In 1967, appellant Pennsylvania electric utilities joined a
venture to construct seven nuclear generating units. But in 1980,
because of intervening events, including the Arab oil embargo and
the accident at Three Mile Island, the participants canceled plans
for construction of four of the plants. Thereafter appellant
Duquesne Light Co. applied to the Pennsylvania Public Utility
Commission (PUC) to obtain a rate increase and to amortize its
expenditures on the canceled plants over 10 years. The PUC granted
a rate increase that included an amount representing the first
payment of the 10-year amortized recovery of Duquesne's costs in
the aborted plants. Shortly before the close of the rate
proceeding, a state law (Act 335) was enacted that provided that an
electric utility's cost of construction of a generating facility
shall not be made part of a ratebase nor otherwise included in
rates charged until such time as the facility "is used and useful
in service to the public." The State Office of the Consumer
Advocate moved the PUC to reconsider in light of this law, but the
PUC, on reconsideration, affirmed its original rate order, reading
the new law as excluding the costs of canceled plants from the
ratebase, but not as preventing their recovery through
amortization. Meanwhile, the PUC similarly granted appellant
Pennsylvania Power Co. a rate increase, and authorized it to
amortize its share of the canceled plants over a 10-year period.
The Consumer Advocate appealed both PUC decisions to the
Pennsylvania Commonwealth Court, which held that the PUC had
correctly construed Act 336. The Pennsylvania Supreme Court
reversed, holding that Act 336 prohibited recovery of the costs in
question either by inclusion in the ratebase or by amortization,
and that the statute did not take appellants' property in violation
of the Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment, applicable to the
States under the Fourteenth Amendment. The court remanded the case
to the PUC for further proceedings to correct its rate orders,
giving effect to the exclusion required by Act 336.
Held:
1. This Court has jurisdiction to decide the case under 28
U.S.C. § 1267(2), which authorizes the Court to review by
appeal
"[f]inal judgments . . . rendered by the highest court of a
State in which a decision could be had . . . where is drawn in
question the validity of a statute of any state on the ground of
its being repugnant to the Constitution . . .
Page 488 U. S. 300
and the decision is in favor of its validity."
Although the Pennsylvania Supreme Court remanded the case for
further proceedings to revise the rate orders, that court's
judgment is final for purposes of this Court's appellate
jurisdiction. The state court's last word on Act 336's
constitutionality has been presented, and all that remains is the
straightforward application of its clear directive to otherwise
complete rate orders. Pp.
488 U. S.
306-307.
2. A state scheme of utility regulation, such as is involved
here, does not "take" property simply because it disallows recovery
of capital investments that are not "used and useful in service to
the public." Pp.
488 U. S.
307-316.
(a) Under the "prudent investment" or "historical cost" rule, a
utility is compensated for all prudent investments at their actual
cost when made (their "historical" cost), irrespective of whether
individual investments are deemed necessary or beneficial in
hindsight. It was ruled in
FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co.,
320 U. S. 591,
that historical cost was a valid basis on which to calculate
utility compensation. Pp.
488 U. S.
307-312.
(b) The Constitution does not require that subsidiary aspects of
Pennsylvania's ratemaking methodology be examined piecemeal, as
appellants argue. State legislatures are competent bodies to set
utility rates, and the PUC is essentially an administrative arm of
the legislature. Similarly, an otherwise reasonable rate is not
subject to constitutional attack by questioning the theoretical
consistency of the method that produced it, as appellants do here
by noting Act 335's theoretical inconsistency in suddenly and
selectively applying the "used and useful requirement," normally
associated with the fair value method of ratesetting, in the
context of Pennsylvania's system based on historical costs. Pp.
488 U. S.
313-314.
(c) In this case, at all relevant times, Pennsylvania's rate
system has been predominantly, but not entirely, based on
historical costs, and it has not been shown that the rate orders in
question, as modified by Act 335, failed to give a reasonable rate
of return on equity given the risk under such a regime. Therefore,
Act 335's limited effect on those rate orders does not result in
constitutionally impermissible rates. Pp.
488 U. S.
314-315.
(d) But adoption of the "prudent investment" rule as the single
constitutional standard of valuation would be inconsistent with the
view of the Constitution that this Court has taken since
Hope
Natural Gas, and would unnecessarily foreclose alternatives
that could benefit both consumers and investors. The Constitution,
within broad limits, leaves the States free to decide what
ratesetting methodology best meets their needs in balancing the
interests of the utility and the public. Pp.
488 U. S.
315-316.
516 Pa. 142,
532
A.2d 325, affirmed.
Page 488 U. S. 301
REHNQUIST, C.J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
BRENNAN, WHITE, MARSHALL, STEVENS, O'CONNOR, SCALIA, and KENNEDY,
JJ., joined. SCALIA, J., filed a concurring opinion, in which WHITE
and O'CONNOR, JJ., joined,
post, p.
488 U. S. 317.
BLACKMUN, J., filed a dissenting opinion,
post, p.
488 U. S.
317.
THE CHIEF JUSTICE delivered the opinion of the Court.
Pennsylvania law required that rates for electricity be fixed
without consideration of a utility's expenditures for electrical
generating facilities which were planned but never built, even
though the expenditures were prudent and reasonable when made. The
Supreme Court of Pennsylvania held that such a law did not take the
utilities' property in violation of the Fifth Amendment to the
United States Constitution. We agree with that conclusion, and hold
that a
Page 488 U. S. 302
state scheme of utility regulation does not "take" property
simply because it disallows recovery of capital investments that
are not "used and useful in service to the public." 66
Pa.Cons.Stat. § 1315 (Supp.1988).
I
In response to predictions of increased demand for electricity,
Duquesne Light Company (Duquesne) and Pennsylvania Power Company
(Penn Power) joined a venture in 1967 to build more generating
capacity. The project, known as the Central Area Power Coordination
Group (CAPCO), involved three other electric utilities and had as
its objective the construction of seven large nuclear generating
units. In 1980, the participants canceled plans for construction of
four of the plants. Intervening events, including the Arab oil
embargo and the accident at Three Mile Island, had radically
changed the outlook both for growth in the demand for electricity
and for nuclear energy as a desirable way of meeting that demand.
At the time of the cancellation, Duquesne's share of the
preliminary construction costs associated with the four halted
plants was $34,697,389. Penn Power had invested $9,569,665.
In 1980, and again in 1981, Duquesne sought permission from the
Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission (PUC) [
Footnote 1] to recoup its expenditures for the
unbuilt plants over a 10-year period. The Commission deferred
ruling on the request until it received the report from its
investigation of the CAPCO construction. That report was issued in
late 1982. The report found that Duquesne and Penn Power could not
be faulted for initiating the construction of more nuclear
generating capacity at the time they joined the CAPCO project in
1967. The projections at that time indicated a growing demand
Page 488 U. S. 303
for electricity and a cost advantage to nuclear capacity. It
also found that the intervening events which ultimately confounded
the predictions could not have been predicted, and that work on the
four nuclear plants was stopped at the proper time. In summing up,
the Administrative Law Judge found "that the CAPCO decisions in
regard to the [canceled plants] at every stage to their
cancellation, were reasonable and prudent." App. to Juris.
Statement 19h. He recommended that Duquesne and Penn Power be
allowed to amortize their sunk costs in the project over a 10-year
period. The PUC adopted the conclusions of the report. App. to
Juris. Statement 1i.
In 1982, Duquesne again came before the PUC to obtain a rate
increase. Again, it sought to amortize its expenditures on the
canceled plants over 10 years. In January, 1988, the PUC issued a
final order which granted Duquesne the authority to increase its
revenues $106.8 million to a total yearly revenue in excess of $800
million.
Pennsylvania PUC v. Duquesne Light Co., 67 Pa.
P.U.C. 1, 51 P.U.R. 4th 198 (1983). The rate increase included $3.6
million in revenue representing the first payment of the 10-year
amortization of Duquesne's $36 million loss in the CAPCO
plants.
The Pennsylvania Office of the Consumer Advocate (Consumer
Advocate) moved the PUC for reconsideration in light of a state law
enacted about a month before the close of the 1982 Duquesne rate
proceeding. The Act, No. 336, 1982 Pa. Laws 1473, amended the
Pennsylvania Utility Code by limiting "the consideration of certain
costs in the ratebase." [
Footnote
2]
Page 488 U. S. 304
It provided that
"the cost of construction or expansion of a facility undertaken
by a public utility producing . . . electricity shall not be made a
part of the ratebase nor otherwise included in the rates charged by
the electric utility until such time as the facility is used and
useful in service to the public."
66 Pa.Cons.Stat. § 1315 (Supp.1988). On reconsideration, the PUC
affirmed its original rate order.
Pennsylvania PUC v. Duquesne
Light Co., 57 Pa.P.U.C. 177, 52 P.U.R. 4th 644 (1983). It read
the new law as excluding the costs of canceled plants (obviously
not used and useful) from the ratebase, but not as preventing their
recovery through amortization.
Meanwhile, another CAPCO member, Penn Power, also sought to
amortize its share of the canceled CAPCO power plants over a
10-year period. The PUC granted Penn Power authority to increase
its revenues by $15.4 million, to a total of $184.2 million.
Pennsylvania PUC v. Pennsylvania Power Co., 58 Pa.P.U.C.
305, 60 P.U.R. 4th 593 (1984). Part of
Page 488 U. S. 305
that revenue increase represented $956,967 for the first year of
the 10-year amortized recovery of Penn Power's costs in the aborted
nuclear plants.
The Consumer Advocate appealed both of these decisions to the
Commonwealth Court, which by a divided vote held that the
Commission had correctly construed § 1315.
Cohen v.
Pennsylvania PUC, 90 Pa.Comw. 98, 494 A.2d 58 (1985). The
Consumer Advocate then appealed to the Supreme Court of
Pennsylvania, and that court reversed.
Barasch v. Pennsylvania
PUC, 516 Pa. 142,
532 A.2d
325 (1987). That court held that the controlling language of
the Act prohibited recovery of the costs in question either by
inclusion in the ratebase or by amortization. The Supreme Court
rejected appellants' constitutional challenge to the statute thus
interpreted, observing that
"[t]he 'just compensation' safeguarded to a utility by the
fourteenth amendment of the federal constitution is a reasonable
return on the fair value of its property at the time it is being
used for public service."
Id. at 163, 532 A.2d at 335. Since the instant CAPCO
investment was not serving the public and did not constitute an
operating expense, no constitutional rights to recovery attached to
it. The court remanded to the PUC for further proceedings to
correct its rate order, giving effect to the exclusion required by
Act 335. [
Footnote 3] Duquesne
and Penn Power appealed to this Court, arguing that the effect of
Act 335 excluding their prudently incurred costs from the rate
violated the Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment, applicable to
the States under the Fourteenth Amendment. We noted probable
jurisdiction. 485 U.S. 933 (1988).
Page 488 U. S. 306
II
Although the parties have not discussed it, we must first
inquire into our jurisdiction to decide this case.
See Jackson v.
Ashton, 8 Pet. 148 (1834);
Mansfield C. &
L. M. R. Co. v. Swan, 111 U. S. 379
(1884). Our jurisdiction here rests on 28 U.S.C. § 1257(2), which
authorizes this Court to review
"[f]inal judgments or decrees rendered by the highest Court of a
State in which a decision could be had . . . [b]y appeal, where is
drawn in question the validity of a statute of any state on the
ground of its being repugnant to the Constitution . . . and the
decision is in favor of its validity."
Although this case has been remanded for further proceedings to
revise the relevant rate orders, we hold that, for purposes of our
appellate jurisdiction, the judgment of the Pennsylvania Supreme
Court is final.
We have acknowledged that the words of § 1257 could well be
interpreted to preclude review in this Court as long as any
proceedings remain in state court.
Radio Station WOW, Inc. v.
Johnson, 326 U. S. 120,
326 U. S. 124
(1945). In
Cox Broadcasting Corp. v. Cohn, 420 U.
S. 469,
420 U. S. 477
(1975), however, we recognized that, in practice, the final
judgment rule has not been interpreted so strictly.
Cox
outlined four circumstances in which the adjudication of a federal
issue in a case by the highest available state court had been
reviewed in this Court notwithstanding the prospect of some further
state court proceedings.
This case falls into the first of the four categories. The
Pennsylvania Supreme Court has finally adjudicated the
constitutionality of Act 335 in the context of otherwise completed
rate proceedings, and so has left "the outcome of further
proceedings preordained."
Cox, supra, at
420 U. S. 479.
We do not think that the PUC might undo the effects of Act 335 on
remand by allowing recovery of the disputed costs in some other way
consistent with state law. The Pennsylvania Supreme Court's
interpretation of the Act does not leave its
Page 488 U. S. 307
effect in doubt; the CAPCO related costs may not be "otherwise
included in the rates charged." 66 Pa. Cons.Stat. § 1316 (1986).
[
Footnote 4] We are satisfied
that we are presented with the State's last word on the
constitutionality of Act 335, and that all that remains is the
straightforward application of its clear directive to otherwise
complete rate Orders. We therefore have jurisdiction.
See Cox,
supra, at
420 U. S. 479;
Mills v. Alabama, 384 U. S. 214
(1966).
III
As public utilities, both Duquesne and Penn Power are under a
state statutory duty to serve the public. A Pennsylvania statute
provides that "[e]very public utility shall furnish and maintain
adequate, efficient, safe, and reasonable service and facilities"
and that "[s]uch service also shall be reasonably continuous and
without unreasonable interruptions or delay." 66 Pa.Cons.Stat. §
1501 (1986). Although their assets are employed in the public
interest to provide consumers of the State with electric power,
they are owned and operated by private investors. This partly
public, partly private status of utility property creates its own
set of questions under the Takings Clause of the Fifth
Amendment.
The guiding principle has been that the Constitution protects
utilities from being limited to a charge for their property serving
the public which is so "unjust" as to be confiscatory.
Covington & Lexington Turnpike Road Co. v. Sandford,
164 U. S. 578,
164 U. S. 597
(1896) (A rate is too low if it is "so unjust as to destroy the
value of [the] property for all the purposes for which it was
acquired," and in so doing "practically
Page 488 U. S. 308
deprive[s] the owner of property without due process of law");
FPC v. Natural Gas Pipeline Co., 315 U.
S. 575,
315 U. S. 585
(1942) ("By longstanding usage in the field of rate regulation, the
lowest reasonable rate' is one which is not confiscatory in the
constitutional sense"); FPC v. Texaco Inc., 417 U.
S. 380, 417 U. S.
391-392 (1974) ("All that is protected against, in a
constitutional sense, is that the rates fixed by the Commission be
higher than a confiscatory level"). If the rate does not afford
sufficient compensation, the State has taken the use of utility
property without paying just compensation, and so violated the
Fifth and Fourteenth Amendments. As has been observed, however,
"[h]ow such compensation may be ascertained, and what are the
necessary elements in such an inquiry, will always be an
embarrassing question." Smyth v. Ames, 169 U.
S. 466, 169 U. S. 546
(1898). See also Permian Basin Area Rate Cases,
390 U. S. 747,
390 U. S. 790
(1968) ("[N]either law nor economics has yet devised generally
accepted standards for the evaluation of ratemaking
orders").
At one time, it was thought that the Constitution required rates
to be set according to the actual present value of the assets
employed in the public service. This method, known as the "fair
value" rule, is exemplified by the decision in
Smyth v. Ames,
supra. Under the fair value approach, a "company is entitled
to ask . . . a fair return upon the value of that which it employs
for the public convenience," while, on the other hand,
"the public is entitled to demand . . . that no more be exacted
from it for the use of [utility property] than the services
rendered by it are reasonably worth."
169 U.S. at
169 U. S. 547.
In theory, the
Smyth v. Ames fair value standard mimics
the operation of the competitive market. To the extent utilities'
investments in plants are good ones (because their benefits exceed
their costs), they are rewarded with an opportunity to earn an
"above-cost" return, that is, a fair return on the current "market
value" of the plant. To the extent utilities' investments turn out
to be bad ones (such as plants that are canceled and so never used
and useful to
Page 488 U. S. 309
the public), the utilities suffer because the investments have
no fair value, and so justify no return.
Although the fair value rule gives utilities strong incentive to
manage their affairs well and to provide efficient service to the
public, it suffered from practical difficulties which ultimately
led to its abandonment as a constitutional requirement. [
Footnote 5] In response to these
problems, Justice Brandeis had advocated an alternative approach as
the constitutional minimum, what has become known as the "prudent
investment" or "historical cost" rule. He accepted the
Smyth v.
Ames eminent domain analogy, but concluded that what was
"taken" by public utility regulation is not specific physical
assets that are to be individually valued, but the capital
prudently devoted to the public utility enterprise by the
utilities' owners.
Missouri ex rel. Southwestern Bell Telephone
Co. v. Public Service Comm'n, 262 U.
S. 276,
262 U. S. 291
(1923). Under the prudent investment rule, the utility is
compensated for all prudent investments at their actual cost when
made (their "historical" cost), irrespective of whether individual
investments are deemed necessary or beneficial in hindsight. The
utilities incur fewer risks, but are limited to a standard rate of
return on the actual amount of money reasonably invested. [
Footnote 6]
Page 488 U. S. 310
Forty-five years ago in the landmark case of
FPC v. Hope
Natural Gas Co., 320 U. S. 591
(1944), this Court abandoned the rule of
Smyth v. Ames,
and held that the "fair value" rule is not the only
constitutionally acceptable method of fixing utility rates. In
Hope, we ruled that historical cost was a valid basis on
which to calculate utility compensation. 320 U.S. at
320 U. S. 605
("Rates which enable [a] company to operate successfully, to
maintain its financial integrity, to attract capital, and to
compensate its investors for the risk assumed certainly cannot be
condemned as invalid, even though they might produce only a meager
return on the so called
fair value' ratebase"). We also
acknowledged in that case that all of the subsidiary aspects of
valuation for ratemaking purposes could not properly be
characterized as having a constitutional dimension, despite the
fact that they might affect property rights to some degree. Today
we reaffirm these teachings of Hope Natural Gas:
"[I]t is not theory, but the impact, of the rate order which
counts. If the total effect of the rate order cannot be said to be
unreasonable, judicial inquiry . . . is at an end. The fact that
the method employed to reach that result may contain infirmities is
not then important."
Id. at
320 U. S. 602.
This language, of course, does not dispense with all of the
constitutional difficulties when a utility raises a claim that the
rate which it is permitted to charge is so low as to be
confiscatory: whether a particular rate is "unjust" or
"unreasonable" will depend to some extent on what is a fair rate of
return, given the risks under a particular ratesetting system, and
on the amount of capital upon which the investors are entitled to
earn that return. At the margins, these questions have
constitutional overtones.
Pennsylvania determines rates under a slightly modified form of
the historical cost/prudent investment system. [
Footnote 7] Neither
Page 488 U. S. 311
Duquesne nor Penn Power alleges that the total effect of the
rate order arrived at within this system is unjust or unreasonable.
In fact, the overall effect is well within the
Page 488 U. S. 312
bounds of
Hope, even with total exclusion of the CAPCO
costs. Duquesne was authorized to earn a 16.14% return on common
equity and an 11.64% overall return on a ratebase of nearly $1.8
billion.
See Pennsylvania PUC v. Duquesne Light Co., 57
Pa.P.U.C. at 51, 51 P.U.R.4th at 243. Its $35 million investment in
the canceled plants comprises roughly 1.9% of its total base. The
denial of plant amortization will reduce its annual allowance by
.4%. Similarly, Penn Power was allowed a charge of 15.72% return on
common equity and a 12.02% overall return. Its investment in the
CAPCO plants comprises only 2.4% of its $401.8 million ratebase.
See Pennsylvania PUC v. Pennsylvania Power Co., 58
Pa.P.U.C. at 331-332, 60 P.U.R.4th at 618. The denial of amortized
recovery of its $9.6 million investment in CAPCO will reduce its
annual revenue allowance by only .5%.
Given these numbers, it appears that the PUC would have acted
within the constitutional range of reasonableness if it had allowed
amortization of the CAPCO costs but set a lower rate of return on
equity, with the result that Duquesne and Penn Power received the
same revenue they will under the instant orders on remand. The
overall impact of the rate orders, then, is not constitutionally
objectionable. No argument has been made that these slightly
reduced rates jeopardize the financial integrity of the companies,
either by leaving them insufficient operating capital or by
impeding their ability to raise future capital. Nor has it been
demonstrated that these rates are inadequate to compensate current
equity holders for the risk associated with their investments under
a modified prudent investment scheme. [
Footnote 8]
Page 488 U. S. 313
Instead, appellants argue that the Constitution requires that
subsidiary aspects of Pennsylvania's ratemaking methodology be
examined piecemeal. One aspect which they find objectionable is the
constraint Act 335 places on the PUC's decisions. They urge that
such legislative direction to the PUC impermissibly interferes with
the PUC's duty to balance consumer and investor interest under
Permian Basin, 390 U.S. at
390 U. S. 792.
Appellants also note the theoretical inconsistency of Act 335,
suddenly and selectively applying the used and useful requirement,
normally associated with the fair value approach, in the context of
Pennsylvania's system based on historical cost. Neither of the
errors appellants perceive in this case is of constitutional
magnitude.
It cannot seriously be contended that the Constitution prevents
state legislatures from giving specific instructions to their
utility commissions. We have never doubted that state legislatures
are competent bodies to set utility rates. And the Pennsylvania PUC
is essentially an administrative arm of the legislature.
See,
e.g., Barasch v. Pennsylvania PUC, 516 Pa. at 171, 532 A.2d at
339 ("The Commission is but an instrumentality of the state
legislature for the performance of [ratemaking]");
Minnesota
Rate Cases, 230 U. S. 352,
230 U. S. 433
(1913) ("The ratemaking power is a legislative power and
necessarily implies a range of legislative discretion"). [
Footnote 9] We stated in
Permian
Basin that the commission "must be free, within the
limitations imposed by pertinent constitutional
Page 488 U. S. 314
and
statutory commands, to devise methods of regulation
capable of equitably reconciling diverse and conflicting
interests." 390 U.S. at
390 U. S. 767
(emphasis added). This is not to say that any system of ratemaking
applied by a utilities commission, including the specific
instructions it has received from its legislature, will necessarily
be constitutional. But if the system fails to pass muster, it will
not be because the legislature has performed part of the work.
Similarly, an otherwise reasonable rate is not subject to
constitutional attack by questioning the theoretical consistency of
the method that produced it. "It is not theory, but the impact of
the rate order which counts."
Hope, 320 U.S. at
320 U. S. 602.
The economic judgments required in rate proceedings are often
hopelessly complex, and do not admit of a single correct result.
The Constitution is not designed to arbitrate these economic
niceties. Errors to the detriment of one party may well be canceled
out by countervailing errors or allowances in another part of the
rate proceeding. The Constitution protects the utility from the net
effect of the rate order on its property. Inconsistencies in one
aspect of the methodology have no constitutional effect on the
utility's property if they are compensated by countervailing
factors in some other aspect.
Admittedly, the impact of certain rates can only be evaluated in
the context of the system under which they are imposed. One of the
elements always relevant to setting the rate under
Hope is
the return investors expect given the risk of the enterprise.
Id. at
320 U. S. 603
("[R]eturn to the equity owner should be commensurate with returns
on investments in other enterprises having corresponding risks");
Bluefield Water Works & Improvement Co. v. Public Service
Comm'n of West Virginia, 262 U. S. 679,
262 U. S.
692-693 (1923) ("A public utility is entitled to such
rates as will permit it to earn a return . . . equal to that
generally being made at the same time and in the same general part
of the country on investments in other business undertakings which
are attended by
Page 488 U. S. 315
corresponding risks and uncertainties"). The risks a utility
faces are in large part defined by the rate methodology, because
utilities are virtually always public monopolies dealing in an
essential service, and so relatively immune to the usual market
risks. Consequently, a State's decision to arbitrarily switch back
and forth between methodologies in a way which required investors
to bear the risk of bad investments at some times while denying
them the benefit of good investments at others would raise serious
constitutional questions. But the instant case does not present
this question. At all relevant times, Pennsylvania's rate system
has been predominantly, but not entirely, based on historical cost,
and it has not been shown that the rate orders as modified by Act
335 fail to give a reasonable rate of return on equity given the
risks under such a regime. We therefore hold that Act 335's limited
effect on the rate order at issue does not result in a
constitutionally impermissible rate.
Finally we address the suggestion of the Pennsylvania Electric
Association as
amicus that the prudent investment rule
should be adopted as the constitutional standard. We think that the
adoption of any such rule would signal a retreat from 45 years of
decisional law in this area which would be as unwarranted as it
would be unsettling.
Hope clearly held that "the
Commission was not bound to the use of any single formula or
combination of formulae in determining rates." 320 U.S. at
320 U. S. 602.
More recently, we upheld the Federal Power Commission's (FPC)
departure from the individual producer cost-of-service (prudent
investment) system. In
Wisconsin v. FPC, 373 U.
S. 294 (1963), the FPC had concluded, after extensive
hearings, that
"the individual company cost-of-service method, based on
theories of original cost and prudent investment, was not a
workable or desirable method for determining the rates of
independent producers and that the 'ultimate solution' lay in what
has become to be known as the area rate approach: 'the
determination of fair prices . . . based on reasonable financial
requirements of the industry.'
Page 488 U. S. 316
Id. at
373 U. S. 298-299. In
upholding the FPC's area rate methodology against the argument that
the individual company prudent investment rule was constitutionally
required, the Court observed:"
"[T]o declare that a particular method of rate regulation is so
sanctified as to make it highly unlikely that any other method
could be sustained would be wholly out of keeping with this Court's
consistent and clearly articulated approach to the question of the
Commission's power to regulate rates. It has repeatedly been stated
that no single method need be followed by the Commission in
considering the justness and reasonableness of rates."
Id. at
373 U. S. 309
(collecting cases).
See also FPC v. Texaco Inc., 417 U.S.
at
417 U. S.
387-390.
The adoption of a single theory of valuation as a constitutional
requirement would be inconsistent with the view of the Constitution
this Court has taken since
Hope Natural Gas, supra. As
demonstrated in
Wisconsin v. FPC, circumstances may favor
the use of one ratemaking procedure over another. The designation
of a single theory of ratemaking as a constitutional requirement
would unnecessarily foreclose alternatives which could benefit both
consumers and investors. [
Footnote 10] The Constitution within broad limits leaves
the States free to decide what ratesetting methodology best meets
their needs in balancing the interests of the utility and the
public.
Affirmed.
Page 488 U. S. 317
[
Footnote 1]
The Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission exercises a
legislative grant of power to enforce the Pennsylvania public
utilities laws. 66 Pa.Cons.Stat. § 601 (1986).
"[T]he authority of the Commission must arise either from the
express words of the pertinent statutes or by strong and necessary
implication therefrom."
Philadelphia v. Philadelphia Electric Co., 504 Pa. 312,
317,
473 A.2d
997, 999 (1984) (collecting cases).
[
Footnote 2]
Act 336 amended the Pennsylvania Utility Code by adding 66
Pa.Cons.Stat. § 1315. The relevant parts of Act 336 read as
follows:
"
AN ACT"
"Amending Title 66 (Public Utilities) of the Pennsylvania
Consolidated Statutes, providing
a limitation on the
consideration of certain costs in the ratebase for electric
public utilities."
"
* * * *"
"Section 1. Title 66 . . . is amended by adding a section to
read:"
"§ 1315. Limitation on consideration of certain costs for
electric utilities."
"Except for such nonrevenue-producing, nonexpense reducing
investments as may be reasonably shown to be necessary to improve
environmental conditions at existing facilities or improve safety
at existing facilities or as may be required to convert facilities
to the utilization of coal,
the cost of construction or
expansion of a facility undertaken by a public utility
producing, generating, transmitting, distributing or furnishing
electricity
shall not be made a part of the ratebase nor
otherwise included in the rates charged by the electric utility
until such time as the facility is used and useful in service to
the public. Except as stated in this section, no electric
utility property shall be deemed used and useful
until it is
presently providing actual utility service to the
customers."
"Section 2. This act shall be applicable to
all proceedings
pending before the Public Utility Commission and the courts at this
time. Nothing contained in this act shall be construed to
modify or change existing law with regard to rate making treatment
of investment in facilities of fixed utilities other than electric
facilities."
"Section 3.
This act shall take effect
immediately."
"APPROVED -- The 30th day of December, A. D.1982."
(Emphasis added.)
[
Footnote 3]
On October 10, 1985, too late to affect this case, the
Pennsylvania Legislature enacted Act 1985-62 which added 66
Pa.Cons.Stat. § 520 (Supp.1988) to the state utility code. Under §
520, the PUC is now authorized to permit amortized recovery of
prudently incurred investment in canceled generating units.
[
Footnote 4]
As a result of recent legislation, this Court will not long have
appellate jurisdiction over cases of the instant type. Public L.
100-362, 102 Stat. 662, effective September 26, 1988, and
applicable to judgments rendered on or after that date, eliminates
substantially all of our appellate jurisdiction, including §
1267(2). Persons aggrieved by state court judgments should now file
a petition for certiorari, rather than appeal.
See S.Rep.
No. 100-300 (1988); H.R.Rep. No. 100-660 (1988); B. Boskey & E.
Gressman, The Supreme Court Bids Farewell to Mandatory Appeals, 109
S. Ct. LXXXI (1988).
[
Footnote 5]
Perhaps the most serious problem associated with the fair value
rule was the "laborious and baffling task of finding the present
value of the utility."
Missouri ex rel. Southwestern Bell
Telephone Co. v. Public Service Comm'n, 262 U.
S. 276,
262 U. S.
292-294 (1923) (Brandeis, J. dissenting). The exchange
value of a utility's assets, such as power plants, could not be set
by a market price, because such assets were rarely bought and sold.
Nor could the capital assets be valued by the stream of income they
produced, because setting that stream of income was the very object
of the rate proceeding. According to Brandeis, the
Smyth v.
Ames test usually degenerated to proofs about how much it
would cost to reconstruct the asset in question, a hopelessly
hypothetical, complex, and inexact process. 262 U.S. at
262 U. S.
292-294.
[
Footnote 6]
The system avoids the difficult valuation problems encountered
under the
Smyth v. Ames test, because it relies on the
actual historical cost of investments as the basis for setting the
rate. The amount of a utility's actual outlays for assets in the
public service is more easily ascertained by a ratemaking body
because less judgment is required than in valuing an asset.
[
Footnote 7]
Pennsylvania values property in the ratebase according to its
historical cost. As provided by 66 Pa.Cons.Stat. § 1311(b)
(1986),
"[t]he value of the property of the public utility included in
the ratebase shall be the original cost of the property when first
devoted to the public service less the applicable accrued
depreciation."
Accordingly, the PUC declared in Duquesne's rate proceeding that
"we shall adopt as the fair value of the respondent's ratebase, the
original cost measure of value."
Pennsylvania PUC v. Duquesne
Light Co., 57 Pa.P.U.C. 1, 5, 51 P.U.R.4th 198, 202 (1983). So
too in Penn Power's case.
See Pennsylvania PUC v. Pennsylvania
Power Co., 58 Pa.P.U.C. 306, 310, 60 P.U.R.4th 593, 697 (1984)
(same).
Having adjusted the historical cost in various ways to account
for such things as depreciation and working capital, the PUC
proceeds to set a rate of return based largely on the cost of
capital to the enterprise. The cost of each component of the
utility's capital is considered,
i.e.,
"the cost of debt, the cost of preferred stock, and the cost of
common stock[,] [t]he latter being determined by the return
required to sell such stock upon reasonable terms in the
market."
Pennsylvania PUC v. Duquesne Light Co., supra, at 42,
51 P.U.R.4th at 235;
Bluefield Water Works & Improvement
Co. v. Public Service Comm'n of West Virginia, 262 U.
S. 679,
262 U. S.
692-693 (1923). It then exercises "informed judgment" to
set the total rate of return based on these component costs of
capital.
Ibid. See also Pennsylvania PUC v.
Pennsylvania Power, supra, at 325-326, 60 P.U.R.4th at
611-621.
The bulk of the rate based on capital, then, represents a return
(set by costs of capital) on a ratebase (determined by historical
cost). These are features of the historical cost/prudent investment
system. Pennsylvania has modified the system in several instances,
however, when prudent investments will never be used and useful.
For such occurrences, it has allowed amortization of the capital
lost, but does not allow the utility to earn a return on that
investment.
See, e.g., Pennsylvania PUC v. Metropolitan Edison
Co., 55 Pa.P.U.C. 478, 486 (1982) (amortization of company's
investment in contaminated Three Mile Island Unit 2);
Philadelphia Electric Co. v. Pennsylvania PUC, 61 Pa.Comw.
325, 433 A.2d 620 (1981) (excluding from the ratebase a portion of
a utility's generating plant that was excess capacity, but allowing
recovery of the operating expenses, including depreciation charges
on the entire plants);
UGI Corp. v. Pennsylvania PUC, 49
Pa.Comw. 69, 410 A.2d 923 (1980) (permitting amortization of
terminated feasibility studies);
Pennsylvania PUC v.
Philadelphia Electric Co., 46 Pa.P.U.C. 746, 750 (1973)
(10-year amortization of unusual expenses caused by tropical
storm). The loss to utilities from prudent but ultimately
unsuccessful investments under such a system is greater than under
a pure prudent investment rule, but less than under a fair value
approach. Pennsylvania's modification slightly increases the
overall risk of investments in utilities over the pure prudent
investment rule. Presumably the PUC adjusts the risk premium
element of the rate of return on equity accordingly.
[
Footnote 8]
Duquesne's embedded cost of debt was 9.42%.
Pennsylvania PUC
v. Duquesne Light Co., 57 Pa.P.U.C. at 44, 51 P.U.R.4th at
237. Penn Power's debt service was at 10.25%.
Pennsylvania PUC
v. Pennsylvania Power Co., 58 Pa.P.U.C. at 332, 60 P.U.R.4th
at 618.
[
Footnote 9]
Indeed, the issue of constitutional concern has usually been
just the reverse of appellants' objection. Challenges to state and
federal laws have been raised on the ground that the legislatures
have delegated too much authority and discretion.
See Hampton
& Co. v. United States, 276 U. S. 394
(1928) (federal delegation of authority to set import tariff
rates);
York R. Co. v. Driscoll, 331 Pa. 193, 200 A. 864
(1938) (PUC's authorization to exempt utility securities from
reporting and registration requirements an unconstitutional
delegation of legislative power under Pennsylvania Constitution
because it allowed the utility to nullify the statutory reporting
requirements).
[
Footnote 10]
For example, rigid requirement of the prudent investment rule
would foreclose hybrid systems such as the one Pennsylvania used
before the effective date of Act 336 and now uses again.
See n 4,
supra. It would also foreclose a return to some form of
the fair value rule just as its practical problems may be
diminishing. The emergent market for wholesale electric energy
could provide a readily available objective basis for determining
the value of utility assets.
JUSTICE SCALIA, with whom JUSTICE WHITE and JUSTICE O'CONNOR
join, concurring.
I join the Court in reaffirming our established rule that no
single ratemaking methodology is mandated by the Constitution,
which looks to the consequences a governmental authority produces,
rather than the techniques it employs.
See, e.g., FPC v. Texaco
Inc., 417 U. S. 380,
417 U. S.
387-390 (1974);
Wisconsin v. FPC, 373 U.
S. 294,
373 U. S. 309
(1963);
FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.
S. 591,
320 U. S. 602
(1944). I think it important to observe, however, that while
"prudent investment" (by which I mean capital reasonably expended
to meet the utility's legal obligation to assure adequate service)
need not be taken into account as such in ratemaking formulas, it
may need to be taken into account in assessing the
constitutionality of the particular consequences produced by those
formulas. We cannot determine whether the payments a utility has
been allowed to collect constitute a fair return on investment, and
thus whether the government's action is confiscatory, unless we
agree upon what the relevant "investment" is. For that purpose, all
prudently incurred investment may well have to be counted. As the
Court's opinion describes, that question is not presented in the
present suit, which challenges techniques, rather than
consequences.
JUSTICE BLACKMUN, dissenting.
The Court, I fear, because of what it regards as the investment
of time in having this case argued and briefed, is strong-arming
the finality concept and finding a
Cox exception that does
not exist. We have jurisdiction, under 28 U.S.C. § 1257, only if
there is a "final judgment" by the "highest court of a State" in
which a decision could be had. To be sure, we have interpreted §
1257 somewhat flexibly to the effect that the finality requirement
is satisfied in four discrete situations despite the need of
further proceedings in the state courts:
Cox Broadcasting Corp.
v. Cohn, 420 U. S. 469,
420 U. S. 477
(1975).
Page 488 U. S. 318
The Court here concludes that this case falls within the first
of the four
Cox exceptions ("the outcome of further
proceedings preordained,"
id. at
420 U. S.
479). With all respect, I disagree, for this case
concerns rates, and there is no rate order whatsoever before this
Court. The Supreme Court of Pennsylvania invalidated the rate
orders set by the Pennsylvania Commission, and remanded the cases
for further ratemaking. The Court deludes itself when it speaks of
preordination of the Commission's further action. New rates will be
set, based upon factors we do not as yet know, and only then will a
final judgment possibly emerge in due course.
I therefore would dismiss the appeal for want of the final
judgment that § 1257 requires.