NOTICE: This opinion is subject to
formal revision before publication in the preliminary print of the
United States Reports. Readers are requested to notify the Reporter
of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States, Washington,
D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in
order that corrections may be made before the preliminary print
goes to press.
SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
_________________
No. 15–214
_________________
JOSEPH P. MURR, et al., PETITIONERS
v. WISCONSIN, et al.
on writ of certiorari to the court of appeals
of wisconsin, district iii
[June 23, 2017]
Justice Kennedy delivered the opinion of the
Court.
The classic example of a property taking by the
government is when the property has been occupied or otherwise
seized. In the case now before the Court, petition-ers contend that
governmental entities took their real property—an undeveloped
residential lot—not by some physical occupation but instead by
enacting burdensome regulations that forbid its improvement or
separate sale because it is classified as substandard in size. The
relevant governmental entities are the respondents.
Against the background justifications for the
challenged restrictions, respondents contend there is no regulatory
taking because petitioners own an adjacent lot. The regulations, in
effecting a merger of the property, permit the continued
residential use of the property including for a single improvement
to extend over both lots. This retained right of the landowner,
respondents urge, is of sufficient offsetting value that the
regulation is not severe enough to be a regulatory taking. To
resolve the issue whether the landowners can insist on confining
the analysis just to the lot in question, without regard to their
ownership of the adjacent lot, it is necessary to discuss the
background principles that define regulatory takings.
I
A
The St. Croix River originates in northwest
Wisconsin and flows approximately 170 miles until it joins the
Mississippi River, forming the boundary between Minnesota and
Wisconsin for much of its length. The lower portion of the river
slows and widens to create a natural water area known as Lake St.
Croix. Tourists and residents of the region have long extolled the
picturesque grandeur of the river and surrounding area.
E.g., E. Ellett, Summer Rambles in the West 136–137
(1853).
Under the Wild and Scenic Rivers Act, the river
was designated, by 1972, for federal protection. §3(a)(6), 82Stat.
908, 16 U. S. C. §1274(a)(6) (designating Upper St. Croix
River); Lower Saint Croix River Act of 1972, §2, 86Stat. 1174, 16
U. S. C. §1274(a)(9) (adding Lower St. Croix River). The
law required the States of Wisconsin and Minnesota to develop “a
management and development program” for the river area. 41 Fed.
Reg. 26237 (1976). In compliance, Wisconsin authorized the State
Department of Natural Resources to promulgate rules limiting
development in order to “guarantee the protection of the wild,
scenic and recreational qualities of the river for present and
future generations.” Wis. Stat. §30.27(l) (1973).
Petitioners are two sisters and two brothers in
the Murr family. Petitioners’ parents arranged for them to receive
ownership of two lots the family used for recreation along the
Lower St. Croix River in the town of Troy, Wisconsin. The lots are
adjacent, but the parents purchased them separately, put the title
of one in the name of the family business, and later arranged for
transfer of the two lots, on different dates, to petitioners. The
lots, which are referred to in this litigation as Lots E and F, are
described in more detail below.
For the area where petitioners’ property is
located, the Wisconsin rules prevent the use of lots as separate
building sites unless they have at least one acre of land suitable
for development. Wis. Admin. Code §§ NR 118.04(4),
118.03(27), 118.06(1)(a)(2)(a), 118.06(1)(b) (2017). A grand-father
clause relaxes this restriction for substandardlots which were “in
separate ownership from abutting lands” on January 1, 1976, the
effective date of the regulation. § NR 118.08(4)(a)(1).
The clause permits the use of qualifying lots as separate building
sites. The rules also include a merger provision, however, which
provides that adjacent lots under common ownership may not be “sold
or developed as separate lots” if they do not meet the size
requirement. § NR 118.08(4)(a)(2). The Wisconsin rules
require localities to adopt parallel provisions, see
§ NR 118.02(3), so the St. Croix County zoning ordinance
contains identical restrictions, see St. Croix County, Wis.,
Ordinance §17.36I.4.a (2005). The Wisconsin rules also authorize
the local zoning authority to grant variances from the regulations
where enforcement would create “unnecessary hardship.”
§ NR 118.09(4)(b); St. Croix County Ordinance
§17.09.232.
B
Petitioners’ parents purchased Lot F in 1960
and built a small recreational cabin on it. In 1961, they
transferred title to Lot F to the family plumbing company. In 1963,
they purchased neighboring Lot E, which they held in their own
names.
The lots have the same topography. A steep bluff
cuts through the middle of each, with level land suitable for
development above the bluff and next to the water below it. The
line dividing Lot E from Lot F runs from the riverfront to the far
end of the property, crossing the blufftop along the way. Lot E has
approximately 60 feet of river frontage, and Lot F has
approximately 100 feet. Though each lot is approximately 1.25 acres
in size, because of the waterline and the steep bank they each have
less than one acre of land suitable for development. Even when
combined, the lots’ buildable land area is only 0.98 acres due to
the steep terrain.
The lots remained under separate ownership, with
Lot F owned by the plumbing company and Lot E owned by petitioners’
parents, until transfers to petitioners. Lot F was conveyed to them
in 1994, and Lot E was conveyed to them in 1995.
Murr v.
St. Croix County Bd. of Adjustment, 2011 WI App 29, 332 Wis.
2d 172, 177–178, 184–185, 796 N. W. 2d 837, 841, 844 (2011);
2015 WI App 13, 359 Wis. 2d 675, 859 N. W. 2d 628 (unpublished
opinion), App. to Pet. for Cert. A–3, ¶¶4–5. (There are certain
ambiguities in the record concerning whether the lots had merged
earlier, but the parties and the courts below appear to have
assumed the merger occurred upon transfer to petitioners.)
A decade later, petitioners became interested in
moving the cabin on Lot F to a different portion of the lot and
selling Lot E to fund the project. The unification of the lots
under common ownership, however, had implicated the state and local
rules barring their separate sale or development. Petitioners then
sought variances from the St. Croix County Board of Adjustment to
enable their building and improvement plan, including a variance to
allow the separate sale or use of the lots. The Board denied the
requests, and the state courts affirmed in relevant part. In
particular, the Wisconsin Court of Appeals agreed with the Board’s
interpretation that the local ordinance “effectively merged” Lots E
and F, so petitioners “could only sell or build on the single
larger lot.”
Murr,
supra, at 184, 796 N. W. 2d,
at 844.
Petitioners filed the present action in state
court, alleging that the state and county regulations worked a
regulatory taking by depriving them of “all, or practically all, of
the use of Lot E because the lot cannot be sold or developed as a
separate lot.” App. 9. The parties each submitted appraisal numbers
to the trial court. Respondents’ appraisal included values of
$698,300 for the lots together as regulated; $771,000 for the lots
as two distinct build-able properties; and $373,000 for Lot F as a
single lot with improvements. Record 17–55, 17–56. Petitioners’
appraisal included an unrebutted, estimated value of $40,000 for
Lot E as an undevelopable lot, based on the counterfactual
assumption that it could be sold as a separate property.
Id., at 22–188.
The Circuit Court of St. Croix County granted
summary judgment to the State, explaining that petitioners retained
“several available options for the use and enjoyment of their
property.” Case No. 12–CV–258 (Oct. 31, 2013), App. to Pet. for
Cert. B–9. For example, they could preserve the existing cabin,
relocate the cabin, or eliminate the cabin and build a new
residence on Lot E, on Lot F, or across both lots. The court also
found petitioners had not been deprived of all economic value of
their property. Considering the valuation of the property as a
single lot versus two separate lots, the court found the market
value of the property was not significantly affected by the
regulations because the decrease in value was less than 10 percent.
Ibid.
The Wisconsin Court of Appeals affirmed. The
court explained that the regulatory takings inquiry required it to
“ ‘first determine what, precisely, is the property at
issue.’ ”
Id., at A–9, ¶17. Relying on Wisconsin
Supreme Court precedent in
Zealy v.
Waukesha, 201
Wis. 2d 365, 548 N. W. 2d 528 (1996), the Court of Appeals
rejected petitioners’ request to analyze the effect of the
regulations on Lot E only. Instead, the court held the takings
analysis “properly focused” on the regulations’ effect “on the
Murrs’ property as a whole”—that is, Lots E and F together. App. to
Pet. for Cert. A–12, ¶22.
Using this framework, the Court of Appeals
concluded the merger regulations did not effect a taking. In
particular, the court explained that petitioners could not
reasonably have expected to use the lots separately because they
were “ ‘charged with knowledge of the existing zoning
laws’ ” when they acquired the property.
Ibid. (quoting
Murr,
supra, at 184, 796 N. W. 2d, at 844).
Thus, “even if [petitioners] did intend to develop or sell Lot E
separately, that expectation of separate treatment became
unreasonable when they chose to acquire Lot E in 1995, after their
having acquired Lot F in 1994.” App. to Pet. for Cert. A–17,
¶30
. The court also discounted the severity of the economic
impact on petitioners’ property, recognizing the Circuit Court’s
conclusion that the regulations diminished the property’s combined
value by less than 10 percent. The Supreme Court of Wisconsin
denied discretionary review. This Court granted certiorari, 577
U. S. ___ (2016).
II
A
The Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment
provides that private property shall not “be taken for public use,
without just compensation.” The Clause is made applicable to the
States through the Fourteenth Amendment.
Chicago, B. & Q. R.
Co. v.
Chicago, 166 U. S. 226 (1897) . As this
Court has recognized, the plain language of the Takings Clause
“requires the payment of compensation whenever the government
acquires private property for a public purpose,” see
Tahoe-Sierra Preservation Council, Inc. v.
Tahoe Regional
Planning Agency, 535 U. S. 302, 321 (2002) , but it does
not address in specific terms the imposition of regulatory burdens
on private property
. Indeed, “[p]rior to Justice Holmes’s
exposition in
Pennsylvania Coal Co. v.
Mahon, 260
U. S. 393 (1922) , it was generally thought that the Takings
Clause reached only a direct appropriation of property, or the
functional equivalent of a practical ouster of the owner’s
possession,” like the permanent flooding of property.
Lucas
v.
South Carolina Coastal Council, 505 U. S. 1003, 1014
(1992) (citation, brackets, and internal quotation marks omitted);
accord,
Horne v.
Department of Agriculture, 576
U. S. ___, ___ (2015) (slip op., at 7); see also
Loretto v.
Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp., 458
U. S. 419, 427 (1982) .
Mahon, however, initiated this
Court’s regulatory takings jurisprudence, declaring that “while
property may be regulated to a certain extent, if regulation goes
too far it will be recognized as a taking.” 260 U. S., at 415.
A regulation, then, can be so burdensome as to become a taking, yet
the
Mahon Court did not formulate more detailed guidance for
determining when this limit is reached.
In the near century since
Mahon, the
Court for the most part has refrained from elaborating this
principle through definitive rules. This area of the law has been
characterized by “ad hoc, factual inquiries, designed to allow
careful examination and weighing of all the relevant
circumstances.”
Tahoe-Sierra,
supra, at 322 (citation
and internal quotation marks omitted). The Court has, however,
stated two guidelines relevant here for determining when government
regulation is so onerous that it constitutes a taking. First, “with
certain qualifications . . . a regulation which ‘denies
all economically beneficial or productive use of land’ will require
compensation under the Takings Clause.”
Palazzolo v.
Rhode Island, 533 U. S. 606, 617 (2001) (quoting
Lucas,
supra, at 1015). Second, when a regulation
impedes the use of property without depriving the owner of all
economically beneficial use, a taking still may be found based on
“a complex of factors,” including (1) the economic impact of the
regulation on the claimant; (2) the extent to which the regulation
has interfered with distinct investment-backed expectations; and
(3) the character of the governmental action.
Palazzolo,
supra, at 617 (citing
Penn Central Transp. Co. v.
New
York City, 438 U. S. 104, 124 (1978) ).
By declaring that the denial of all economically
beneficial use of land constitutes a regulatory taking,
Lucas stated what it called a “categorical” rule. See 505
U. S., at 1015. Even in
Lucas, however, the Court
included a ca-veat recognizing the relevance of state law and
land-use customs: The complete deprivation of use will not re-quire
compensation if the challenged limitations “inhere . . .
in the restrictions that background principles of the State’s law
of property and nuisance already placed upon land ownership.”
Id., at 1029; see also
id., at 1030–1031 (listing
factors for courts to consider in making thisdetermination).
A central dynamic of the Court’s regulatory
takings jurisprudence, then, is its flexibility. This has been and
remains a means to reconcile two competing objectives central to
regulatory takings doctrine. One is the individual’s right to
retain the interests and exercise the freedoms at the core of
private property ownership. Cf.
id., at 1028 (“[T]he notion
. . . that title is somehow held subject to the ‘implied
limitation’ that the State may subsequently eliminate all
economically valuable use is inconsistent with the historical
compact recorded in the Takings Clause that has become part of our
constitutional culture”). Property rights are necessary to preserve
freedom, for property ownership empowers persons to shape and to
plan their own destiny in a world where governments are always
eager to do so for them.
The other persisting interest is the
government’s well-established power to “adjus[t] rights for the
public good.”
Andrus v.
Allard, 444 U. S. 51, 65
(1979) . As Justice Holmes declared, “Government hardly could go on
if to some extent values incident to property could not be
diminished without paying for every such change in the general
law.”
Mahon,
supra, at 413. In adjudicating
regulatory takings cases a proper balancing of these principles
requires a careful inquiry informed by the specifics of the case.
In all instances, the analysis must be driven “by the purpose of
the Takings Clause, which is to prevent the government from
‘forcing some people alone to bear public burdens which, in all
fairness and justice, should be borne by the public as a
whole.’ ”
Palazzolo,
supra, at 617–618 (quoting
Armstrong v.
United States, 364 U. S. 40, 49
(1960) ).
B
This case presents a question that is linked
to the ultimate determination whether a regulatory taking has
occurred: What is the proper unit of property against which to
assess the effect of the challenged governmental action? Put
another way, “[b]ecause our test for regulatory taking requires us
to compare the value that has been taken from the property with the
value that remains in the property, one of the critical questions
is determining how to define the unit of property ‘whose value is
to furnish the denominator of the fraction.’ ”
Keystone
Bituminous Coal Assn. v.
DeBenedictis, 480 U. S.
470, 497 (1987) (quoting Michelman, Property, Utility, and
Fairness, 80 Harv. L. Rev. 1165, 1992 (1967)).
As commentators have noted, the answer to this
question may be outcome determinative. See Eagle, The Four-Factor
Penn Central Regulatory Takings Test, 118 Pa. St.
L. Rev. 601, 631 (2014); see also Wright, A New Time for
Denominators, 34 Env. L. 175, 180 (2004). This Court, too, has
explained that the question is important to the regulatory takings
inquiry. “To the extent that any portion of property is taken, that
portion is always taken in its entirety; the relevant question,
however, is whether the property taken is all, or only a portion
of, the parcel in question.”
Concrete Pipe & Products of
Cal., Inc. v.
Construction Laborers Pension Trust for
Southern Cal., 508 U. S. 602, 644 (1993) .
Defining the property at the outset, however,
should not necessarily preordain the outcome in every case. In
some, though not all, cases the effect of the challenged regulation
must be assessed and understood by the effect on the entire
property held by the owner, rather than just some part of the
property that, considered just on its own, has been diminished in
value. This demonstrates the contrast between regulatory takings,
where the goal is usually to determine how the challenged
regulation affects the property’s value to the owner, and physical
takings, where the impact of physical appropriation or occupation
of the property will be evident.
While the Court has not set forth specific
guidance on how to identify the relevant parcel for the regulatory
taking inquiry, there are two concepts which the Court has
indicated can be unduly narrow.
First, the Court has declined to limit the
parcel in an artificial manner to the portion of property targeted
by the challenged regulation. In
Penn Central, for example,
the Court rejected a challenge to the denial of a permit to build
an office tower above Grand Central Terminal. The Court refused to
measure the effect of the denial only against the “air rights”
above the terminal, cautioning that “ ‘[t]aking’ jurisprudence
does not divide a single parcel into discrete segments and attempt
to determine whether rights in a particular segment have been
entirely abrogated.” 438 U. S., at 130.
In a similar way, in
Tahoe-Sierra, the
Court refused to “effectively sever” the 32 months during which
petitioners’ property was restricted by temporary moratoria on
development “and then ask whether that segment ha[d] been taken in
its entirety.” 535 U. S., at 331. That was because “defining
the property interest taken in terms of the very regulation being
challenged is circular.”
Ibid. That approach would overstate
the effect of regulation on property, turning “every delay” into a
“total ban.”
Ibid.
The second concept about which the Court has
expressed caution is the view that property rights under the
Takings Clause should be coextensive with those under state law.
Although property interests have their foundations in state law,
the
Palazzolo Court reversed a state- court decision that
rejected a takings challenge to regulations that predated the
landowner’s acquisition of title. 533 U. S., at 626–627. The
Court explained that States do not have the unfettered authority to
“shape and define property rights and reasonable investment-backed
expectations,” leaving landowners without recourse against
unreasonable regulations.
Id., at 626.
By the same measure, defining the parcel by
reference to state law could defeat a challenge even to a state
enactment that alters permitted uses of property in ways
inconsistent with reasonable investment-backed expectations. For
example, a State might enact a law that consolidates nonadjacent
property owned by a single person or entity in different parts of
the State and then imposes development limits on the aggregate set.
If a court defined the parcel according to the state law requiring
consolidation, this improperly would fortify the state law against
a takings claim, because the court would look to the retained value
in the property as a whole rather than considering whether
individual holdings had lost all value.
III
A
As the foregoing discussion makes clear, no
single consideration can supply the exclusive test for determining
the denominator. Instead, courts must consider a number of factors.
These include the treatment of the land under state and local law;
the physical characteristics of the land; and the prospective value
of the regulated land. The endeavor should determine whether
reasonable expectations about property ownership would lead a
landowner to anticipate that his holdings would be treated as one
parcel, or, instead, as separate tracts. The inquiry is objective,
and the reasonable expectations at issue derive from background
customs and the whole of our legal tradition. Cf.
Lucas, 505
U. S., at 1035 (Kennedy, J., concurring) (“The expectations
protected by the Constitution are based on objective rules and
customs that can be understood as reasonable by all parties
involved”).
First, courts should give substantial weight to
the treatment of the land, in particular how it is bounded or
divided, under state and local law. The reasonable expectations of
an acquirer of land must acknowledge legitimate restrictions
affecting his or her subsequent use and dispensation of the
property. See
Ballard v.
Hunter, 204 U. S. 241,
262 (1907) (“Of what concerns or may concern their real estate men
usually keep informed, and on that probability the law may frame
its proceedings”). A valid takings claim will not evaporate just
because a purchaser took title after the law was enacted. See
Palazzolo, 533 U. S., at 627 (some “enactments are
unreasonable and do not become less so through passage of time or
title”). A reasonable restriction that predates a landowner’s
acquisition, however, can be one of the objective factors that most
landowners would reasonably consider in forming fair expectations
about their property. See
ibid. (“[A] prospective enactment,
such as a new zoning ordinance, can limit the value of land without
effecting a taking because it can be understood as reasonable by
all concerned”). Ina similar manner, a use restriction which is
triggeredonly after, or because of, a change in ownership should
also guide a court’s assessment of reasonable private
expectations.
Second, courts must look to the physical
characteristics of the landowner’s property. These include the
physical relationship of any distinguishable tracts, the parcel’s
topography, and the surrounding human and ecological environment.
In particular, it may be relevant that the property is located in
an area that is subject to, or likely to become subject to,
environmental or other regulation. Cf.
Lucas,
supra,
at 1035 (Kennedy, J., concurring) (“Coastal property may present
such unique concerns for a fragile land system that the State can
go further in regulating its development and use than the common
law of nuisance might otherwise permit”).
Third, courts should assess the value of the
property under the challenged regulation, with special attention to
the effect of burdened land on the value of other holdings. Though
a use restriction may decrease the market value of the property,
the effect may be tempered if the regulated land adds value to the
remaining property, such as by increasing privacy, expanding
recreational space, or preserving surrounding natural beauty. A law
that limits use of a landowner’s small lot in one part of the city
by reason of the landowner’s nonadjacent holdings elsewhere may
decrease the market value of the small lot in an unmitigated
fashion. The absence of a special relationship between the holdings
may counsel against consideration of all the holdings as a single
parcel, making the restrictive law susceptible to a takings
challenge. On the other hand, if the landowner’s other property is
adjacent to the small lot, the market value of the properties may
well increase if their combination enables the expansion of a
structure, or if development restraints for one part of the parcel
protect the unobstructed skyline views of another part. That, in
turn, may counsel in favor of treatment as a single parcel and may
reveal the weakness of a regulatory takings challenge to the
law.
State and federal courts have considerable
experience in adjudicating regulatory takings claims that depart
from these examples in various ways. The Court anticipates that in
applying the test above they will continue to exercise care in this
complex area.
B
The State of Wisconsin and petitioners each
ask this Court to adopt a formalistic rule to guide the parcel
inquiry. Neither proposal suffices to capture the central legal and
factual principles that inform reasonable expectations about
property interests.
Wisconsin would tie the definition of the parcel
to state law, considering the two lots here as a single whole due
to their merger under the challenged regulations. That approach, as
already noted, simply assumes the answer to the question: May the
State define the relevant parcel in a way that permits it to escape
its responsibility to justify regulation in light of legitimate
property expectations? It is, of course, unquestionable that the
law must recognize those legitimate expectations in order to give
proper weight to the rights of owners and the right of the State to
pass reasonable laws and regulations. See
Palazzolo,
supra, at 627.
Wisconsin bases its position on a footnote in
Lucas, which suggests the answer to the denominator question
“may lie in how the owner’s reasonable expectations have been
shaped by the State’s law of property—
i.e., whether and to
what degree the State’s law has accorded legal recognition and
protection to the particular interest in land with respect to which
the takings claimant alleges a diminution in (or elimination of)
value.” 505 U. S., at 1017, n. 7. As an initial matter,
Lucas referenced the parcel problem only in dicta,
unnecessary to the announcement or application of the rule it
established. See
ibid. (“[W]e avoid th[e] difficulty” of
determining the relevant parcel “in the present case”). In any
event, the test the Court adopts today is consistent with the
respect for state law described in
Lucas. The test considers
state law but in addition weighs whether the state enactments at
issue accord with other indicia of reasonable expectations about
property.
Petitioners propose a different test that is
also flawed. They urge the Court to adopt a presumption that lot
lines define the relevant parcel in every instance, making Lot E
the necessary denominator. Petitioners’ argument, however, ignores
the fact that lot lines are themselves creatures of state law,
which can be overridden by the State in the reasonable exercise of
its power. In effect, petitioners ask this Court to credit the
aspect of state law that favors their preferred result (lot lines)
and ignore that which does not (merger provision).
This approach contravenes the Court’s case law,
which recognizes that reasonable land-use regulations do not work a
taking. See
Palazzolo, 533 U. S., at 627;
Mahon,
260 U. S., at 413. Among other cases,
Agins v.
City
of Tiburon, 447 U. S. 255 (1980) , demonstrates the
validity of this proposition because it upheld zoning regulations
as a legitimate exercise of the government’s police power. Of
course, the Court’s later opinion in
Lingle v.
Chevron
U. S. A. Inc. recognized that the test articulated in
Agins—that regulation effects a taking if it “ ‘does
not substantially advance legitimate state interests’ ”—was
improper because it invited courts to engage in heightened review
of the effectiveness of government regulation. 544 U. S. 528,
540 (2005) (quoting
Agins,
supra, at 260).
Lingle made clear, however, that the holding of
Agins
survived, even if its test was “imprecis[e].” See 544 U. S.,
at 545–546, 548.
The merger provision here is likewise a
legitimate exercise of government power, as reflected by its
consistency with a long history of state and local merger
regulations that originated nearly a century ago. See Brief for
National Association of Counties et al. as
Amici Curiae
5–10. Merger provisions often form part of a regulatory scheme that
establishes a minimum lot size in order to preserve open space
while still allowing orderly development. See E. McQuillin, Law of
Municipal Corporations §25:24 (3d ed. 2010); see also
Agins,
supra, at 262 (challenged “zoning ordinances benefit[ed] the
appellants as well as the public by serving the city’s interest in
assuring careful and orderly development of residential property
with provision for open-space areas”).
When States or localities first set a minimum
lot size, there often are existing lots that do not meet the new
requirements, and so local governments will strive to reduce
substandard lots in a gradual manner. The regulations here
represent a classic way of doing this: by implementing a merger
provision, which combines contiguous substandard lots under common
ownership, alongside a grandfather clause, which preserves adjacent
substandard lots that are in separate ownership. Also, as here, the
harshness of a merger provision may be ameliorated by the
availability of a variance from the local zoning authority for
landowners in special circumstances. See 3 E. Ziegler, Rathkopf’s
Law of Zoning and Planning §49:13 (39th ed. 2017).
Petitioners’ insistence that lot lines define
the relevant parcel ignores the well-settled reliance on the merger
provision as a common means of balancing the legitimate goals of
regulation with the reasonable expectations of landowners.
Petitioners’ rule would frustrate municipalities’ ability to
implement minimum lot size regulations by casting doubt on the many
merger provisions that exist nationwide today. See Brief for
National Association of Counties et al. as
Amici Curiae
12–31 (listing over 100 examples of merger provisions).
Petitioners’ reliance on lot lines also is
problematic for another reason. Lot lines have varying degrees of
formality across the States, so it is difficult to make them a
standard measure of the reasonable expectations of property owners.
Indeed, in some jurisdictions, lot lines may be subject to informal
adjustment by property owners, with minimal government oversight.
See Brief for California et al. as
Amici Curiae 17; 1
J. Kushner, Subdivision Law and Growth Management §5:8 (2d ed.
2017) (lot line adjustments that create no new parcels are often
exempt from subdivision review); see,
e.g., Cal. Govt. Code
Ann. §66412(d) (West 2016) (permitting adjustment of lot lines
subject to limited conditions for government approval). The ease of
modifying lot lines also creates the risk of gamesmanship by
landowners, who might seek to alter the lines in anticipation of
regulation that seems likely to affect only part of their
property.
IV
Under the appropriate multifactor standard, it
follows that for purposes of determining whether a regulatory
taking has occurred here, petitioners’ property should be evaluated
as a single parcel consisting of Lots E and F together.
First, the treatment of the property under state
and local law indicates petitioners’ property should be treated as
one when considering the effects of the restrictions. As the
Wisconsin courts held, the state and local regulations merged Lots
E and F.
E.g., App. to Pet. for Cert. A–3, ¶6 (“The 1995
transfer of Lot E brought the lots under common ownership and
resulted in a merger of the two lots under [the local ordinance]”).
The decision to adopt the merger provision at issue here was for a
specific and legitimate purpose, consistent with the widespread
understanding that lot lines are not dominant or controlling in
every case. See
supra, at ___. Petitioners’ land was subject
to this regulatory burden, moreover, only because of voluntary
conduct in bringing the lots under common ownership after the
regulations were enacted. As a result, the valid merger of the lots
under state law informs the reasonable expectation they will be
treated as a single property.
Second, the physical characteristics of the
property support its treatment as a unified parcel. The lots are
contiguous along their longest edge. Their rough terrain and narrow
shape make it reasonable to expect their range of potential uses
might be limited. Cf. App. to Pet. for Cert. A–5, ¶8
(“[Petitioners] asserted Lot E could not be put to alternative uses
like agriculture or commerce due to its size, location and steep
terrain”). The land’s location along the river is also significant.
Petitioners could have anticipated public regulation might affect
their enjoyment of their property, as the Lower St. Croix was a
regulated area under federal, state, and local law long before
petitioners possessed the land.
Third, the prospective value that Lot E brings
to Lot F supports considering the two as one parcel for purposes of
determining if there is a regulatory taking. Petitioners are
prohibited from selling Lots E and F separately or from building
separate residential structures on each. Yet this restriction is
mitigated by the benefits of using the property as an integrated
whole, allowing increased privacy and recreational space, plus the
optimal location of any improvements. See Case No. 12–CV–258, App.
to Pet. for Cert. B–9 (“They have an elevated level of privacy
because they do not have close neighbors and are able to swim and
play volleyball at the property”).
The special relationship of the lots is further
shown by their combined valuation. Were Lot E separately saleable
but still subject to the development restriction, petitioners’
appraiser would value the property at only $40,000. We express no
opinion on the validity of this figure. We also note the number is
not particularly helpful for understanding petitioners’ retained
value in the properties because Lot E, under the regulations,
cannot be sold without Lot F. The point that is useful for these
purposes is that the combined lots are valued at $698,300, which is
far greater than the summed value of the separate regulated lots
(Lot F with its cabin at $373,000, according to respondents’
appraiser, and Lot E as an undevelopable plot at $40,000, according
to petitioners’ appraiser). The value added by the lots’
combination shows their complementarity and supports their
treatment as one parcel.
The State Court of Appeals was correct in
analyzing petitioners’ property as a single unit. Petitioners
allege that in doing so, the state court applied a categorical rule
that all contiguous, commonly owned holdings must be combined for
Takings Clause analysis. See Brief for Petitioners i (“[D]oes the
‘parcel as a whole’ concept . . . establish a rule that
two legally distinct, but commonly owned contiguous parcels, must
be combined for takings analysis purposes”). This does not appear
to be the case, however, for the precedent relied on by the Court
of Appeals addressed multiple factors before treating contiguous
properties as one parcel. See App. to Pet. for Cert. A–9–A–11,
¶¶17–19 (citing
Zealy v.
Waukesha, 201 Wis. 2d 365,
548 N. W. 2d 528); see
id., at 378, 548 N. W. 2d,
at 533 (considering the property as a whole because it was “part of
a single purchase” and all 10.4 acres were undeveloped). The
judgment below, furthermore, may be affirmed on any ground
permitted by the law and record. See
Thigpen v.
Roberts, 468 U. S. 27, 30 (1984) . To the extent the
state court treated the two lots as one parcel based on a
bright-line rule, nothing in this opinion approves that
methodology, as distinct from the result.
Considering petitioners’ property as a whole,
the state court was correct to conclude that petitioners cannot
establish a compensable taking in these circumstances. Petitioners
have not suffered a taking under
Lucas, as they have not
been deprived of all economically beneficial use of their property.
See 505 U. S., at 1019. They can use the property for
residential purposes, including an enhanced, larger residential
improvement. See
Palazzolo, 533 U. S., at 631 (“A
regulation permitting a landowner to build a substantial residence
. . . does not leave the property ‘economically
idle’ ”). The property has not lost all economic value, as its
value has decreased by less than 10 percent. See
Lucas,
supra, at 1019, n. 8 (suggesting that even a landowner
with 95 percent loss may not recover).
Petitioners furthermore have not suffered a
taking under the more general test of
Penn Central. See 438
U. S., at 124. The expert appraisal relied upon by the state
courts refutes any claim that the economic impact of the regulation
is severe. Petitioners cannot claim that they reasonably expected
to sell or develop their lots separately given the regulations
which predated their acquisition of both lots. Finally, the
governmental action was a reasonable land-use regulation, enacted
as part of a coordinated federal, state, and local effort to
preserve the river and surrounding land.
* * *
Like the ultimate question whether a
regulation has gone too far, the question of the proper parcel in
regulatory takings cases cannot be solved by any simple test. See
Arkansas Game and Fish Comm’n v.
United States, 568
U. S. 23, 31 (2012) . Courts must instead define the parcel in
a manner that reflects reasonable expectations about the property.
Courts must strive for consistency with the central purpose of the
Takings Clause: to “bar Government from forcing some people alone
to bear public burdens which, in all fairness and justice, should
be borne by the public as a whole.”
Armstrong, 364
U. S., at 49. Treating the lot in question as a single parcel
is legitimate for purposes of this takings inquiry, and this
supports the conclusion that no regulatory taking occurred
here.
The judgment of the Wisconsin Court of Appeals
is affirmed.
It is so ordered.
Justice Gorsuch took no part in the
consideration or decision of this case.