the standards for ascertaining the existence and
scope of such an exemption surely must be at least as severe as
those applied to federal regulatory legislation.
The Court has consistently refused to find that regulation gave
rise to an implied exemption without first determining that
exemption was necessary in order to make the regulatory Act work,
"and, even then, only to the minimum extent necessary." [
Footnote 37]
Page 428 U. S. 598
The application of that standard to this case inexorably
requires rejection of respondent's claim. For Michigan's regulatory
scheme does not conflict with federal antitrust policy and,
conversely, if the federal antitrust laws should be construed to
outlaw respondent's light bulb exchange program, there is no reason
to believe that Michigan's regulation of its electric utilities
will no longer be able to function effectively. Regardless of the
outcome of this case, Michigan's interest in regulating its
utilities' distribution of electricity will be almost entirely
unimpaired.
We conclude that neither Michigan's approval of the tariff filed
by respondent nor the fact that the lamp exchange program may not
be terminated until a new tariff is filed is a sufficient basis for
implying an exemption from the federal antitrust laws for that
program. [
Footnote 38]
IV
The dissenting opinion voices the legitimate concern that
violation of the antitrust laws by regulated companies may give
rise to "massive treble damage liabilities." This is an
oft-repeated criticism of the inevitably
Page 428 U. S. 599
imprecise language of the Sherman Act and of the consequent
difficulty in predicting with certainty its application to various
specific fact situations. [
Footnote 39] The far-reaching value of this basic part of
our law, however, has enabled it to withstand such criticism in the
past. [
Footnote 40]
The concern about treble damages liability has arguable
relevance to this case in two ways. If the hazard of violating the
antitrust laws were enhanced by the fact of regulation, or if a
regulated company had engaged in anticompetitive conduct in
reliance on a justified understanding that such conduct was immune
from the antitrust laws, a concern with the punitive aspects of the
treble damages remedy would be appropriate. But neither of those
circumstances is present in this case.
When regulation merely takes the form of approval of a tariff
proposed by the company, it surely has not increased the company's
risk of violating the law. The
Page 428 U. S. 600
respondent utility maintained its lamp exchange program both
before and after it was regulated. The approval of the program by
the Michigan Commission provided the company with an arguable
defense to the antitrust charge, but did not increase its exposure
to liability.
Nor can the utility fairly claim that it was led to believe that
its conduct was exempt from the federal antitrust laws. A claim of
immunity or exemption is in the nature of an affirmative defense to
conduct which is otherwise assumed to be unlawful. This Court has
never sustained a claim that otherwise unlawful private conduct is
exempt from the antitrust laws because it was permitted or required
by state law.
In the Court's most recent consideration of this subject, it
described the defendant's claim with pointed precision as "this
so-called state action exemption."
Goldfarb v. Virginia State
Bar, 421 U. S. 773,
421 U. S. 788.
The Court then explained that the question whether the
anticompetitive activity had been required by the State acting as
sovereign was the "threshold inquiry" in determining whether it was
state action of the type the Sherman Act was not meant to
proscribe. [
Footnote 41]
Certainly that careful use of language could not have been read as
a guarantee that compliance with any state requirement would
automatically confer federal antitrust immunity.
The dissenting opinion in this case makes much of the obvious
fact that
Parker v. Brown implicitly held that
California's raisin marketing program was not a violation of the
Sherman Act. That is, of course, perfectly
Page 428 U. S. 601
true. But the only way the legality of any program may be tested
under the Sherman Act is by determining whether the persons who
administer it have acted lawfully. The federal statute proscribes
the conduct of persons, not programs, and the narrow holding in
Parker concerned only the legality of the conduct of the
state officials charged by law with the responsibility for
administering California's program. What sort of charge might have
been made against the various private persons who engaged in a
variety of different activities implementing that program is
unknown and unknowable, because no such charges were made.
[
Footnote 42] Even if the
state program had been held unlawful, such a holding would not
necessarily have supported a claim that private individuals who had
merely conformed their conduct to an invalid program had thereby
violated the Sherman Act. Unless and until a court answered that
question, there would be no occasion to consider an affirmative
defense of immunity or exemption.
Nor could respondent justifiably rely on either the holding in
Eastern R. Conf. v. Noerr Motors, 365 U.
S. 127, or the reference in that opinion to
Parker. [
Footnote
43] The holding in
Noerr was that the concerted
activities of the railroad defendants in opposing legislation
favorable to the plaintiff motor carriers was not prohibited by the
Sherman Act. The case did not involve any question of either
liability or exemption for private action taken in compliance with
state law.
Moreover, nothing in the
Noerr opinion implies that
Page 428 U. S. 602
the mere fact that a state regulatory agency may approve a
proposal included in a tariff, and thereby require that the
proposal be implemented until a revised tariff is filed and
approved, is a sufficient reason for conferring antitrust immunity
on the proposed conduct. The passage quoted in the dissent,
post at
428 U. S. 622,
sets up an assumed dichotomy between a restraint imposed by
governmental action, as contrasted with one imposed by private
action, and then cites
United States v. Rock Royal Co-op.,
307 U. S. 533, and
Parker for the conclusion that the former does not violate
the Sherman Act. [
Footnote
44] That passing reference to
Parker sheds no light on
the significance of state action which amounts to little more than
approval of a private proposal. It surely does not qualify the
categorical statement in
Parker that
"a state does not give immunity to those who violate the Sherman
Act by authorizing them to violate it, or by declaring that their
action is lawful."
317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 351.
Yet the dissent would allow every state agency to grant precisely
that immunity by merely including a direction to engage in the
proposed conduct in an approval order. [
Footnote 45]
Page 428 U. S. 603
MR. JUSTICE STEWART's separate opinion possesses a virtue which
ours does not. It announces a simple rule that can easily be
applied in any case in which a state regulatory agency approves a
proposal and orders a regulated company to comply with it. No
matter what the impact of the proposal on interstate commerce, and
no matter how peripheral or casual the State's interests may be in
permitting it to go into effect, the state act would confer
immunity from treble damages liability. Such a rule is supported by
the wholesome interest in simplicity in the regulation of a complex
economy. In our judgment, however, that interest is heavily
outweighed by the fact that such a rule may give a host of state
regulatory agencies broad power to grant exemptions from an
important federal law for reasons wholly unrelated either to
federal policy or even to any necessary significant state interest.
Although it is tempting to try to fashion a rule which would govern
the decision of the liability issue and the damages issue in all
future cases presenting state action issues, we believe the Court
should adhere to its settled policy of giving concrete meaning to
the general language of the Sherman Act by a process of
case-by-case adjudication of specific controversies.
Since the District Court has not yet addressed the question
whether the complaint alleged a violation of the antitrust laws,
the case is remanded for a determination of that question and for
such other proceedings as may be appropriate.
Reversed and remanded.
* Parts II and IV of this opinion are joined only by MR. JUSTICE
BRENNAN, MR. JUSTICE WHITE, and MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL.
[
Footnote 1]
392 F.
Supp. 1110 (ED Mich.1974).
[
Footnote 2]
513 F.2d 630 (CA6 1975).
[
Footnote 3]
Petitioner's complaint asserts that respondent's light bulb
exchange program violates § 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2,
and § 3 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 14. In his brief in this
Court, petitioner has also argued that the program constitutes
unlawful tying violative of § 1 of the Sherman Act. The complaint
seeks treble damages and an injunction permanently enjoining
respondent from requiring the purchase of bulbs in connection with
the sale of electrical energy. The complaint purports to be filed
on behalf of all persons similarly situated, but the record
contains no indication that the plaintiff moved for a class
determination pursuant to Fed.Rule Civ.Proc. 23(c).
[
Footnote 4]
Respondent does not distribute fluorescent lights or
high-intensity discharge lamps; if bulbs of those types were
included, respondent's share of the market would only be about
23%.
[
Footnote 5]
Under respondent's practice, new residential customers are
provided with bulbs in "such quantities as may be needed" for all
of their permanent fixtures; thereafter, respondent replaces
residential customers' burned out light bulbs in proportion to
their estimated use of electricity for lighting. The customer
incurs no direct charge for such bulbs at the time they are
furnished to him, but normally turns in any burned-out bulbs to
obtain a new supply.
[
Footnote 6]
See Mich.Comp.Laws §§ 460.551, 460.559 (1970).
[
Footnote 7]
Apparently, many commercial customers use relatively large
quantities of fluorescent lighting, and therefore have less
interest in the bulb exchange program.
[
Footnote 8]
Of this amount, $2,363,328 was paid to the three principal
manufacturers of bulbs from whom respondent made its purchases; the
other $471,672 represented costs incurred in the use of
respondent's personnel and facilities in carrying out the
program.
[
Footnote 9]
According to respondent, the effect of the program is to save
consumers about $3 million a year, since the bulbs they now receive
at a cost of $2,835,000 would cost them about $6 million in the
retail market.
[
Footnote 10]
Mich.Comp.Laws § 460.6 (1970).
[
Footnote 11]
See Brief for Respondent 11; Mich.Comp.Laws § 460.501
(1970).
[
Footnote 12]
"The California Agricultural Prorate Act authorizes the
establishment, through action of state officials, of programs for
the marketing of agricultural commodities produced in the state, so
as to restrict competition among the growers and maintain prices in
the distribution of their commodities to packers. The declared
purpose of the Act is to 'conserve the agricultural wealth of the
State' and to 'prevent economic waste in the marketing of
agricultural products' of the state."
317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
346.
"The declared objective of the California Act is to prevent
excessive supplies of agricultural commodities from 'adversely
affecting' the market, and although the statute speaks in terms of
'economic stability' and 'agricultural waste,' rather than of
price, the evident purpose and effect of the regulation is to
'conserve agricultural wealth of the state' by raising and
maintaining prices, but 'without permitting unreasonable profits to
producers.' § 10."
Id. at
317 U. S.
355.
[
Footnote 13]
Title 28 U.S.C. § 2281 has been consistently read by this Court
as authorizing a three-judge court only when the state statute
which is sought to be enjoined is of a general and state-wide
application.
Moody v. Flowers, 387 U. S.
97,
387 U. S.
101.
[
Footnote 14]
Article I, § 8, cl. 3, of the United States Constitution
provides:
"Congress shall have Power . . . To regulate Commerce with
foreign Nations, and among the several States, and with the Indian
Tribes. . . ."
[
Footnote 15]
The Court also asked the parties to consider whether the
Agricultural Adjustment Act, as amended, or any other Act of
Congress, invalidated the California program. The supplemental
briefs noted that the California program had been adopted with the
collaboration of officials of the United States Department of
Agriculture, and had been aided by loans from the Commodity Credit
Corporation recommended by the Secretary of Agriculture. These
facts were emphasized in portions of Mr. Chief Justice Stone's
opinion discussing the Agricultural Adjustment Act and the Commerce
Clause,
see 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 357,
317 U. S.
358-359,
317 U. S. 368,
but were not mentioned in connection with the Court's discussion of
the Sherman Act.
[
Footnote 16]
The first order entered in the Supreme Court Journal on Monday,
May 11, 1942, provided:
"No. 1040.
W. B. Parker, Director of Agriculture, et al.,
appellants, v. Porter L. Brown. This cause is restored to the
docket for reargument on October 12 next. In their briefs and on
the oral argument, counsel for the parties are requested to discuss
the questions whether the state statute involved is rendered
invalid by the action of Congress in passing the Sherman Act, the
Agricultural Adjustment Act, as amended, or any other Act of
Congress. The Solicitor General is requested to file a brief as
amicus curiae, and, if he so desires, to participate in
the oral argument."
Journal, O.T. 1941, p. 252.
[
Footnote 17]
The Honorable Earl Warren, later Chief Justice of the United
States.
[
Footnote 18]
In the index to his supplemental brief, the California Attorney
General outlined his discussion of the Sherman Act in these
words:
The Sherman Anti-Trust law and the California raisin
program . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
1. Is a state subject to the Sherman Act? . . . . . . 35
2. Does the state seasonal program for raisins
violate the provisions of the Sherman Act? . . . 48
(a) The Sherman Act is circumscribed by the
rule of reason. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
(b) Federal legislation as exempting state
program from anti-trust laws. . . . . . . . 60
3. May the California raisin program be enjoined
in the present action?. . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
[
Footnote 19]
At p. 59 of its brief, the Government stated:
"The Sherman Act does not in terms define its scope in so far as
it applies to the activities of state governments. But nothing in
the Act precludes its application to programs sponsored by the
states. Sections 1 and 2 prohibit unlawful conduct by 'persons,'
and the word 'person,' as defined in Section 7, in some connections
at least, may include a state.
Georgia v. Evans,
316 U. S.
159."
"But the question we face here is not whether California or its
officials have violated the Sherman Act, but whether the state
program interferes with the accomplishment of the objectives of the
federal statute."
[
Footnote 20]
At p. 63 of its brief, the Government stated:
"A state statute permitting, or requiring, dealers in a
commodity to combine so as to limit the supply or raise the price
of a subject of interstate Commerce would clearly be void. The
question here is whether a state may itself undertake to control
the supply and price of a commodity shipped in interstate commerce
or otherwise restrain interstate competition through a mandatory
regulation."
[
Footnote 21]
"But it is plain that the prorate program here was never
intended to operate by force of individual agreement or
combination. It derived its authority and its efficacy from the
legislative command of the state, and was not intended to operate
or become effective without that command. We find nothing in the
language of the Sherman Act or in its history which suggests that
its purpose was to restrain a state or its officers or agents from
activities directed by its legislature. In a dual system of
government in which, under the Constitution, the states are
sovereign, save only as Congress may constitutionally subtract from
their authority, an unexpressed purpose to nullify a state's
control over its officers and agents is not lightly to be
attributed to Congress."
"The Sherman Act makes no mention of the state as such, and
gives no hint that it was intended to restrain state action or
official action directed by a state."
"
* * * *"
"There is no suggestion of a purpose to restrain state action in
the Act's legislative history. The sponsor of the bill which was
ultimately enacted as the Sherman Act declared that it prevented
only 'business combinations.' 21 Cong.Rec. 2562, 2457;
see also
[id.] at 2459, 2461. That its purpose was to suppress
combinations to restrain competition and attempts to monopolize by
individuals and corporations abundantly appears from its
legislative history."
"
* * * *"
"The state, in adopting and enforcing the prorate program, made
no contract or agreement, and entered into no conspiracy in
restraint of trade or to establish monopoly, but, as sovereign,
imposed the restraint as an act of government which the Sherman Act
did not undertake to prohibit.
Olsen v. Smith,
195 U. S.
332,
195 U. S. 344-[3]45;
cf.
Lowenstein v. Evans, 69 F. 908, 910."
317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
350-352.
[
Footnote 22]
See n 15,
supra.
[
Footnote 23]
See Monroe v. Pape, 365 U. S. 167,
365 U. S.
172-187;
Adickes v. Kress & Co.,
398 U. S. 144,
398 U. S.
188-234 (BRENNAN, J., concurring in part and dissenting
in part).
[
Footnote 24]
In his three-page discussion of the Sherman Act issue in
Parker v. Brown, Mr Chief Justice Stone made 13 references
to the fact that state action was involved. Each time, his language
was carefully chosen to apply only to official action, as opposed
to private action approved, supported, or even directed by the
State. Thus, his references were to (1) "the legislative command of
the state," and (2) "a state or its officers or agents from
activities directed by its legislature," 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 350;
and to (3) "a state's control over its officers and agents," (4)
"the state as such," (5) "state action or official action directed
by a state," and (6) "state action,"
id. at
317 U. S. 351;
and to (7) "the state command to the Commission and to the program
committee," (8) "state action," (9) "the state which has created
the machinery for establishing the prorate program," (10) "it is
the state, acting through the Commission, which adopts the program
. . . ," (11) "[t]he state itself exercises its legislative
authority," (12) "[t]he state in adopting and enforcing the prorate
program . . ," and finally (13) "as sovereign, imposed the
restraint as an act of government . . . ,"
id. at
317 U. S.
352.
The cumulative effect of these carefully drafted references
unequivocally differentiates between official action, on the one
hand, and individual action (even when commanded by the State), on
the other hand.
[
Footnote 25]
Indeed, in
Parker v. Brown itself, there was
significant private participation in the formulation and
effectuation of the proration program. As the Court pointed out,
approval of the program upon referendum by a prescribed number of
producers was one of the conditions for effectuating the program.
See ibid.
[
Footnote 26]
"It cannot be said that any State may give a corporation,
created under its laws, authority to restrain interstate or
international commerce against the will of the nation as lawfully
expressed by Congress."
Northern Securities Co. v. United States, 193 U.
S. 197,
193 U. S.
346.
[
Footnote 27]
In the
Parker opinion itself, the Court pointed out
that a State does not give immunity to those who violate the
Sherman Act "by declaring that their action is lawful." 317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
351.
[
Footnote 28]
"Respondents' arguments, at most, constitute the contention that
their activities complemented the objective of the ethical codes.
In our view, that is not state action for Sherman Act purposes. It
is not enough that, as the County Bar puts it, anticompetitive
conduct is 'prompted' by state action; rather, anticompetitive
activities must be compelled by direction of the State acting as a
sovereign,"
Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U.
S. 773,
421 U. S.
791.
[
Footnote 29]
See Continental Co. v. Union Carbide, 370 U.
S. 690;
cf. also Union Pacific R. Co. v. United
States, 313 U. S. 450,
cited in
Parker v. Brown, supra at
317 U. S.
352.
[
Footnote 30]
Thus, although the private decision to enforce a state-wide fair
trade program was not only approved by the State, but actually
would have been ineffective without the statutory command to
nonsigners to adhere to the prices set by the plaintiff, the
rationale of
Parker v. Brown did not immunize the
restraint. Quite the contrary, in his opinion for the Court, Mr.
Justice Douglas cited
Parker for the proposition that
private conduct was forbidden by the Sherman Act even though the
State had compelled retailers to follow a parallel price policy. He
said:
"Therefore, when a state compels retailers to follow a parallel
price policy, it demands private conduct which the Sherman Act
forbids.
See Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S.
341,
317 U. S. 350."
341 U.S. at
341 U. S.
389.
[
Footnote 31]
We recently described an analogous exercise of a public
utility's power to make business decisions subject to Commission
approval in
Jackson v. Metropolitan Edison Co.,
419 U. S. 345:
"The nature of governmental regulation of private utilities is
such that a utility may frequently be required by the state
regulatory scheme to obtain approval for practices a business
regulated in less detail would be free to institute without any
approval from a regulatory body. Approval by a state utility
commission of such a request from a regulated utility, where the
Commission has not put its own weight on the side of the proposed
practice by ordering it, does not transmute a practice initiated by
the utility and approved by the Commission into 'state action.' At
most, the Commission's failure to overturn this practice amounted
to no more than a determination that a Pennsylvania utility was
authorized to employ such a practice if it so desired. Respondent's
exercise of the choice allowed by state law where the initiative
comes from it, and not from the State, does not make its action in
doing so 'state action' for purposes of the Fourteenth
Amendment."
Id. at
419 U. S. 357.
(Footnote omitted.)
[
Footnote 32]
Nor is such a conclusion even arguably inconsistent with the
underlying rationale of
Parker v. Brown. For, in that
case, California required every raisin producer in the State to
comply with the proration program, whereas Michigan has never
required any utility to adopt a lamp exchange program.
[
Footnote 33]
As MR. JUSTICE STEWART pointed out in his dissenting opinion in
Otter Tail Power Co. v. United States, 410 U.
S. 366,
410 U. S. 389,
the
"very reason for the regulation of private utility rates -- by
state bodies and by the Commission -- is the inevitability of a
monopoly that requires price control to take the place of price
competition."
[
Footnote 34]
Commenting on a possible conflict between federal regulatory
policy and federal antitrust policy. we have repeatedly said
"'[r]epeal [of the antitrust laws] is to be regarded as implied
only if necessary to make the . . . [Act] work, and even then only
to the minimum extent necessary.'"
Id. at
410 U.S.
391, quoting
Silver v. New York Stock Exchange,
373 U. S. 341,
373 U. S.
357.
[
Footnote 35]
Indeed, since our decision in
Otter Tail Power Co. v. United
States, supra, there can be no doubt about the proposition
that the federal antitrust laws are applicable to electrical
utilities. Although there was dissent from the particular
application of the statute in that case, there was no dissent from
the basic proposition that such utilities must obey the federal
antitrust laws.
[
Footnote 36]
Respondent does not argue that state regulation provides a
stronger justification for an implied exemption than federal
regulation. On the contrary, respondent relies heavily on
Gordon v. New York Stock Exchange, 422 U.
S. 659, in which the Court upheld the fixed commissions
of the stock exchange as an integral part of the effective
operation of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. The
inapplicability of that case is manifest from MR. JUSTICE STEWART's
brief concurring opinion in which he stated:
"The Court has never held, and does not hold today, that the
antitrust laws are inapplicable to anticompetitive conduct simply
because a federal agency has jurisdiction over the activities of
one or more of the defendants. An implied repeal of the antitrust
laws may be found only if there exists a 'plain repugnancy between
the antitrust and regulatory provisions.'
United States v.
Philadelphia Nat. Bank, 374 U. S. 321,
374 U. S.
351."
"The mere existence of the Commission's reserve power of
oversight with respect to rules initially adopted by the exchanges,
therefore, does not necessarily immunize those rules from antitrust
attack. . . . The question presented by the present case,
therefore, is whether exchange rules fixing minimum commission
rates are necessary to make the Securities Exchange Act work."
Id. at
422 U. S.
692-693. The lamp supply program is by no means
comparably imperative in the continued effective functioning of
Michigan's regulation of the utilities industry.
[
Footnote 37]
See n 34,
supra. Recent cases make it clear that the relevant
"'aspect of the agency's jurisdiction must be sufficiently
central to the purposes of the enabling statute so that implied
repeal of the antitrust laws is necessary to make the [regulatory
scheme] work.'"
Robinson, Recent Antitrust Developments: 1975, 31 Record of N.Y.
C. B. A. 38, 57-58 (1976).
In
United States v. National Assn. of Securities
Dealers, 422 U. S. 694,
422 U. S.
719-720, the Court pointed out: '
"Implied antitrust immunity is not favored, and can be justified
only by a convincing showing of clear repugnancy between the
antitrust laws and the regulatory system.
See, e.g., United
States v. Philadelphia Nat. Bank, 374 U.S. at
374 U. S.
348;
United States v. Borden Co., 308 U. S.
188,
308 U. S. 197-206
(1939)."
These cases are, of course, consistent with the "cardinal rule,"
applicable to legislation generally, that repeals by implication
are not favored.
Posadas v. National City Bank,
296 U. S. 497,
296 U. S.
503.
[
Footnote 38]
Of course, the absence of an exemption from the antitrust laws
does not mean that those laws have been violated.
[
Footnote 39]
It is this concern which has repeatedly prompted the
introduction of bills which, if adopted, would make the award of
treble damages in antitrust litigation discretionary, rather than
mandatory.
See Report of the Attorney General's National
Committee to Study the Antitrust Laws 378-380 (1955).
See also,
e.g., H.R. 978, 85th Cong., 1st Sess. (1957); H.R.190, 87th
Cong., 1st Sess. (1961).
[
Footnote 40]
"As a charter of freedom, the Act has a generality and
adaptability comparable to that found to be desirable in
constitutional provisions. It does not go into detailed definitions
which might either work injury to legitimate enterprise or, through
particularization, defeat its purposes by providing loopholes for
escape. The restrictions the Act imposes are not mechanical or
artificial. Its general phrases, interpreted to attain its
fundamental objects, set up the essential standard of
reasonableness. They call for vigilance in the detection and
frustration of all efforts unduly to restrain the free course of
interstate commerce, but they do not seek to establish a mere
delusive liberty either by making impossible the normal and fair
expansion of that commerce or the adoption of reasonable measures
to protect it from injurious and destructive practices and to
promote competition upon a sound basis."
Appalachian Coals, Inc. v. United States, 288 U.
S. 344,
288 U. S.
359-360.
[
Footnote 41]
"The threshold inquiry in determining if an anticompetitive
activity is state action of the type the Sherman Act was not meant
to proscribe is whether the activity is required by the State
acting as sovereign.
Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 350-352;
Continental Co. v. Union Carbide, 370 U. S.
690,
370 U. S. 706-707
(1962)."
421 U.S. at
421 U. S.
790.
[
Footnote 42]
Indeed, it did not even occur to the plaintiff that the state
officials might have violated the Sherman Act; that question was
first raised by this Court.
[
Footnote 43]
Actually the reference was primarily to
United States v.
Rock Royal Co-op., 307 U. S. 533, and
only secondarily to
Parker. See 365 U.S. at
365 U. S. 136
n. 15.
[
Footnote 44]
"We accept, as the starting point for our consideration of the
case, the same basic construction of the Sherman Act adopted by the
courts below -- that no violation of the Act can be predicated upon
mere attempts to influence the passage or enforcement of laws. It
has been recognized, at least since the landmark decision of this
Court in
Standard Oil Co. v. United
States, [
221 U.S.
1,] that the Sherman Act forbids only those trade restraints
and monopolizations that are created, or attempted, by the acts of
'individuals or combinations of individuals or corporations.'
Accordingly, it has been held that, where a restraint upon trade or
monopolization is the result of valid governmental action, as
opposed to private action, no violation of the Act can be made
out."
(
Rock Royal and
Parker are then cited in the
footnote, which is omitted.) 365 U.S. at
365 U. S.
135-136.
[
Footnote 45]
MR. JUSTICE STEWART's analysis rests largely on the dubious
assumption that, if each of several steps in the implementation of
an anticompetitive program is lawful, the entire program must be
equally lawful.
MR. CHIEF JUSTICE BURGER, concurring in the judgment and in all
except Parts II and IV of the Court's opinion.
I concur in the judgment and in all except Parts II and IV of
the Court's opinion. I do not agree, however, that
Parker v.
Brown, 317 U. S. 341
(1943), can logically be
Page 428 U. S. 604
limited to suits against state officials. In interpreting
Parker, the Court has heretofore focused on the challenged
activity, not upon the identity of the
parties to
the suit.
"The threshold inquiry in determining if an anticompetitive
activity is state action of the type the Sherman Act was not meant
to proscribe is whether the
activity is required by the
State acting as sovereign."
Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U.
S. 773,
421 U. S. 790
(1975) (emphasis added). If
Parker's holding were limited
simply to the nonliability of state officials, then the Court's
inquiry in
Goldfarb as to the County Bar Association's
claimed exemption could have ended upon our recognition that the
organization was "a voluntary association, and not a state agency.
. . ." 421 U.S. at
421 U. S. 790.
Yet, before determining that there was no exemption from the
antitrust laws, the Court proceeded to treat the Association's
contention that its action, having been "prompted" by the State
Bar, was "state action for Sherman Act purposes."
Ibid.
The reading of
Parker in
428 U.
S. that decision simply does not address the precise
issue raised by the present case. There was no need in
Parker to focus upon the situation where the State, in
addition to requiring a public utility "to meet regulatory criteria
insofar as it is exercising its natural monopoly powers,"
ante at
428 U. S. 596,
also purports, without any independent regulatory purpose, to
control the utility's activities in separate, competitive markets.
Today the Court correctly concludes:
"The Commission's approval of respondent's decision to maintain
such a program does not . . . implement any state-wide policy
relating to light bulbs. We infer that the State's policy is
neutral on the question
Page 428 U. S. 605
whether a utility should, or should not, have such a
program."
Ante at
428 U. S. 585
(emphasis added). To find a "state action" exemption on the basis
of Michigan's undifferentiated sanction of this ancillary practice
could serve no federal or state policy.
MR. JUSTICE BLACKMUN, concurring in the judgment.
I agree with the Court insofar as it holds that the fact that
anticompetitive conduct is sanctioned, or even required, by state
law does not, of itself, put that conduct beyond the reach of the
Sherman Act. Since the opposite proposition is the ground on which
the Court of Appeals affirmed the dismissal of this suit, I also
agree that its judgment must be reversed. My approach, however, is
somewhat different from that of the Court.
I
As to the principal question in the case, that of the Sherman
Act's preemptive effect upon inconsistent state laws, it is, as the
dissent points out, one of congressional intent. No one denies that
Congress could, if it wished, override those state laws whose
operation would subvert the federal policy of free competition in
interstate commerce. In discerning that intent, however, I find
somewhat less assistance in the legislative history than does the
dissent. It is true that the framers of the Sherman Act expressed
the view that certain areas of economic activity were left entirely
to state regulation. The dissent quotes several of these
expressions.
Post at
428 U. S.
632-634. A careful reading of those statements reveals,
however, that they little more than reflect the then-prevailing
view that Congress lacked the power, under the Commerce Clause, to
regulate economic activity that was within the domain of the
States. The Court since then has recognized a greatly expanded
Commerce Clause
Page 428 U. S. 606
power. Arguably, the Sherman Act should have remained confined
within the outlines of that power as it was thought to exist in
1890 on the theory that, if Congress believed it could not regulate
any more broadly, it must not have attempted to do so. But that
bridge already has been crossed, for it has been held that Congress
intended the reach of the Sherman Act to expand along with that of
the commerce power.
Hospital Building Co. v. Rex Hospital
Trustees, 425 U. S. 738,
425 U. S. 743
n. 2 (1976), and cases cited.
Our question in this case is one that the Sherman Act's framers
did not directly confront or explicitly address: what was to be the
result if the expanding ambit of the Sherman Act should bring it
into conflict with inconsistent state law? But it seems to me that
this bridge also has been crossed. In
Schwegmann Bros. v.
Calvert Distillers Corp., 341 U. S. 384
(1951), the issue was whether the Sherman Act permitted enforcement
of a Louisiana statute requiring compliance by liquor retailers
with resale price agreements to which they were not parties, but
which had been entered into by other retailers with their wholesale
suppliers. The Court held the Louisiana statute unenforceable;
there is no plausible reading of that decision other than that the
statute was preempted by the Sherman Act. [
Footnote 2/1]
Northern Securities Co. v. United
States, 193 U. S. 197
(1904), is to the same effect. The defenders of the railroad
holding company attacked in that case argued that it was beyond the
Sherman Act's reach because it was lawful under the corporation
Page 428 U. S. 607
laws of New Jersey. The holding company was nonetheless held
unlawful, and, to that extent, the law of New Jersey was forced to
give way. [
Footnote 2/2] Indeed, I
suppose that some degree of state law preemption is implicit in the
most fundamental operation of the Sherman Act. If a State had no
antitrust policy of its own, anticompetitive combinations of all
kinds would be sanctioned and enforced under that State's general
contract and corporation law. Yet there has never been any doubt
that, if such combinations offend the Sherman Act, they are
illegal, and state laws to that extent are overridden. [
Footnote 2/3]
Congress itself has given support to the view that inconsistent
state laws are preempted by the Sherman Act. Were it the case that
state statutes held complete sway, Congress would not have found it
necessary in 1937 to pass the Miller-Tydings Fair Trade Act, 50
Stat. 693, amending the Sherman Act, specifically exempting from
the latter's operation certain price maintenance agreements
sanctioned by state law. 15 U.S.C. § 1. There are other instances
of Congress' acting to protect state-sanctioned anticompetitive
schemes from the Sherman
Page 428 U. S. 608
Act. In response to
Schwegmann, see H.R.Rep. No. 1437,
82d Cong., 2d Sess., 1-2, Congress in 1952 passed the McGuire bill,
66 Stat. 632, extending the Miller-Tydings exemption to state
statutes that enforced resale price agreements against nonsigners.
15 U.S.C. §§ 45(a)(2) to (5). A similar enactment is the
McCarran-Ferguson Act of 1945, 59 Stat. 34, exempting from federal
statutes "any law enacted by any State for the purpose of
regulating the business of insurance," with provision that the
Sherman Act, and other named federal statutes, should apply to that
business after a specified date "to the extent that such business
is not regulated by State law." 15 U.S.C. § 1012(b). [
Footnote 2/4] These express grants of
Sherman Act immunity seem significant to me. As the Court stated in
United States v. Borden Co., 308 U.
S. 188,
308 U. S. 201
(1939), construing the immunity granted to certain agreements by
the Agricultural Marketing
Page 428 U. S. 609
Agreement Act of 1937, "[i]f Congress had desired to grant any
further immunity, Congress doubtless would have said so."
II
I also agree with MR. JUSTICE STEVENS that the particular
anticompetitive scheme attacked in this case must fall despite the
imprimatur it claims to have received from the State of Michigan.
To say, as I have, that the Sherman Act generally preempts
inconsistent state laws is not to answer the much more difficult
question as to which such laws are preempted and to what extent. I
fear there are no easy solutions, though several suggest
themselves.
It cannot be decisive, for example, simply that a state law goes
so far as to require, rather than simply to authorize, the
anticompetitive conduct in question. The Court accepted this as a
prerequisite to antitrust immunity in
Goldfarb v. Virginia
State Bar, 421 U. S. 773,
421 U. S. 790
(1975), but it cannot alone be sufficient. The whole issue in
Schwegmann was whether the State
could require
obedience to a fixed resale price arrangement. Similarly,
compliance with an anticompetitive contract, or adherence to an
illegal corporate combination, might well be "required" by a
State's general contract and corporation law.
Neither can it be decisive that a particular state-sanctioned
scheme was initiated by the private actors, rather than by the
State. I see no difference in the degree of private initiation as
between the marketing arrangement approved in
Parker v.
Brown, 317 U. S. 341
(1943) (and properly approved, I think, for reasons set forth
below), and the resale price maintenance scheme disapproved in
Schwegmann. In each case, the particular scheme was
initiated by the private actors at the invitation of a general
statute, with which they may or may
Page 428 U. S. 610
not have had anything to do. The same was true in
Northern
Securities, and the same is true here. To be sure, there is a
certain rough justice, as well as an appearance of simplicity, in a
rule based upon who actually is responsible for the scheme in
question, but I fear that both the justice and the simplicity would
prove illusory in the rule's actual application. Every state
enactment is initiated, in its way, by its beneficiaries. It would
scarcely make sense to immunize only those powerful enough to speak
entirely through their governmental representatives, or, for that
matter, to stifle such speech with the threat that it will destroy
antitrust immunity. Moreover, the process of enactment is likely to
involve such a complex interplay between those regulating and those
regulated that it will be impossible to identify the true
"initiator."
A final, ostensibly simple, solution that I find wanting would
be to insist only on some degree of affirmative articulation by the
State of its conscientious intent to sanction the challenged
scheme, and its reasons therefor. This also is a tempting solution,
particularly in this case, where there is little to suggest (at
least in recent years) that the Michigan Public Service Commission
has even actively considered the light bulb tie-in, much less
articulated a justification for it. Yet such a solution would also
lead to perverse results. A regulation whose justification was too
plain to require explication would be vulnerable; a questionable
one could be immunized if its proponents had the skill or influence
to generate the proper legislative history. And, of course,
deciding how much "affirmative articulation" of state policy is
enough is not a simple matter.
I would apply, at least for now, a rule of reason, taking it as
a general proposition that state-sanctioned anticompetitive
activity must fall like any other if its potential harms outweigh
its benefits. This does not mean
Page 428 U. S. 611
that state-sanctioned and private activity are to be treated
alike. The former is different, because the fact of state sanction
figures powerfully in the calculus of harm and benefit. If, for
example, the justification for the scheme lies in the protection of
health or safety, the strength of that justification is forcefully
attested to by the existence of a state enactment. I would assess
the justifications of such enactments in the same way as is done in
equal protection review, and where such justifications are at all
substantial (as one would expect them to be in the case of most
professional licensing or fee-setting schemes, for example,
cf.
Olsen v. Smith, 195 U. S. 332
(1904)), I would be reluctant to find the restraint unreasonable. A
particularly strong justification exists for a state-sanctioned
scheme if the State, in effect, has substituted itself for the
forces of competition, and regulates private activity to the same
ends sought to be achieved by the Sherman Act. Thus, an
anticompetitive scheme which the State institutes on the plausible
ground that it will improve the performance of the market in
fostering efficient resource allocation and low prices can scarcely
be assailed. One could not doubt the legality of Detroit Edison's
electric power monopoly; the fear of such a monopoly is primarily
its tendency to charge excessive prices, but its prices in this
instance are controlled by the State.
No doubt such a rule of reason will crystallize, as it is
applied, into various
per se rules relating to certain
kinds of state enactments, such as the regulation of the classic
natural monopoly, the public utility. We should not shrink in our
general approach, however, from what seems to me our
constitutionally mandated task, one often set for us by conflicting
federal and state laws, and that is the balancing of implicated
federal and state interests with a view to assuring that, when
these are truly in conflict, the former prevail.
Page 428 U. S. 612
The dissent's fears on this score appear to me to be
exaggerated. The balancing of harm and benefit is, in general, a
process with which federal courts are well acquainted in the
antitrust field. The special problem of assessing state interests
to determine whether they are strong enough to prevail against
supreme federal dictates is also a familiar one to the federal
courts. Indeed, a state action that interferes with competition not
only among its own citizens, but also among the States, is already
subject under the Commerce Clause to much the same searching review
of state justifications as is proposed here.
See, e.g., Dean
Milk Co. v. Madison, 340 U. S. 349,
340 U. S. 354
(1951) (state restriction on sale of milk not locally processed
held invalid because "reasonable and adequate alternatives [were]
available" to protect health interests);
Southern Pacific Co.
v. Arizona, 325 U. S. 761,
325 U. S.
770-784 (1945) (state restriction of train lengths held
invalid under the Commerce Clause because "the state [safety]
interest is outweighed by the interest of the nation in an
adequate, economical and efficient railway transportation
service").
III
By these standards, the present case does not seem a difficult
one. The light bulb tie-in presents the usual dangers of such a
scheme, principally that respondent will extend its monopoly from
the sale of electric power into that of light bulbs, not because it
sells better light bulbs, but because its light bulbs are the ones
customers must pay for if they are to have light at all.
See P. Areeda, Antitrust Analysis 569-570 (2d ed.1974). On
the record before us, the scheme appears to be unjustified. No
doubt it originated as a means to promote electric power use, but
it is difficult to see why a tie-in (rather than an optional,
promotional light bulb sale) was necessary
Page 428 U. S. 613
to that end even in the 19th century, laying aside the question
whether the promotion of greater electric power use remains today a
plausible public goal. Respondent would justify the scheme on the
ground of consumer savings, its light bulbs assertedly being
cheaper and better than those commercially available. Brief for
Respondent 7-9, 41-42. But again, a tie-in is not necessary to pass
along these savings. A tie-in is only necessary in order to force
consumers to pay for light bulbs from Detroit Edison rather than
someone else. But there is no indication that one light bulb does
not fit the socket as well as another, or that the sale of light
bulbs is in any way crucial to respondent's successful operation.
Conceivably, Michigan's aim is the very extension of the monopoly,
born of a preference for having light bulbs supplied by one whose
prices are already regulated. But ending competition in the light
bulb market cannot be accepted as an adequate state objective
without some evidence -- of which there is not the least hint in
this record -- that such competition is in some way ineffective.
For all that appears, light bulb marketing, unlike electric power
production, is not a natural monopoly, nor does it implicate health
or safety, nor is it beset with problems of instability or other
flaws in the competitive market. [
Footnote 2/5]
Page 428 U. S. 614
This is what I take it the Court means when it says the electric
light bulb market is "essentially unregulated," and, on that
understanding, I agree with its conclusion. It is conceivable that
respondent may show, upon further evidence, a sufficient
justification for the scheme, but it certainly has not done so as
yet. [
Footnote 2/6]
[
Footnote 2/1]
The Court expressly stated in
Schwegmann: "The fact
that a state authorizes the price-fixing does not, of course, give
immunity to the scheme, absent approval by Congress." And again:
"[W]hen a state compels retailers to follow a parallel price
policy, it demands private conduct which the Sherman Act forbids."
341 U.S. at
341 U. S. 386,
341 U. S.
389.
[
Footnote 2/2]
The argument that New Jersey law exempted Northern Securities
Company from the Sherman Act was thoroughly canvassed in the
plurality 193 U.S. at
193 U. S.
344-351. It was rejected for the reason
"that no State can endow any of its corporations, or any
combination of its citizens, with authority to restrain interstate
or international commerce, or to disobey the national will as
manifested in legal enactments of Congress."
Id. at
193 U. S.
350.
[
Footnote 2/3]
In passing, we may cast at least a sidelong glance at a related
area of federal trade regulation -- that of the patent laws.
Although the federal statute is no more explicit on the point than
is the Sherman Act,
see 35 U.S.C. § 100
et seq.,
it clearly preempts state laws that purport either to expand on or
to infringe the federal patent monopoly.
See, e.g., Lear, Inc.
v. Adkins, 395 U. S. 653
(1969);
Sears, Roebuck & Co. v. Stiffel Co.,
376 U. S. 225
(1964);
Compco Corp. v. Day-Brite Lighting, 376 U.
S. 234 (1964).
[
Footnote 2/4]
The McCarran-Ferguson Act was passed in reaction to the holding
in
United States v. Underwriters Assn., 322 U.
S. 533 (1944), that the business of insurance is
"commerce" within the meaning of the Sherman Act. Congress'
expressed concern was that the application of that Act would
"greatly impair or nullify the regulation of insurance by the
States," bringing to a halt their "experimentation and
investigation" in the area. The Act was vigorously endorsed by
Governors and insurance commissioners of "almost all of the
States." The Justice Department, in opposing the McCarran-Ferguson
Act, specifically argued that
Parker v. Brown,
317 U. S. 341
(1943), made the legislation unnecessary because it immunized the
insurance business insofar as it was regulated by the States.
Congress was not so sure:
"
Parker v. Brown dealt with a State commission
authorized by State statute to enforce a program in conformity
with, if not supplementary to, a Federal statute. Obviously, all
State regulation concerning insurance does not and would not fall
in such a category."
S.Rep. No. 1112, 78th Cong., 2d Sess., 5 (1944).
See
also S.Rep. No. 20, 79th Cong., 1st Sess., 1-3 (1945);
H.R.Rep. No. 873, 78th Cong., 1st Sess., 7 (1943); H.R.Rep. No.
143, 79th Cong., 1st Sess., 4 (1945).
[
Footnote 2/5]
The approach described in the text is entirely consistent with
the result reached in
Parker v. Brown. Wildly fluctuating
agricultural prices are a prime candidate for some collective
scheme that interrupts free competition in order to bring badly
needed stability; under the State's close supervision, as was the
case in
Parker, the scheme seems entirely reasonable. I
see no reason to disapprove the holding of
Parker,
therefore, and, to the extent that the plurality, by stressing the
identity of the state defendants in that case, intimates that a
different result might have been reached had the raisin growers
themselves been sued, I cannot agree.
Neither can I agree with the dissent, however, that
Parker must be taken to stand for the broad proposition
that a State can immunize any conduct from the application of the
Sherman Act. It is true, as the dissent points out, that there are
statements arguably to that effect in
Parker, but the
opinion is hardly unambiguous on the point. The Court also observed
in that case that "a state does not give immunity to those who
violate the Sherman Act by authorizing them to violate it, or by
declaring that their action is lawful." 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 351.
Moreover, if we must choose between
Parker's more
categorical statements and the seemingly contrary statements in
Schwegmann and
Northern Securities, see nn.
428
U.S. 579fn2/1|>1 and
428
U.S. 579fn2/2|>2,
supra, I prefer the latter, as
more in keeping with the actual holdings of those cases.
[
Footnote 2/6]
MR. JUSTICE STEVENS states that there may be cases in which
"the State's participation in a decision [to adopt the
challenged restraint] is so dominant that it is unfair to hold a
private party responsible for his conduct in implementing it."
Ante at
428 U. S.
594-595. I agree that a defense based on fairness may be
available. I would not, however, rule it out in this case, as the
Court's opinion does. The parties, like the court below, so far
have addressed themselves only to the question whether petitioner's
suit is completely barred by
Parker v. Brown and the
Michigan Public Service Commission's approval of the challenged
tie-in. I would confine our present decision to that question
alone, leaving consideration of a fairness defense to the lower
courts on remand, and making only these two further
observations:
First, I take it that a defense based on fairness would be a
defense to a damages recovery, but not injunctive relief. The
latter, of course, presents no danger of unfairness. Moreover, as
MR. JUSTICE STEVENS implies by his emphasis on not unfairly holding
a private party "responsible," the defense rests on the theory not
that the challenged restraint is legal, but that, since the
defendant has committed no voluntary act in implementing it, he
cannot be said to have violated any law. The same would not be true
of acts following a judgment that the restraint is in fact illegal,
and the state law to that extent invalid.
Second, I would hope that consideration will be given on remand
to allowing a defense against damages wherever the conduct on which
such damages would be based was required by state law. Such a rule
would comport with the theory that a defendant should not be held
"responsible" in damages for conduct as to which he had no choice,
by which I do not mean to rule out other possible grounds for such
a rule.
See Posner, The Proper Relationship Between State
Regulation and the Federal Antitrust Laws, 49 N.Y.U.L.Rev. 693,
728-732 (1974). It would also eliminate what seems to me the
extremely unfair possibility that, during a particular period --
and it could be a regulatory lag during which the regulatee was
attempting to
change the state mandate -- the regulatee
could be required by state law to conform to a course of conduct
for which he was all the while accumulating treble damages
liability under federal law.
MR. JUSTICE STEWART, with whom MR. JUSTICE POWELL and MR.
JUSTICE REHNQUIST join, dissenting.
The Court today holds that a public utility company, pervasively
regulated by a state utility commission,
Page 428 U. S. 615
may be held liable for treble damages under the Sherman Act for
engaging in conduct which, under the requirements of its tariff, it
is obligated to perform. I respectfully dissent from this
unprecedented application of the federal antitrust laws, which will
surely result in disruption of the operation of every
state-regulated public utility company in the Nation and in the
creation of "the prospect of massive treble damage liabilities"
[
Footnote 3/1] payable ultimately
by the companies' customers.
The starting point in analyzing this case is
Parker v.
Brown, 317 U. S. 341.
While
Parker did not create the "so-called state action
exemption" [
Footnote 3/2] from the
federal antitrust laws, [
Footnote
3/3] it is the case that is most frequently
Page 428 U. S. 616
cited for the proposition that the "[Sherman] Act was intended
to regulate private practices, and not to prohibit a State from
imposing a restraint as an act of government."
Goldfarb v.
Virginia State Bar, 421 U. S. 773,
421 U. S. 788.
The plurality opinion would hold that that case decided only that
"the sovereign State itself,"
ante at
428 U. S. 591,
could not be sued under the Sherman Act. This view of
Parker, which would trivialize that case to the point of
overruling it, [
Footnote 3/4] flies
in the face of the decisions of
Page 428 U. S. 617
this Court that have interpreted or applied
Parker's
"state action" doctrine, and is unsupported by the sources on which
the plurality relies.
As to those sources, I would have thought that, except in rare
instances, an analysis of the positions taken by the parties in
briefs submitted to this Court should play no role in interpreting
its written opinions. [
Footnote
3/5] A
Page 428 U. S. 618
contrary rule would permit the "plain meaning" of our decisions
to be qualified or even overridden by their "legislative history"
--
i.e., briefs submitted by the contending parties. The
legislative history of congressional enactments is useful in
discerning legislative intent, because that history emanates from
the same source as the legislation itself, and is thus directly
probative of the intent of the draftsmen. The conflicting views
presented in the adversary briefs and arguments submitted to this
Court do not bear an analogous relationship to the Court's final
product.
But assuming,
arguendo, that it is appropriate to look
behind the language of
Parker v. Brown, supra, I think it
is apparent that the plurality has distorted the positions taken by
the State of California and the United States as
amici
curiae. The question presented on reargument in
Parker was "whether the state statute involved is rendered
invalid by the action of Congress in passing the Sherman Act. . .
."
Ante at
428 U. S. 587
n. 16. This phrasing indicates that the precise issue on which the
Court sought reargument was whether the California statute was
preempted by the Sherman Act, not whether sovereign States were
immune from suit under the Sherman Act.
The State of California and the Solicitor General certainly
understood this to be the principal issue. As the plurality opinion
correctly notes, the supplemental brief filed by the State of
California in response to the question posed by this Court advanced
three basic arguments. And as it further notes, this Court's
decision in
Parker rested on the first of those arguments.
But what the plurality fails to acknowledge is that California's
first argument was in principal part a straightforward
contention
Page 428 U. S. 619
that the Sherman Act was not intended to preempt state
regulation of intrastate commerce. [
Footnote 3/6]
With respect to the
amicus brief of the United
States,
Page 428 U. S. 620
the plurality opinion states that the "Solicitor General did not
take issue with the appellants' first argument."
Ante at
428 U. S. 588.
Indeed, the plurality says, the Solicitor General "expressly
disclaimed any argument that the State of California or its
officials had violated federal law."
Ibid. In support of
this assertion, the plurality opinion quotes the following language
from p. 59 of the Solicitor General's brief in
Parker:
"'[T]he question we face here is not whether California or its
officials have violated the Sherman Act, but whether the state
program interferes with the accomplishment of the objectives of the
federal statute.'"
Ante at
428 U. S. 589
n.19.
This statement by the Solicitor General was indeed correct,
because the question on which the Court had requested supplemental
briefing was "whether the state statute involved is rendered
invalid by the action of Congress in passing the Sherman Act," not
"whether California or its officials have violated the Sherman Act.
. . ." As the Solicitor General noted in the very next
sentence,
"[a] state law may be superseded as conflicting with a federal
statute irrespective of whether its administrators are subject to
prosecution for violation of the paramount federal enactment.
[
Footnote 3/7]"
The Solicitor General then proceeded
Page 428 U. S. 621
to take strenuous issue with the principal contention advanced
in the first part of the relevant section of California's brief --
that the framers of the federal legislation had not intended to
preempt state legislation like the California Agricultural Prorate
Act. [
Footnote 3/8]
Thus, it is clear that the plurality has misread the positions
taken by the State of California and the Solicitor General in
Parker v. Brown. The question presented to the Court in
Parker was whether the restraint on trade effected by the
California statute was exempt
Page 428 U. S. 622
from the operation of the Sherman Act. That was the question
addressed by the Solicitor General and, in principal part, by the
State of California. And it was the question resolved by this Court
in its holding that
"[t]he state in adopting and enforcing the prorate program made
no contract or agreement and entered into no conspiracy in
restraint of trade or to establish monopoly but, as sovereign,
imposed the restraint as an act of government which the Sherman Act
did not undertake to prohibit."
317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
352.
The notion that
Parker decided only that "action taken
by state officials pursuant to express legislative command did not
violate the Sherman Act,"
ante at
428 U. S. 589,
and that that "narrow holding . . . avoided any question about the
applicability of the antitrust laws to private action" taken under
command of state law,
ante at
428 U. S. 590,
is thus refuted by the very sources on which the plurality opinion
relies. That narrow view of the
Parker decision is also
refuted by the subsequent cases in this Court that have interpreted
and applied the
Parker doctrine.
In
Eastern. R. Conf. v. Noerr Motors, 365 U.
S. 127, for instance, the Court held that no violation
of the Sherman Act could be predicated on the attempt by private
persons to influence the passage or enforcement of state laws
regulating competition in the trucking industry. [
Footnote 3/9] The Court took as its starting point
the ruling in
Parker v. Brown that,
"where a restraint upon trade or monopolization is the result of
valid governmental action, as opposed to private action, no
violation of the Act can be made out."
365 U.S. at
365 U. S. 136.
The Court
Page 428 U. S. 623
viewed it as
"equally clear that the Sherman Act does not prohibit two or
more persons from associating together in an attempt to persuade
the legislature or the executive to take particular action with
respect to a law that would produce a restraint or monopoly."
Ibid. A contrary ruling, the Court held, "would
substantially impair the power of government to take actions
through its legislature and executive that operate to restrain
trade."
Id. at
365 U. S. 137.
Surely, if a rule permitting Sherman Act liability to arise from
lobbying by private parties for state rules restricting competition
would impair the power of state governments to impose restraints,
then
a fortiori a rule permitting Sherman Act liability to
arise from private parties' compliance with such rules would impair
the exercise of the States' power. But, as the Court in
Noerr correctly noted, the latter result was foreclosed by
Parker's holding that,
"where a restraint upon trade or monopolization is the result of
valid governmental action, as opposed to private action, no
violation of the Act can be made out."
365 U.S. at
365 U. S.
136.
Litigation testing the limits of the state action exemption has
focused on whether alleged anticompetitive conduct by private
parties is indeed "the result of" state action. Thus, in
Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U.
S. 773, the question was whether price-fixing practiced
by the respondents was "required by the State acting as sovereign.
Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
350-352. . . ."
Id. at
421 U. S. 790.
The Court held that the "so-called state action exemption,"
id. at
421 U. S. 788,
did not protect the respondents, because it
"cannot fairly be said that the State of Virginia, through its
Supreme Court Rules, required the anticompetitive activities of
either respondent. . . . Respondents' arguments, at most,
constitute the contention that their activities complemented the
objective
Page 428 U. S. 624
of the ethical codes. In our view, that is not state action for
Sherman Act purposes. It is not enough that, as the County Bar puts
it, anticompetitive conduct is
prompted' by state action;
rather, anticompetitive activities must be compelled by direction
of the State acting as a sovereign."
Id. at
421 U. S.
790-791. The plurality's view that
Parker does
not cover state-compelled private conduct flies in the face of this
carefully drafted language in the
Goldfarb opinion.
Parker, Noerr, and
Goldfarb point unerringly
to the proper disposition of this case. The regulatory process at
issue has three principal stages. First, the utility company
proposes a tariff. Second, the Michigan Public Service Commission
investigates the proposed tariff and either approves it or rejects
it. Third, if the tariff is approved, the utility company must,
under command of state law, provide service in accord with its
requirements until or unless the Commission approves a
modification. The utility company thus engages in two distinct
activities: it proposes a tariff and, if the tariff is approved, it
obeys its terms. The first action cannot give rise to antitrust
liability under
Noerr, and the second -- compliance with
the terms of the tariff under the command of state law -- is immune
from antitrust liability under
Parker and
Goldfarb. [
Footnote
3/10]
Page 428 U. S. 625
The plurality's contrary view would effectively overrule not
only
Parker, but the entire body of post-
Parker
case law in this area, including
Noerr. With the
Parker holding reduced to the trivial proposition that the
Sherman Act was not intended to run directly against state
officials or governmental entities, the Court would fashion a new
two-part test for determining whether state utility regulation
creates immunity from the federal antitrust law. The first part of
the test would focus on whether subjecting state-regulated
utilities to antitrust liability would be "unjust." The second part
of the test would look to whether the draftsmen of the Sherman Act
intended to "superimpose" antitrust standards, and thus exposure to
treble damages, on conduct compelled by state regulatory laws. THE
CHIEF JUSTICE accedes to the new two-part test, at least where the
State "purports, without any independent regulatory purpose, to
control [a] utility's activities in separate, competitive
Page 428 U. S. 626
markets."
Ante at
428 U. S. 604.
The new immunity test thus has the approval of a majority of the
Court in instances where state-compelled anticompetitive practices
are deemed "ancillary" to the State's regulatory goals. [
Footnote 3/11]
With scarcely a backward glance at the
Noerr case, the
Court concludes that, because the utility company's "participation"
in the decision to incorporate the lamp exchange program into the
tariff was "sufficiently significant," there is nothing "unjust" in
concluding that the company is required to conform its conduct to
federal antitrust law "like comparable conduct by unregulated
businesses. . . ."
Ante at
428 U. S. 594.
This attempt to distinguish between the exemptive force of
mandatory state rules adopted at the behest of private parties and
those adopted pursuant to the State's unilateral decision is flatly
inconsistent with the rationale of
Noerr. There, the Court
pointedly rejected "[a] construction of the Sherman Act that would
disqualify people from taking a public position on matters in which
they are financially interested" because such a construction
"would . . . deprive the government of a valuable source of
information and, at the same time, deprive the people of their
right to petition in the very instances in which that right may be
of the most importance to them."
365 U.S. at
365 U. S. 139.
[
Footnote 3/12]
Page 428 U. S. 627
Today's holding will not only penalize the right to petition but
may very well strike a crippling blow at state utility regulation.
As the Court seems to acknowledge, such regulation is heavily
dependent on the active participation of the regulated parties, who
typically propose tariffs which are either adopted, rejected, or
modified by utility commissions. But if a utility can escape the
unpredictable consequences of the second arm of the Court's new
test,
see infra this page, only by playing possum -- by
exercising no "option" in the Court's terminology,
ante at
594 -- then it will surely be tempted to do just that, posing a
serious threat to efficient and effective regulation.
The second arm of the Court's new immunity test, which
apparently comes into play only if the utility's own activity does
not exceed a vaguely defined threshold of "sufficient freedom of
choice," purports to be aimed at answering the basic question of
whether "Congress intended to superimpose antitrust standards on
conduct already being regulated" by state utility regulation laws.
Ante at
428 U. S. 595.
Yet analysis of the Court's opinion reveals that the three factors
to which the Court pays heed have little or nothing to do with
discerning congressional intent. Rather, the second arm of the new
test simply creates a vehicle for
ad hoc judicial
determinations of the substantive validity of state regulatory
goals, which closely resembles the discarded doctrine of
substantive due process.
See Ferguson v. Skrupa,
372 U. S. 726.
The Court's delineation of the second arm of the new test
proceeds as follows. Apart from the "fairness" question, the Court
states, there are "at least three reasons" why the light bulb
program should not enjoy Sherman Act immunity.
Ante at
428 U. S. 595.
"First," the Court observes,
"merely because certain conduct may be subject both to state
regulation and to the federal antitrust laws does not necessarily
mean that it must satisfy
Page 428 U. S. 628
inconsistent standards. . . ."
Ibid. That is true enough as an abstract proposition,
but the very question is whether the utility's alleged "tie" of
light bulb sales to the provision of electric service is immune
from antitrust liability, assuming it would constitute an antitrust
violation in the absence of regulation. [
Footnote 3/13] Second, the Court states, "even assuming
inconsistency, we could not accept the view that the federal
interest must inevitably be subordinated to the State's. . . ."
Ibid. The Court goes on to amplify this rationale as
follows:
"The mere possibility of conflict between state regulatory
policy and federal antitrust policy is an insufficient basis for
implying an exemption from the federal antitrust laws. Congress
could hardly have intended state regulatory agencies to have
broader power than federal agencies to exempt private conduct from
the antitrust laws. Therefore,
Page 428 U. S. 629
assuming that there are situations in which the existence of
state regulation should give rise to an implied exemption, the
standards for ascertaining the existence and scope of such an
exemption surely must be at least as severe as those applied to
federal regulatory legislation."
"The Court has consistently refused to find that regulation gave
rise to an implied exemption without first determining that
exemption was necessary in order to make the regulatory act work,
'and even then only to the minimum extent necessary.'"
"The application of that standard to this case inexorably
requires rejection of respondent's claim."
Ante at
428 U. S.
596-598 (footnotes omitted).
The Court's analysis rests on a mistaken premise. The "implied
immunity" doctrine employed by this Court to reconcile the federal
antitrust laws and federal regulatory statutes cannot, rationally,
be put to the use for which the Court would employ it. That
doctrine, a species of the basic rule that repeals by implication
are disfavored, comes into play only when two arguably inconsistent
federal statutes are involved. "
I
mplied repeal'" of federal antitrust laws by inconsistent state
regulatory statutes is not only "
not favored,'" ante
at 428 U. S.
597-598, n. 37, it is impossible. See
U.S.Const., Art. VI, cl. 2.
A closer scrutiny of the Court's holding reveals that its
reference to the inapposite "implied repeal" doctrine is simply
window dressing for a type of judicial review radically different
from that engaged in by this Court in
Gordon v. New York Stock
Exchange, 422 U. S. 659, and
United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.
S. 321. Those cases turned exclusively on issues of
statutory construction, and involved no judicial scrutiny of the
abstract "necessity" or "centrality" of particular
Page 428 U. S. 630
regulatory provisions. Instead, the federal regulatory statute
was accepted as a given, as was the federal antitrust law. The
Court's interpretative effort was aimed at accommodating these
arguably inconsistent bodies of law, not at second-guessing
legislative judgments concerning the "necessity" for including
particular provisions in the regulatory statute.
The Court's approach here is qualitatively different. The State
of Michigan, through its Public Service Commission, has decided
that requiring Detroit Edison to provide "free" light bulbs as a
term and condition of service is in the public interest. Yet the
Court is prepared to set aside that policy determination:
"The lamp supply program is by no means . . .
imperative in the continued effective functioning of
Michigan's regulation of the utilities industry."
Ante at
428 U. S. 597
n. 36 (emphasis added). Even
"if the federal antitrust laws should be construed to outlaw
respondent's light bulb exchange program, there is no reason to
believe that Michigan's regulation of its electric utilities will
no longer be able to
function effectively. Regardless of
the outcome of this case, Michigan's interest in regulating its
utilities' distribution of electricity will be
almost entirely
unimpaired."
Ante at
428 U. S. 598
(emphasis added).
The emphasized language in these passages shows that the Court
is adopting an interpretation of the Sherman Act which will allow
the federal judiciary to substitute its judgment for that of state
legislatures and administrative agencies with respect to whether
particular anticompetitive regulatory provisions are
"
sufficiently central,'" ante at 428 U. S. 597
n. 37, to a judicial conception of the proper scope of state
utility regulation. The content of those "`purposes,'"
ibid., which the Court will suffer the States to promote
derives presumably from the mandate of the Sherman Act. On this
assumption -- and no other is plausible -- it becomes
apparent
Page 428 U. S. 631
that the Court's second reason for extending the Sherman Act to
cover the light bulb program, when divested of inapposite
references to the federal implied repeal doctrine, is merely a
restatement of the third rationale, which the Court phrases as
follows:
"[F]inally, even if we were to assume that Congress did not
intend the antitrust laws to apply to areas of the economy
primarily regulated by a State, that assumption would not foreclose
the enforcement of the antitrust laws in an essentially unregulated
area such as the market for electric light bulbs."
Ante at
428 U. S. 595.
This statement raises at last the only legitimate question, which
is whether
Parker erred in holding that Congress, in
enacting the Sherman Act, did not intend to vitiate state
regulation of the sort at issue here by creating treble damages
exposure for activities performed in compliance therewith.
The Court's rationale appears to be that the draftsmen of the
Sherman Act intended to exempt state-regulated utilities from
treble damages only to the extent those utilities are complying
with state rules which narrowly reflect the "typica[l] assum[ption]
that the [utility] is a natural monopoly," and which regulate the
utility's "natural monopoly powers," as opposed to its "business
activity in competitive areas of the economy."
Ante at
428 U. S.
595-596 (footnotes omitted). Furthermore, such
regulation must be "
sufficiently central'" to the regulation of
natural monopoly powers if it is to shield the regulated party from
antitrust liability. Ante at 428 U. S. 597
n. 37. This Delphic reading of the Sherman Act, which is unaided by
any reference to the language or legislative history of that Act,
is, of course, inconsistent with Parker v. Brown.
Parker involved a state scheme aimed at artificially
raising the market price of raisins. Raisin production is not a
"natural monopoly." If the limits of
Page 428 U. S. 632
the state action exemption from the Sherman Act are congruent
with the boundaries of "natural monopoly" power, then
Parker was wrongly decided.
But the legislative history of the Sherman Act shows
conclusively that
Parker was correctly decided. The floor
debates and the House Report on the proposed legislation clearly
reveal, as at least one commentator has noted, that "Congress fully
understood the narrow scope given to the commerce clause" in 1890.
[
Footnote 3/14] This
understanding is, in many ways, of historic interest only, because
subsequent decisions of this Court have "permitted the reach of the
Sherman Act to expand along with expanding notions of congressional
power." [
Footnote 3/15] But the
narrow view taken by the Members of Congress in 1890 remains
relevant for the limited purpose of assessing their intention
regarding the interaction of the Sherman Act and state economic
regulation.
The legislative history reveals very clearly that Congress'
perception of the limitations of its power under the Commerce
Clause was coupled with an intent not to intrude upon the authority
of the several States to regulate "domestic" commerce. As the House
Report stated:
"It will be observed that the provisions of the bill are
carefully confined to such subjects of legislation as are clearly
within the legislative authority of Congress."
"
No attempt is made to invade the legislative
authority
Page 428 U. S. 633
of the several States or even to occupy doubtful
grounds. No system of laws can be devised by Congress alone
which would effectually protect the people of the United States
against the evils and oppression of trusts and monopolies. Congress
has no authority to deal, generally, with the subject within the
States, and the States have no authority to legislate in respect of
commerce between the several States or with foreign nations."
"It follows, therefore, that the legislative authority of
Congress and that of the several States must be exerted to secure
the suppression of restraints upon trade and monopolies. Whatever
legislation Congress may enact on this subject, within the limits
of its authority, will prove of little value unless the States
shall supplement it by such auxiliary and proper legislation as may
be within their legislative authority. [
Footnote 3/16]"
Similarly, the floor debates on the proposed legislation reveal
an intent to "g[o] as far as the Constitution permits Congress to
go" [
Footnote 3/17] in the words
of Senator Sherman, conjoined with an intent not to "interfere
with" state law efforts to "prevent
and control
combinations within the limit of the State." [
Footnote 3/18] Far from demonstrating an intent to
preempt state laws aimed at preventing or controlling combinations
or monopolies, the legislative debates show that Congress' goal was
to supplement such state efforts, themselves restricted to the
geographic boundaries of the several States. As Senator Sherman
stated:
"Each State can deal with a combination within the State, but
only the General Government can deal
Page 428 U. S. 634
with combinations reaching not only the several States, but the
commercial world. This bill does not include combinations within a
State. . . . [
Footnote 3/19]"
Indeed, a preexisting body of state law forbidding combinations
in restraint of trade provided the model for the federal Act. As
Senator Sherman stated with respect to the proposed
legislation:
"It declares that certain contracts are against public policy,
null and void. It does not announce a new principle of law, but
applies old and well recognized principles of the common law to the
complicated jurisdiction of our State and Federal Government.
Similar contracts in any State in the Union are now, by common or
statute law, null and void. [
Footnote
3/20]"
It is noteworthy that the body of state jurisprudence which
formed the model for the Sherman Act coexisted with state laws
permitting regulated industries to operate under governmental
control in the public interest. Indeed, state regulatory laws long
antedated the passage of the Sherman Act and had, prior to its
passage, been upheld by this Court against constitutional attack.
[
Footnote 3/21] Such laws were an
integral part of state efforts to regulate
Page 428 U. S. 635
competition to which Congress turned for guidance in barring
restraints of interstate commerce, and it is clear that those laws
were left undisturbed by the passage of the Sherman Act in 1890.
For, as congressional spokesmen expressly stated, there was no
intent to "interfere with" state laws regulating domestic commerce
or "invade the legislative authority of the several States. . .
."
As previously noted, the intent of the draftsmen of the Sherman
Act not to intrude on the sovereignty of the States was coupled
with a full and precise understanding of the narrow scope of
congressional power under the Commerce Clause, as it was then
interpreted by decisions of this Court. Subsequent decisions of the
Court, however, have permitted the "jurisdictional" reach of the
Sherman Act to expand along with an expanding view of the commerce
power of Congress.
See Hospital Building Co. v. Rex Hospital
Trustees, 425 U. S. 738,
425 U. S. 743
n. 2, and cases cited therein. These decisions, based on a
determination that Congress intended to exercise all the power it
possessed when it enacted the Sherman Act, [
Footnote 3/22] have in effect allowed the Congress of
1890 the retroactive benefit of an enlarged judicial conception of
the commerce power. [
Footnote
3/23]
It was this retroactive expansion of the jurisdictional reach of
the Sherman Act that was in large part responsible for the advent
of the
Parker doctrine.
Parker involved a program
regulating the production of raisins
Page 428 U. S. 636
within the State of California. Under the original understanding
of the draftsmen of the Sherman Act, such in-state production, like
in-state manufacturing, would not have been subject to the
regulatory power of Congress under the Commerce Clause, and thus
not within the "jurisdictional" reach of the Sherman Act.
See
United States v. E. C. Knight Co., 156 U. S.
1. If the state of the law had remained static, the
Parker problem would rarely, if ever, have arisen. As
stated in
Northern Securities Co. v. United States,
193 U. S. 197, the
operative premise would have been that the "Anti-Trust Act . . .
prescribe[d] . . .
a rule for interstate and international
commerce, (not for domestic commerce,)"
id. at
193 U. S. 337.
The relevant question would have been whether the anticompetitive
conduct required or permitted by the state statute was in restraint
of domestic or interstate commerce. If the former, the conduct
would have been beyond the reach of the Sherman Act; if the latter,
the conduct would probably have violated the Sherman Act,
regardless of contrary state law, on the theory that
"[n]o State can, by . . . any . . . mode, project its authority
into other States, and across the continent, so as to prevent
Congress from exerting the power it possesses under the
Constitution over interstate and international commerce, or . . .
to exempt its corporation engaged in interstate commerce from
obedience to any rule lawfully established by Congress for such
commerce."
Id. at
193 U. S.
345-346.
But the law did not remain static. As one commentator has put
it:
"By 1942, when
Parker v. Brown was decided, the
interpretation and scope of the commerce clause had changed
substantially. With the development of the 'affection doctrine,'
purely intrastate events"
-- like state-mandated anticompetitive arrangements with respect
to in-state agricultural production or in-state provision of
utility services -- "could be regulated
Page 428 U. S. 637
under the commerce clause if these events had the requisite
impact on interstate commerce." [
Footnote 3/24] This development created a potential for
serious conflict between state statutes regulating commerce which,
in 1890, would have been considered "domestic" but which, in 1942,
were viewed as falling within the jurisdictional reach of the
Sherman Act. To have held that state statutes requiring
anticompetitive arrangements with respect to such commerce were
preempted by the Sherman Act would, in effect, have transformed a
generous principle of judicial construction -- namely the
"retroactive" expansion of the jurisdictional reach of the Sherman
Act to the limits of an expanded judicial conception of the
commerce power -- into a transgression of the clearly expressed
congressional intent not to intrude on the regulatory authority of
the States.
The "state action" doctrine of
Parker v. Brown, as
clarified by
Goldfarb, represents the best possible
accommodation of this limiting intent and the post-1890 judicial
expansion of the jurisdictional reach of the Sherman Act.
Parker's basic holding -- that the Sherman Act did not
intend to displace restraints imposed by the State acting as
sovereign -- coincides with the expressed legislative goal not to
"invade the legislative authority of the several States. . .. "
Goldfarb clarified
Parker by holding that private
conduct, if it is to come within the state action exemption, must
be not merely "prompted" but "compelled" by state action. Thus
refined, the doctrine performs the salutary function of isolating
those areas of state regulation where the State's sovereign
interest is, by the State's own judgment, at its strongest, and
limits the exemption to those areas. [
Footnote 3/25]
Page 428 U. S. 638
Beyond this, the Court cannot go without disregarding the
purpose of the Sherman Act not to disrupt state regulatory laws.
[
Footnote 3/26] Congress, of
course, can alter its
Page 428 U. S. 639
original intent and expand or contract the categories of state
law which may permissibly impose restraints on competition. For
example, in 1937, Congress passed the Miller-Tydings Act, which
attached a proviso to § 1 of the Sherman Act permitting resale
price maintenance contracts where such contracts were permitted by
applicable state law. This proviso was interpreted in
Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers Corp., 341 U.
S. 384, not to permit a State to enforce a law providing
that all retailers within a State were bound by a resale price
maintenance contract executed by any one retailer in the State. As
the Court today notes,
Parker -- and the legislative
judgment embodied in the 1890 version of the Sherman Act -- would,
standing alone, have seemed to immunize the state scheme.
Ante at
428 U. S. 593.
But Congress was thought to have struck a new balance in 1937 with
respect to a specific category of state-imposed restraints.
Accordingly, the Court in
Schwegmann determined
congressional intent concerning the permissible limits of state
restraints with respect to resale price maintenance by reference to
the later, and more specific, expression of congressional purpose.
[
Footnote 3/27]
Page 428 U. S. 640
There has been no analogous alteration of the original intent
regarding the area of state regulation at issue here. Indeed, to
the extent subsequent congressional action is probative at all, it
shows a continuing intent to defer to the regulatory authority of
the States over the terms and conditions of in-state electric
utility service. Thus, § 201(a) of the Federal Power Act, 16 U.S.C.
§ 824(a), provides in relevant part that "Federal regulation . . .
[is] to extend only to those matters which are not subject to
regulation by the States."
The Court's opinion simply ignores the clear evidence of
congressional intent and substitutes its own policy judgment about
the desirability of disregarding any facet of state economic
regulation that it thinks unwise or of no great importance. In
adopting this freewheeling approach to the language of the Sherman
Act, the Court creates a statutory simulacrum of the substantive
due process doctrine I thought had been put to rest long ago.
See Ferguson v. Skrupa, 372 U. S. 726.
[
Footnote 3/28] For the Court's
approach contemplates the selective interdiction of those
anticompetitive state regulatory measures that are deemed not
"central" to the limited range of regulatory goals considered
"imperative" by the federal judiciary.
Henceforth, a state-regulated public utility company must at its
peril successfully divine which of its countless and interrelated
tariff provisions a federal court will ultimately consider
"central" or "imperative." If it guesses wrong, it may be subjected
to treble damages as a penalty for its compliance with state
law.
[
Footnote 3/1]
Posner, The Proper Relationship Between State Regulation and the
Federal Antitrust Laws, 49 N.Y.U.L.Rev. 693, 728 (1974).
[
Footnote 3/2]
Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U.
S. 773,
421 U. S.
788.
[
Footnote 3/3]
The progenitor of that doctrine in this Court was
Olsen v.
Smith, 195 U. S. 332, a
decision relied on by
Parker to support the proposition
that, when a State, acting as sovereign, imposes a restraint on
commerce, that restraint does not violate the Sherman Act.
Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 352.
Olsen involved a challenge to the validity of a Texas law
fixing the charges of pilots operating in the port of Galveston and
prohibiting all but duly commissioned pilots from engaging in the
pilotage business. The Court rejected the argument that the Texas
pilotage statutes were "repugnant . . . to the laws of Congress
forbidding combinations in restraint of trade or commerce," 195
U.S. at
195 U. S.
339:
"The contention that, because the commissioned pilots have a
monopoly of the business, and by combination among themselves
exclude all others from rendering pilotage services, is also but a
denial of the authority of the State to regulate, since if the
State has the power to regulate, and in so doing to appoint and
commission, those who are to perform pilotage services, it must
follow that no monopoly or combination in a legal sense can arise
from the fact that the duly authorized agents of the State are
alone allowed to perform the duties devolving upon them by law.
When the propositions just referred to are considered in their
ultimate aspect they amount simply to the contention not that the
Texas laws are void for want of power, but that they are unwise. If
an analysis of those laws justified such conclusion -- which we do
not at all imply is the case -- the remedy is in Congress, in whom
the ultimate authority on the subject is vested, and cannot be
judicially afforded by denying the power of the State to exercise
its authority over a subject concerning which it has plenary power
until Congress has seen fit to act in the premises."
Id. at
195 U. S.
344-345.
[
Footnote 3/4]
If
Parker v. Brown, supra, could be circumvented by the
simple expedient of suing the private party against whom the
State's "anticompetitive" command runs, then that holding would
become an empty formalism, standing for little more than the
proposition that Porter Brown sued the wrong parties.
MR. JUSTICE BLACKMUN, in a separate opinion today, states that
he sees "no reason to disapprove the holding of
Parker"
ante at
428 U. S. 613
n. 5, but then proceeds to do precisely that. The holding in
Parker was that
"[t]he state, in adopting and enforcing the prorate program . .
. , imposed [a] restraint as an act of government which the Sherman
Act did not undertake to prohibit."
317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 352.
MR. JUSTICE BLACKMUN's position is that the Sherman Act does
prohibit all state-imposed restraints which do not satisfy the
Sherman Act's "rule of reason" -- a view quite different from the
holding in
Parker. The fact that the
result in
Parker could have been reached by a different route -- by
a holding, for instance, that the prorate restraint was
"reasonable" within the meaning of the Sherman Act or was impliedly
exempted by the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 -- is
simply irrelevant.
I am puzzled by MR. JUSTICE BLACKMUN's willingness to emasculate
Parker, which the Court indicated to have continued
vitality just this Term.
See Virginia Pharmacy Bd. v. Virginia
Consumer Council, 425 U. S. 748,
425 U. S. 770.
It seems to me that such a step is inconsistent not only with the
legislative history of the Sherman Act, but also with well settled
principles of
stare decisis applicable to this Court's
construction of federal statutes.
See Edelman v. Jordan,
415 U. S. 651,
415 U. S. 671
n. 14. If those principles preclude the reconsideration of an
antitrust exemption which is in every sense an "aberration" and an
"anomaly,"
Flood v. Kuhn, 407 U.
S. 258,
407 U. S. 282,
then
a fortiori they preclude the reexamination of an
exemption that coincides with a clear expression of congressional
intent.
[
Footnote 3/5]
A different approach is, of course, called for in interpreting
this Court's summary dispositions of appeals.
See generally
Hicks v. Miranda, 422 U. S. 332,
422 U. S. 345
n. 14;
Port Authority Bondholders Protective Comm. v. Port of
New York Authority, 387 F.2d 259, 262 (CA2).
[
Footnote 3/6]
California's argument began with a statement of the principle
that the Federal Government and the States -- "sister
sovereignties," Supplemental Brief for Appellants 35 in
Parker
v. Brown, O T.1942, No. 46 -- are each "supreme" when
legislating "within their respective spheres." "The subject of
Federal power is still
commerce,' -- not all commerce, but
commerce with foreign nations and among the several states."
Id. at 35-37. Incorporating by explicit reference its
preceding argument with respect to whether the Federal Agricultural
Adjustment Act of 1938 preempted the California statute,
id. at 38, and proceeding from the premise that the
subject matter of the California law was intrastate commerce within
the jurisdiction of the State, California contended that
"it should never be held that Congress intends to supersede or
suspend the exercise of the police powers of the States unless its
purpose to effect that result is clearly manifested."
Ibid. California added that
"[s]uch an intent should be even more clear and express when it
serves not only to suspend the police powers, but to subject the
sovereignty of the State to the inhibition and penalties of
Congressional action."
Id. at 38-39.
The plurality's position today seems to be that, because the
State of California placed particular emphasis on the fact that the
proscriptions of the Sherman Act, if applicable, would run directly
against the State, California's argument in the first part of its
brief was simply and solely that "Congress never intended to
subject a sovereign State to the provisions of the Sherman Act. . .
."
Ante at
428 U. S. 588.
Yet, as the preceding quotations show, California's argument in the
first part of its brief dovetailed two interrelated themes: first,
that state regulation of intrastate commerce was not preempted by
the Sherman Act and, second, that the framers of the Sherman Act
did not intend its proscriptions to run directly against the
sovereign States. It was the first of these themes that California
deemed primary. Near the close of the first part of California's
brief appeared the following passage:
"To hold the State within the prohibition of the Sherman Act in
the present instance would result in prohibiting it from exercising
its otherwise valid police powers. This Court has repeatedly and
emphatically stated that"
"it should never be held that Congress intends to supersede or
by its legislation suspend the exercise of the police powers of the
State, even when it may do so, unless its purpose to effect that
result is clearly manifested."
Supplemental Brief for Appellants 47-48 in
Parker v.
Brown, O.T. 1942, No. 46 (footnote omitted).
[
Footnote 3/7]
This distinction was properly drawn, as is apparent from
decisions in the labor law context. A State or political
subdivision thereof is not normally subject to the prohibitions of
the National Labor Relations Act, 49 Stat. 449, as amended, 29
U.S.C. § 151
et seq. See, e.g., NLRB v. Natural Gas
Utility Dist., 402 U. S. 600. But
it certainly does not follow that sovereign enactments of the State
may not be deemed preempted by the federal legislation.
San
Diego Unions v. Garmon, 359 U. S. 236;
Garner v. Teamsters, 346 U. S. 485.
[
Footnote 3/8]
The Solicitor General began his analysis with the following
statement:
"A state statute permitting, or requiring, dealers in a
commodity to combine so as to limit the supply or raise the price
of a subject of interstate commerce would clearly be void. The
question here is whether a state may itself undertake to control
the supply and price of a commodity shipped in interstate commerce
or otherwise restrain interstate competition through a mandatory
regulation."
Brief for United States as
Amicus Curiae 63 in
Parker v. Brown, O.T. 1942, No. 46. He then acknowledged
that
"[i]t seems clear that Congress, when it enacted the statute,
did not intend to deprive the states of their normal 'police'
powers over business and industry. . . . For example, in the field
of public utilities, a state can undoubtedly regulate rates without
running afoul of the Sherman Act notwithstanding the fact that the
rate regulation may embrace interstate commerce."
Id. at 63-64 (footnotes and citations omitted). But,
the Solicitor General continued,
"[a]lthough Congress plainly did not regard local laws in these
fields as incompatible with the Sherman Act, we believe that the
same cannot be said when the state statute is designed directly to
control the competitive aspects of an industry in a manner which
will have more than local effect."
Id. at 64-65. This was the critical portion of the
Solicitor General's argument, which sought to draw a delicate
distinction between acceptable police power legislation, such as
public utility regulation, and preempted police power legislation,
such as that designed explicitly to suppress competition affecting
interstate commerce.
[
Footnote 3/9]
The only exception is where the attempt to influence state
regulation is a "sham" aimed at "harass[ing] and deter[ring] . . .
competitors from having
free and unlimited access' to the
agencies and courts. . . ."
California Motor Transport Co. v. Trucking Unlimited,
404 U. S. 508,
404 U. S.
515.
[
Footnote 3/10]
The Court's reliance on
Jackson v. Metropolitan Edison
Co., 419 U. S. 345, is
misplaced. There, the Court held that a utility's discontinuance of
service to a customer for nonpayment of bills was not "state
action" sufficient to trigger the protections of the Due Process
Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment. The petitioner had argued that,
because the State Public Utility Commission had approved that
practice as a part of the respondent's general tariff, the
termination was "state action" for Fourteenth Amendment purposes.
Id. at
419 U. S. 354.
The Court disagreed, holding as follows:
"The nature of governmental regulation of private utilities is
such that a utility may frequently be required by the state
regulatory scheme to obtain approval for practices a business
regulated in less detail would be free to institute without any
approval from a regulatory body. Approval by a state utility
commission of such a request from a regulated utility, where the
Commission has not put its own weight on the side of the proposed
practice by ordering it, does not transmute a practice initiated by
the utility and approved by the Commission into 'state action.' At
most, the Commission's failure to overturn this practice amounted
to no more than a determination that a Pennsylvania utility was
authorized to employ such a practice if it so desired. Respondent's
exercise of the choice allowed by state law where the initiative
comes from it, and not from the State, does not make its action in
doing so 'state action' for purposes of the Fourteenth
Amendment."
Id. at
419 U. S. 357
(footnote omitted). This constitutional holding has no bearing on
whether a utility's action in compliance with a tariff which it
proposed is exempt from Sherman Act liability. The latter is a
question of legislative intent, not constitutional law, and must be
answered on the basis of a separate line of authority -- namely,
decisions such as
Parker and
Noerr which have
construed the Sherman Act.
[
Footnote 3/11]
I disagree with THE CHIEF JUSTICE's conclusion that Michigan's
policy is "neutral" with respect to whether a utility should have a
lamp exchange program.
See 428
U.S. 579fn3/26|>n. 26,
infra. Moreover, I think it
is apparent that insistence on statutory articulation of a state
"purpose" to regulate activities performed incident to the
provision of a "natural monopoly" service will lead to serious
interference with state regulation.
See ibid.
[
Footnote 3/12]
As the Court noted in
Noerr, the scheme at issue in
Parker required popular initiative. 365 U.S. at
365 U. S.
137-138, n. 17. And as it further noted,
Parker
itself expressly rejected the argument that the necessity for
private initiative affected the "program's validity under the
Sherman Act. . . ."
Id. at
365 U. S.
137
[
Footnote 3/13]
The Court seems to indicate at one point that it would be
improper to "superimpose" antitrust liability on state regulatory
schemes aimed at
suppressing competition and
raising prices.
See ante at
428 U. S. 595
("Unquestionably there are examples of economic regulation in which
the very purpose of the government control is to avoid the
consequences of unrestrained competition. Agricultural marketing
programs, such as that involved in
Parker, were of that
character"). But some state regulation, the Court continues, aims
not at suppressing competition, but rather at duplicating the
effects of competition --
i.e., keeping prices down. With
respect to state regulation of the latter type, the state scheme
will not afford an exemption to the extent the regulated party is
engaged in "business activity in competitive areas of the economy."
Ante at
428 U. S. 596
(footnote omitted).
This rationale will not bear its own weight. If compliance with
a state program aimed at
suppressing competition in
nonmonopoly industries --
i.e., raisin production --
cannot give rise to Sherman Act liability, then surely compliance
with a state program aimed at controlling the terms and conditions
of service performed incident to the provision of a "natural
monopoly" product cannot give rise to treble damages.
[
Footnote 3/14]
Slater, Antitrust and Government Action: A Formula for Narrowing
Parker v. Brown, 69 Nw.U.L.Rev. 71, 84 (1974).
See,
e.g., 20 Cong.Rec. 1169 (1889) (remarks of Sen. Reagan);
id. at 1458 (remarks of Sen. George); 21 Cong.Rec. 2467
(1890) (remarks of Sen. Hiscock);
id. at 2469-2470
(remarks of Sen. Reagan);
id. at 2566 (remarks of Sen.
Stewart);
id. at 2567 (remarks of Sen. Hoar);
id.
at 2600 (remarks of Sen. George).
[
Footnote 3/15]
Hospital Building Co. v. Rex Hospital Trustees,
425 U. S. 738,
[
Footnote 3/16]
H.R.Rep. No. 1707, 51st Cong., 1st Sess., 1 (1890) (emphasis
added).
[
Footnote 3/17]
20 Cong.Rec. 1167 (1889).
[
Footnote 3/18]
21 Cong.Rec. 2456 (1890) (emphasis added).
[
Footnote 3/19]
Id. at 2460.
[
Footnote 3/20]
Id. at 2456.
[
Footnote 3/21]
See Munn v. Illinois, 94 U. S. 113,
94 U. S. 125
("Under [the police] powers, the government regulates the conduct
of its citizens one towards another, and the manner in which each
shall use his own property, when such regulation becomes necessary
for the public good. In their exercise, it has been customary in
England from time immemorial, and in this country from its first
colonization, to regulate ferries, common carriers, hackmen,
bakers, millers, wharfingers, innkeepers, &c., and, in so
doing, to fix a maximum of charge to be made for services rendered,
accommodations furnished, and articles sold. To this day, statutes
are to be found in many of the States upon some or all these
subjects; and we think it has never yet been successfully contended
that such legislation came within any of the constitutional
prohibitions against interference with private property").
[
Footnote 3/22]
E.g., United States v. Frankfort Distilleries,
324 U. S. 293,
324 U. S. 298;
United States v. Underwriters Assn., 322 U.
S. 533,
322 U. S. 558;
Atlantic Cleaners & Dyers v. United States,
286 U. S. 427,
286 U. S. 435.
See also United States v. American Bldg. Maint.
Industries, 422 U. S. 271,
422 U. S. 278;
Gulf Oil Corp. v. Copp Paving Co., 419 U.
S. 186,
419 U. S.
194-195.
[
Footnote 3/23]
See Hospital Building Co. v. Rex Hospital Trustees, 426
U.S. at
426 U. S. 743
n. 2;
Gulf Oil Corp. v. Copp Paving Co., supra at
419 U. S.
201-202;
Mandeville Island Farms v. American Crystal
Sugar Co., 334 U. S. 219,
334 U. S.
229-235.
[
Footnote 3/24]
Slater,
supra, 428
U.S. 579fn3/14|>n. 14, at 85.
[
Footnote 3/25]
MR. JUSTICE BLACKMUN expresses the view that the Court answered
the question of "what was to be the result if the expanding ambit
of the Sherman Act should bring it into conflict with inconsistent
state law" in
Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers
Corp., 341 U. S. 384, and
that the answer it gave was that any state regulatory statute
"inconsistent" with the judicially expanded Sherman Act as
preempted.
Ante at
428 U. S. 606.
But the opinion in
Schwegmann -- which did not purport to
modify or overrule
Parker -- is most plausibly read as
resting on a post-1890 expression of congressional intent, the
Miller-Tydings Act.
See infra at
428 U. S. 639.
Even assuming, however, that
Schwegmann conflicted with
Parker, then surely the most significant aspect of that
conflict is that Congress did not allow it to persist, as
Schwegmann was soon legislatively overruled by the
enactment of the McGuire bill, 66 Stat. 632, 15 U.S.C. §§
45(a)(2)-(5)
[
Footnote 3/26]
The Court states at one point that the omission of a "direct
reference to light bulbs" in the statute creating the Michigan
Public Service Commission indicates that the State's policy is
"neutral on the question whether a utility should, or should not,
have such a program."
Ante at
428 U. S. 584,
428 U. S. 585.
This statement seems to suggest that the Court considers the
specificity with which a state legislature deals with particular
regulatory matters to be relevant in determining whether agency
action respecting such matters represents a sovereign choice,
entitled to deference under the Sherman Act.
This suggestion overlooks the fact that Michigan's policy, far
from being "neutral," is, as announced in Mich.Comp.Laws § 460.6
(1970), to vest an expert agency "with complete power and
jurisdiction to regulate all public utilities in the state. . . ."
That agency is
"vested with power and jurisdiction to regulate all rates,
fares, fees, charges,
services, rules,
conditions of
service and all other matters pertaining to the formation,
operation or direction of such public utilities. It is further
granted the power and jurisdiction to hear and pass upon all
matters pertaining to or necessary or incident to such regulation
of all public utilities, including electric light and power
companies. . . ."
Ibid. (emphasis added).
If a state legislature can ensure antitrust exemption only by
eschewing such broad delegation of regulatory authority and
incorporating regulatory details into statutory law, then there is
a very great risk that the State will be prevented from regulating
effectively. For as this Court has repeatedly observed in another
context,
"[d]elegation . . . has long been recognized as necessary in
order that the exertion of legislative power does not become a
futility. . . . [T]he effectiveness of both the legislative and
administrative processes would become endangered if [the
legislature] were under the . . . compulsion of filling in the
details beyond the liberal prescription [of requiring the making of
'just and reasonable' rates and regulating in the 'public
interest'] here. Then the burdens of minutiae would be apt to clog
the administration of the law and deprive the agency of that
flexibility and dispatch which are its salient virtues."
Sunshine Anthracite Coal Co. v. Adkins, 310 U.
S. 381,
310 U. S.
398.
[
Footnote 3/27]
The decision in
Schwegmann rested primarily on a
detailed analysis of the legislative history of the Miller-Tydings
Act. 341 U.S. at
341 U. S.
390-395.
[
Footnote 3/28]
See Verkuil, State Action, Due Process and Antitrust:
Reflection on
Parker v. Brown, 75 Col.L.Rev. 328
(1975).