Petitioner and another retailer (Hartwell) were authorized by
respondent manufacturer to sell its electronic calculators in the
Houston area. In response to Hartwell's complaints about
petitioner's prices, respondent terminated petitioner's dealership.
Petitioner brought suit in Federal District Court, alleging that
respondent and Hartwell had conspired to terminate petitioner, and
that such conspiracy was illegal
per se under § 1 of the
Sherman Act. The court submitted a liability interrogatory to the
jury asking whether there was an agreement or understanding between
respondent and Hartwell to terminate petitioner's dealership
because of its price cutting, and instructed the jury that the
Sherman Act is violated when a seller enters into such an agreement
or understanding with one of its dealers. The jury answered the
interrogatory affirmatively, awarding damages, and the court
entered judgment for petitioner for treble damages. The Court of
Appeals reversed and remanded for a new trial, holding that, to
render illegal
per se a vertical agreement between a
manufacturer and a dealer to terminate a second dealer, the first
dealer must expressly or impliedly agree to set its prices at some
level.
Held: A vertical restraint of trade is not
per
se illegal under § 1 of the Sherman Act unless it includes
some agreement on price or price levels. Pp.
485 U. S.
723-736.
(a) Ordinarily, whether particular concerted action violates § 1
is determined through case-by-case application of the rule of
reason.
Per se rules are appropriate only for conduct that
is manifestly anticompetitive. Although vertical agreements on
resale prices are illegal
per se, extension of that
treatment to other vertical restraints must be based on
demonstrable economic effect, rather than upon formalistic line
drawing.
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc.,
433 U. S. 36, which
held that vertical nonprice restraints are not
per se
illegal, recognized that such restraints have real potential to
stimulate interbrand competition; that a rule of
per se
illegality for such restraints is not needed or effective to
protect intrabrand competition; and that such restraints do not
significantly facilitate cartelizing. There has been no showing
here that different characteristics attend an agreement between a
manufacturer and a dealer to terminate a "price cutter," without a
further agreement on the
Page 485 U. S. 718
price or price levels to be charged by the remaining dealer. A
quite plausible purpose of the vertical restriction here was to
enable Hartwell to provide better services under its sales
franchise agreement with respondent. There is also no merit to
petitioner's contention that an agreement on the remaining dealer's
price or price levels will so often follow from terminating another
dealer because of its price cutting that prophylaxis against resale
price maintenance warrants the District Court's
per se
rule. Pp.
485 U. S.
723-731.
(b) The term "restraint of trade" in the Sherman Act, like the
term at common law before the statute was adopted, refers not to a
particular list of agreements, but to a particular economic
consequence, which may be produced by quite different sorts of
agreements in varying times and circumstances. Moreover, this
Court's precedents do not indicate that the pre-Sherman Act common
law prohibited as illegal
per se an agreement of the sort
made here. Nor is the District Court's rule of
per se
illegality compelled by precedents under the Sherman Act holding
certain horizontal agreements to constitute price fixing, and thus
to be
per se illegal even though they did not set prices
or price levels. The notion of equivalence between the scope of
horizontal
per se illegality and that of vertical
per
se illegality was explicitly rejected in
GTE
Sylvania. Finally, earlier vertical price-fixing cases are
consistent with the proposition that vertical
per se
illegality requires an agreement setting a price or a price level.
Pp.
485 U. S.
731-735.
780 F.2d 1212, affirmed.
SCALIA, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
REHNQUIST, C.J., and BRENNAN, MARSHALL, BLACKMUN, and O'CONNOR,
JJ., joined. STEVENS, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which
WHITE, J., joined,
post, p.
485 U. S. 736.
KENNEDY, J., took no part in the consideration or decision of the
case.
Page 485 U. S. 719
JUSTICE SCALIA delivered the opinion of the Court.
Petitioner Business Electronics Corporation seeks review of a
decision of the United States Court of Appeals for the
Page 485 U. S. 720
Fifth Circuit holding that a vertical restraint is
per
se illegal under § 1 of the Sherman Act, 26 Stat. 209,
as
amended, 15 U.S.C. § 1, only if there is an express or implied
agreement to set resale prices at some level. 780 F.2d 1212,
1215-1218 (1986). We granted certiorari, 482 U.S. 912 (1987), to
resolve a conflict in the Courts of Appeals regarding the proper
dividing line between the rule that vertical price restraints are
illegal
per se and the rule that vertical nonprice
restraints are to be judged under the rule of reason. [
Footnote 1]
Page 485 U. S. 721
I
In 1968, petitioner became the exclusive retailer in the
Houston, Texas, area of electronic calculators manufactured by
respondent Sharp Electronics Corporation. In 1972, respondent
appointed Gilbert Hartwell as a second retailer in the Houston
area. During the relevant period, electronic calculators were
primarily sold to business customers for prices up to $1,000. While
much of the evidence in this case was conflicting -- in particular,
concerning whether petitioner was "free riding" on Hartwell's
provision of presale educational and promotional services by
providing inadequate services itself -- a few facts are undisputed.
Respondent published a list of suggested minimum retail prices, but
its written dealership agreements with petitioner and Hartwell did
not obligate either to observe them, or to charge any other
specific price. Petitioner's retail prices were often below
respondent's suggested retail prices, and generally below
Hartwell's retail prices, even though Hartwell too sometimes priced
below respondent's suggested retail prices. Hartwell complained to
respondent on a number of occasions about petitioner's prices. In
June, 1973, Hartwell gave respondent the ultimatum that Hartwell
would terminate his dealership unless respondent ended its
relationship with petitioner within 30 days. Respondent terminated
petitioner's dealership in July, 1973.
Petitioner brought suit in the United States District Court for
the Southern District of Texas, alleging that respondent and
Hartwell had conspired to terminate petitioner and that such
conspiracy was illegal
per se under § 1 of the Sherman
Act. The case was tried to a jury. The District Court submitted a
liability interrogatory to the jury that asked whether
"there was an agreement or understanding between Sharp
Electronics Corporation and Hartwell to terminate Business
Electronics as a Sharp dealer because of Business Electronics'
price cutting."
Record, Doc. No. 241. The District Court instructed the jury at
length about this question:
Page 485 U. S. 722
"The Sherman Act is violated when a seller enters into an
agreement or understanding with one of its dealers to terminate
another dealer because of the other dealer's price cutting.
Plaintiff contends that Sharp terminated Business Electronics in
furtherance of Hartwell's desire to eliminate Business Electronics
as a price-cutting rival."
"If you find that there was an agreement between Sharp and
Hartwell to terminate Business Electronics because of Business
Electronics' price cutting, you should answer yes to Question
Number 1."
"
* * * *"
"A combination, agreement or understanding to terminate a dealer
because of his price cutting unreasonably restrains trade and
cannot be justified for any reason. Therefore, even though the
combination, agreement or understanding may have been formed or
engaged in . . . to eliminate any alleged evils of price cutting,
it is still unlawful. . . ."
"If a dealer demands that a manufacturer terminate a price
cutting dealer, and the manufacturer agrees to do so, the agreement
is illegal if the manufacturer's purpose is to eliminate the price
cutting."
App. 18-19.
The jury answered Question 1 affirmatively and awarded $600,000
in damages. The District Court rejected respondent's motion for
judgment notwithstanding the verdict or a new trial, holding that
the jury interrogatory and instructions had properly stated the
law. It entered judgment for petitioner for treble damages plus
attorney's fees.
The Fifth Circuit reversed, holding that the jury interrogatory
and instructions were erroneous, and remanded for a new trial. It
held that, to render illegal
per se a vertical agreement
between a manufacturer and a dealer to terminate a second dealer,
the first dealer
"must expressly or impliedly agree to set its prices at some
level, though not a specific one.
Page 485 U. S. 723
The distributor cannot retain complete freedom to set whatever
price it chooses."
780 F.2d at 1218.
II
A
Section 1 of the Sherman Act provides that
"[e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or
otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among
the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be
illegal."
15 U.S.C. § 1. Since the earliest decisions of this Court
interpreting this provision, we have recognized that it was
intended to prohibit only unreasonable restraints of trade.
National
Collegiate
Page 485 U. S. 724
Athletic Assn. v. Board of Regents of University of
Oklahoma, 468 U. S. 85,
468 U. S. 98
(1984);
see, e.g., Standard Oil Co. v. United States,
221 U. S. 1,
221 U. S. 60
(1911). Ordinarily, whether particular concerted action violates §
1 of the Sherman Act is determined through case-by-case application
of the so-called rule of reason -- that is,
"the factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in
deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as
imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition."
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc.,
433 U. S. 36,
433 U. S. 49
(1977). Certain categories of agreements, however, have been held
to be
per se illegal, dispensing with the need for
case-by-case evaluation. We have said that
per se rules
are appropriate only for "conduct that is manifestly
anticompetitive,"
id. at
433 U. S. 50,
that is, conduct "
that would always or almost always tend to
restrict competition and decrease output,'" Northwest Wholesale
Stationers, Inc. v. Pacific Stationery & Printing Co.,
472 U. S. 284,
473 U. S.
289-290 (1985), quoting Broadcast Music, Inc. v.
Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U. S.
1, 441 U. S. 19-20
(1979). See also FTC v. Indiana Federation of Dentists,
476 U. S. 447,
476 U. S.
458-459 (1986) ("[W]e have been slow . . . to extend
per se analysis to restraints imposed in the context of
business relationships where the economic impact of certain
practices is not immediately obvious"); National Collegiate
Athletic Assn. v. Board of Regents of University of Oklahoma,
supra, at 468 U. S.
103-104 ("Per se rules are invoked when
surrounding circumstances make the likelihood of anticompetitive
conduct so great as to render unjustified further examination of
the challenged conduct"); National Society of Professional
Engineers v. United States, 435 U. S. 679,
435 U. S. 692
(1978) (agreements are per se illegal only if their
"nature and necessary effect are so plainly anticompetitive that no
elaborate study of the industry is needed to establish their
illegality").
Although vertical agreements on resale prices have been illegal
per se since
Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park
& Sons Co., 220 U. S. 373
(1911), we have recognized that the scope of
per se
illegality should be narrow in the context of vertical restraints.
In
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., supra, we
refused to extend
per se illegality to vertical nonprice
restraints, specifically to a manufacturer's termination of one
dealer pursuant to an exclusive territory agreement with another.
We noted that, especially in the vertical restraint context
"departure from the rule of reason standard must be based on
demonstrable economic effect, rather than . . . upon formalistic
linedrawing."
Id. at
220 U. S. 58-59.
We concluded that vertical nonprice restraints had not been shown
to have such a "
pernicious effect on competition'" and to be so
"`lack[ing] [in] . . . redeeming value'" as to justify per
se illegality. Id. at 220 U. S. 58,
quoting Northern Pacific R. Co. v. United States,
356 U. S. 1,
356 U. S. 5
(1958). Rather, we found, they had real potential to stimulate
interbrand competition, "the primary concern of antitrust law," 433
U.S. at 433 U. S. 52,
n.19:
"[N]ew manufacturers and manufacturers entering new markets can
use the restrictions in order to induce competent and aggressive
retailers to make the kind of investment of capital and labor that
is often required in the distribution of products unknown to the
consumer. Established manufacturers can use them to induce
retailers
Page 485 U. S. 725
to engage in promotional activities or to provide service and
repair facilities necessary to the efficient marketing of their
products. Service and repair are vital for many products. . . . The
availability and quality of such services affect a manufacturer's
goodwill and the competitiveness of his product. Because of market
imperfections such as the so-called 'free-rider' effect, these
services might not be provided by retailers in a purely competitive
situation, despite the fact that each retailer's benefit would be
greater if all provided the services than if none did."
Id. at
433 U. S.
55.
Moreover, we observed that a rule of
per se illegality
for vertical nonprice restraints was not needed or effective to
protect intrabrand competition. First, so long as interbrand
competition existed, that would provide a "significant check" on
any attempt to exploit intrabrand market power.
Id. at
433 U. S. 52,
n.19;
see also id. at
433 U. S. 54. In
fact, in order to meet that interbrand competition, a
manufacturer's dominant incentive is to lower resale prices.
Id. at
433 U. S. 56,
and n. 24. Second, the
per se illegality of vertical
restraints would create a perverse incentive for manufacturers to
integrate vertically into distribution, an outcome hardly conducive
to fostering the creation and maintenance of small businesses.
Id. at
433 U. S. 57, n.
26.
Finally, our opinion in
GTE Sylvania noted a
significant distinction between vertical nonprice and vertical
price restraints. That is, there was support for the proposition
that vertical price restraints reduce interbrand price competition
because they "
facilitate cartelizing.'" Id. at
433 U. S. 51, n.
18, quoting Posner, Antitrust Policy and the Supreme Court: An
Analysis of the Restricted Distribution, Horizontal Merger and
Potential Competition Decisions, 75 Colum.L.Rev. 282, 294 (1975).
The authorities cited by the Court suggested how vertical price
agreements might assist horizontal price fixing at the manufacturer
level (by reducing the manufacturer's incentive to cheat on a
cartel, since its retailers could not pass on lower prices to
consumers) or might be used to
Page 485 U. S. 726
organize cartels at the retailer level.
See R. Posner,
Antitrust: Cases, Economic Notes and Other Materials 134 (1974); E.
Gellhorn, Antitrust Law and Economics 252, 256 (1976); Note,
Vertical Territorial and Customer Restrictions in the Franchising
Industry, 10 Colum.J.L. & Soc.Prob. 497, 498, n. 12 (1974).
Similar support for the cartel-facilitating effect of vertical
nonprice restraints was and remains lacking.
We have been solicitous to assure that the market-freeing effect
of our decision in
GTE Sylvania is not frustrated by
related legal rules. In
Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service
Corp., 465 U. S. 752,
465 U. S. 763
(1984), which addressed the evidentiary showing necessary to
establish vertical concerted action, we expressed concern that,
"[i]f an inference of such an agreement may be drawn from highly
ambiguous evidence, there is considerable danger that the
doctrin[e] enunciated in
Sylvania . . . will be seriously
eroded."
See also id. at
465 U. S. 761,
n. 6. We eschewed adoption of an evidentiary standard that "could
deter or penalize perfectly legitimate conduct" or "would create an
irrational dislocation in the market" by preventing legitimate
communication between a manufacturer and its distributors.
Id. at
465 U. S. 763,
764.
Our approach to the question presented in the present case is
guided by the premises of
GTE Sylvania and
Monsanto: that there is a presumption in favor of a
rule-of-reason standard; that departure from that standard must be
justified by demonstrable economic effect, such as the facilitation
of cartelizing, rather than formalistic distinctions; that
interbrand competition is the primary concern of the antitrust
laws; and that rules in this area should be formulated with a view
towards protecting the doctrine of
GTE Sylvania. These
premises lead us to conclude that the line drawn by the Fifth
Circuit is the most appropriate one.
There has been no showing here that an agreement between a
manufacturer and a dealer to terminate a "price cutter," without a
further agreement on the price or price levels to be charged by the
remaining dealer, almost always tends
Page 485 U. S. 727
to restrict competition and reduce output. Any assistance to
cartelizing that such an agreement might provide cannot be
distinguished from the sort of minimal assistance that might be
provided by vertical nonprice agreements like the exclusive
territory agreement in
GTE Sylvania, and is insufficient
to justify a
per se rule. Cartels are neither easy to form
nor easy to maintain. Uncertainty over the terms of the cartel,
particularly the prices to be charged in the future, obstructs both
formation and adherence by making cheating easier.
Cf. Maple
Flooring Mfrs. Assn. v. United States, 268 U.
S. 563 (1925);
Cement Mfrs. Protective Assn. v.
United States, 268 U. S. 588
(1925);
see generally Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. v.
Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U. S. 574,
475 U. S. 590
(1986). Without an agreement with the remaining dealer on price,
the manufacturer both retains its incentive to cheat on any
manufacturer-level cartel (since lower prices can still be passed
on to consumers) and cannot as easily be used to organize and hold
together a retailer-level cartel. [
Footnote 2]
The District Court's rule on the scope of
per se
illegality for vertical restraints would threaten to dismantle the
doctrine of
GTE Sylvania. Any agreement between a
manufacturer and a dealer to terminate another dealer who happens
to have charged lower prices can be alleged to have been directed
against the terminated dealer's "price cutting." In the vast
majority of cases, it will be extremely difficult for the
manufacturer to convince a jury that its motivation was to ensure
adequate services, since price cutting and
Page 485 U. S. 728
some measure of service cutting usually go hand in hand.
Accordingly, a manufacturer that agrees to give one dealer an
exclusive territory and terminates another dealer pursuant to that
agreement, or even a manufacturer that agrees with one dealer to
terminate another for failure to provide contractually obligated
services, exposes itself to the highly plausible claim that its
real motivation was to terminate a price cutter. Moreover, even
vertical restraints that do not result in dealer termination, such
as the initial granting of an exclusive territory or the
requirement that certain services be provided, can be attacked as
designed to allow existing dealers to charge higher prices.
Manufacturers would be likely to forgo legitimate and competitively
useful conduct rather than risk treble damages and perhaps even
criminal penalties.
We cannot avoid this difficulty by invalidating as illegal
per se only those agreements imposing vertical restraints
that contain the word "price," or that affect the "prices" charged
by dealers. Such formalism was explicitly rejected in
GTE
Sylvania. As the above discussion indicates, all vertical
restraints, including the exclusive territory agreement held not to
be
per se illegal in
GTE Sylvania, have the
potential to allow dealers to increase "prices," and can be
characterized as intended to achieve just that. In fact, vertical
nonprice restraints only accomplish the benefits identified in
GTE Sylvania because they reduce intrabrand price
competition to the point where the dealer's profit margin permits
provision of the desired services. As we described it in
Monsanto:
"The manufacturer often will want to ensure that its
distributors earn sufficient profit to pay for programs such as
hiring and training additional salesmen or demonstrating the
technical features of the product, and will want to see that
'free-riders' do not interfere."
465 U.S. at
465 U. S.
762-763.
See also GTE Sylvania, 433 U.S. at
433 U. S.
55.
The dissent erects a much more complex analytic structure, which
ultimately rests, however, upon the same discredited
Page 485 U. S. 729
premise that the only function this nonprice vertical
restriction can serve is restraint of dealer-level competition.
Specifically, the dissent's reasoning hinges upon its perception
that the agreement between Sharp and Hartwell was a "naked"
restraint -- that is, it was not "ancillary" to any other agreement
between Sharp and Hartwell.
Post at
485 U. S.
736-742,
485 U. S.
744-745. But that is not true, unless one assumes,
contrary to
GTE Sylvania and
Monsanto, and
contrary to our earlier discussion, that it is not a quite
plausible purpose of the restriction to enable Hartwell to provide
better services under the sales franchise agreement. [
Footnote 3] From its
Page 485 U. S. 730
faulty conclusion that what we have before us is a "naked"
restraint, the dissent proceeds, by reasoning we do not entirely
follow, to the further conclusion that it is therefore a horizontal
rather than a vertical restraint. We pause over this only to note
that, in addition to producing what we think the wrong result in
the present case, it introduces needless confusion into antitrust
terminology. Restraints imposed by agreement between competitors
have traditionally been denominated as horizontal restraints, and
those imposed by agreement between firms at different levels of
distribution as vertical restraints. [
Footnote 4]
Page 485 U. S. 731
Finally, we do not agree with petitioner's contention that an
agreement on the remaining dealer's price or price levels will so
often follow from terminating another dealer "because of [its]
price cutting" that prophylaxis against resale price maintenance
warrants the District Court's
per se rule. Petitioner has
provided no support for the proposition that vertical price
agreements generally underlie agreements to terminate a
price-cutter. That proposition is simply incompatible with the
conclusion of
GTE Sylvania and
Monsanto that
manufacturers are often motivated by a legitimate desire to have
dealers provide services, combined with the reality that price
cutting is frequently made possible by "free riding" on the
services provided by other dealers. The District Court's
per
se rule would therefore discourage conduct recognized by
GTE Sylvania and
Monsanto as beneficial to
consumers.
B
In resting our decision upon the foregoing economic analysis, we
do not ignore common law precedent concerning what constituted
"restraint of trade" at the time the Sherman Act was adopted. But
neither do we give that pre-1890 precedent the dispositive effect
some would. The term "restraint of trade" in the statute, like the
term at common law, refers not to a particular list of agreements,
but to a particular economic consequence, which may be produced by
quite different sorts of agreements in varying times and
circumstances. The changing content of the term "restraint of
trade" was well recognized at the time the Sherman Act was enacted.
See Gibbs v. Consolidated Gas Co., 130 U.
S. 396,
130 U. S. 409
(1889) (noting that English case laying down the common law
rule
Page 485 U. S. 732
that contracts in restraint of trade are invalid "was made under
a condition of things, and a state of society, different from those
which now prevail, [and therefore] the rule laid down is not
regarded as inflexible, and has been considerably modified");
see also Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons
Co., 220 U.S. at
220 U. S. 406
("With respect to contracts in restraint of trade, the earlier
doctrine of the common law has been substantially modified in
adaptation to modern conditions"); B. Cardozo, The Nature of the
Judicial Process 94-96 (1921).
The Sherman Act adopted the term "restraint of trade" along with
its dynamic potential. It invokes the common law itself, and not
merely the static content that the common law had assigned to the
term in 1890.
See GTE Sylvania, 433 U.S. at
433 U. S. 53, n.
21;
Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. at
221 U. S. 51-60;
see also McNally v. United States, 483 U.
S. 350,
483 U. S.
372-373 (1987) (STEVENS, J., joined by O'CONNOR, J.,
dissenting);
Associated General Contractors of California, Inc.
v. Carpenters, 459 U. S. 519,
459 U. S. 533,
n. 28,
450 U. S.
539-540, and n. 43 (1983); Bork 37. If it were
otherwise, not only would the line of
per se illegality
have to be drawn today precisely where it was in 1890, but also
case-by-case evaluation of legality (conducted where
per
se rules do not apply) would have to be governed by
19th-century notions of reasonableness. It would make no sense to
create out of the single term "restraint of trade" a
chronologically schizoid statute in which a "rule of reason"
evolves with new circumstances and new wisdom but a line of
per
se illegality remains forever fixed where it was.
Of course, the common law, both in general and as embodied in
the Sherman Act, does not lightly assume that the economic
realities underlying earlier decisions have changed, or that
earlier judicial perceptions of those realities were in error. It
is relevant, therefore, whether the common law of
Page 485 U. S. 733
restraint of trade ever prohibited as illegal
per se an
agreement of the sort made here, and whether our decisions under §
1 of the Sherman Act have ever expressed or necessarily implied
such a prohibition.
With respect to this Court's understanding of pre-Sherman Act
common law, petitioner refers to our decision in
Dr. Miles
Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., supra. Though that
was an early Sherman Act case, its holding that a resale price
maintenance agreement was
per se illegal was based largely
on the perception that such an agreement was categorically
impermissible at common law.
Id. at
220 U. S.
404-408. As the opinion made plain, however, the basis
for that common law judgment was that the resale restriction was an
unlawful restraint on alienation.
See ibid. As we
explained in
Boston Store of Chicago v. American Graphophone
Co., 246 U. S. 8,
246 U. S. 21-22
(1918),
"
Dr. Miles . . . decided that, under the general law,
the owner of movables . . . could not sell the movables and
lawfully by contract fix a price at which the product should
afterwards be sold, because to do so would be at one and the same
time to sell and retain, to part with and yet to hold, to project
the will of the seller so as to cause it to control the movable
parted with when it was not subject to his will because owned by
another."
In the present case, of course, no agreement on resale price or
price level, and hence no restraint on alienation, was found by the
jury, so the common law rationale of
Dr. Miles does not
apply.
Cf. United States v. General Electric Co.,
272 U. S. 476,
272 U. S.
486-488 (1926) (
Dr. Miles does not apply to
restrictions on price to be charged by one who is in reality an
agent of, not a buyer from, the manufacturer).
Petitioner's principal contention has been that the District
Court's rule on
per se illegality is compelled not by the
old common law, but by our more recent Sherman Act precedents.
First, petitioner contends that, since certain horizontal
agreements have been held to constitute price fixing (and
Page 485 U. S. 734
thus to be
per se illegal) though they did not set
prices or price levels,
see, e.g., Catalano, Inc. v. Target
Sales, Inc., 446 U. S. 643,
446 U. S.
647-650 (1980) (per curiam), it is improper to require
that a vertical agreement set prices or price levels before it can
suffer the same fate. This notion of equivalence between the scope
of horizontal
per se illegality and that of vertical
per se illegality was explicitly rejected in
GTE
Sylvania, supra, at
433 U. S. 57, n.
27 -- as it had to be, since a horizontal agreement to divide
territories is
per se illegal,
see United States v.
Topco Associates, Inc., 405 U. S. 596,
405 U. S. 608
(1972), while
GTE Sylvania held that a vertical agreement
to do so is not.
See also United States v. Arnold, Schwinn
& Co., 388 U. S. 365,
388 U. S.
390-391 (1967) (Stewart, J., joined by Harlan, J.,
concurring in part and dissenting in part);
White Motor Co. v.
United States, 372 U. S. 253,
372 U. S. 263
(1963).
Second, petitioner contends that
per se illegality here
follows from our two cases holding
per se illegal a group
boycott of a dealer because of its price cutting.
See United
States v. General Motors Corp., 384 U.
S. 127 (1966);
Klor's, Inc. v. Broadway-Hale Stores,
Inc., 359 U. S. 207
(1959). This second contention is merely a restatement of the
first, since both cases involved horizontal combinations --
General Motors, supra, at
384 U. S. 140,
384 U. S.
143-145, at the dealer level, [
Footnote 5] and
Klor's, supra, at
359 U. S. 213,
at the manufacturer and wholesaler levels.
Accord, GTE
Sylvania, supra, at
433 U. S. 58, n.
28,
United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S.
at
388 U. S. 373,
388 U.S. 378;
id.
at
388 U. S. 390
(Stewart, J., joined by Harlan, J., concurring in part and
dissenting in part);
White Motor Co. v. United States,
supra, at
372 U. S.
263.
Page 485 U. S. 735
Third, petitioner contends, relying on
Albrecht v. Herald
Co., 390 U. S. 145
(1968), and
United States v. Parke, Davis & Co.,
362 U. S. 29
(1960), that our vertical price-fixing cases have already rejected
the proposition that
per se illegality requires setting a
price or a price level. We disagree. In
Albrecht, the
maker of the product formed a combination to force a retailer to
charge the maker's advertised retail price.
See 390 U.S.
at
390 U. S. 149.
This combination had two aspects. Initially, the maker hired a
third party to solicit customers away from the noncomplying
retailer. This solicitor "was aware that the aim of the
solicitation campaign was to force [the noncomplying retailer] to
lower his price" to the suggested retail price.
Id. at
390 U. S. 150.
Next, the maker engaged another retailer who "undertook to deliver
[products] at the suggested price" to the noncomplying retailer's
customers obtained by the solicitor.
Ibid. This
combination of maker, solicitor, and new retailer was held to be
per se illegal.
Id. at
390 U. S. 150,
390 U. S. 153.
It is plain that the combination involved both an explicit
agreement on resale price and an agreement to force another to
adhere to the specified price.
In
Parke, Davis, a manufacturer combined first with
wholesalers and then with retailers in order to gain the
"retailers' adherence to its suggested minimum retail prices." 362
U.S. at
362 U. S. 45-46,
and n. 6. The manufacturer also brokered an agreement among its
retailers not to advertise prices below its suggested retail
prices, which agreement was held to be part of the
per se
illegal combination. This holding also does not support a rule that
an agreement on price or price level is not required for a vertical
restraint to be
per se illegal -- first, because the
agreement not to advertise prices was part and parcel of the
combination that contained the price agreement,
id. at
362 U. S. 35-36,
and second because the agreement among retailers that the
manufacturer organized was a
horizontal conspiracy among
competitors.
Id. at
362 U. S.
46-47.
In sum, economic analysis supports the view, and no precedent
opposes it, that a vertical restraint is not illegal
per
se
Page 485 U. S. 736
unless it includes some agreement on price or price levels.
Accordingly, the judgment of the Fifth Circuit is
Affirmed.
JUSTICE KENNEDY took no part in the consideration or decision of
this case.
[
Footnote 1]
The Seventh, Eighth, and Tenth Circuits have agreed with the
analysis of the Fifth.
See Morrison v. Murray Biscuit Co.,
797 F.2d 1430, 1440 (CA7 1986);
McCabe's Furniture, Inc. v.
La-Z-Boy Chair Co., 798 F.2d 323, 329 (CA8 1986),
cert.
pending, No. 86-1101;
Westman Commission Co. v. Hobart
Int'l, Inc., 796 F.2d 1216, 1223-1224 (CA10 1986),
cert.
pending, No. 86-484. Decisions of the Third and Ninth Circuits
have disagreed.
See Cernuto, Inc. v. United Cabinet Corp.,
595 F.2d 164, 168170 (CA3 1979);
Zidell Explorations, Inc. v.
Conval Int'l, Ltd., 719 F.2d 1465, 1469-1470 (CA9 1983).
[
Footnote 2]
The dissent's principal fear appears to be not cartelization at
either level, but Hartwell's assertion of dominant retail power.
This fear does not possibly justify adopting a rule of
per
se illegality. Retail market power is rare, because of the
usual presence of interbrand competition and other dealers,
see
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U. S.
36,
433 U. S. 54
(1977), and it should therefore not be assumed, but rather must be
proved.
Cf. Baxter, The Viability of Vertical Restraints
Doctrine, 75 Calif.L.Rev. 933, 948-949 (1987). Of course, this case
was not prosecuted on the theory, and therefore the jury was not
asked to find, that Hartwell possessed such market power.
[
Footnote 3]
The conclusion of "naked" restraint could also be sustained on
another assumption, namely, that an agreement is not "ancillary"
unless it is designed to enforce a contractual obligation of one of
the parties to the contract. The dissent appears to accept this
assumption.
See post at
485 U. S.
739-741, and n. 3,
485 U. S.
744-746. It is plainly wrong. The classic "ancillary"
restraint is an agreement by the seller of a business not to
compete within the market.
See Mitchel v. Reynolds, 1
P.Wms. 181, 24 Eng. Rep. 347 (1711); Restatement (Second) of
Contracts § 188(2)(a) (1981). That is not ancillary to any other
contractual obligation, but, like the restraint here, merely
enhances the value of the contract, or permits the "enjoyment of
[its] fruits."
United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel
Co., 85 F. 271, 282 (CA6 1898),
aff'd, 175 U.
S. 211 (1899);
cf. Restatement (Second) of
Contracts §§ 187, 188 (1981) (restraint may be ancillary to a
"transaction or
relationship") (emphasis added); R. Bork,
The Antitrust Paradox 29 (1978) (hereinafter Bork) (vertical
arrangements are ancillary to the "transaction of supplying and
purchasing").
More important than the erroneousness of the dissent's common
law analysis of "naked" and "ancillary" restraints are the perverse
economic consequences of permitting nonprice vertical restraints to
avoid
per se invalidity only through attachment to an
express contractual obligation. Such an approach is contrary to the
express views of the principal scholar on whom the dissent relies.
See 7 P. Areeda, Antitrust Law § 1457c, p. 170 (1986)
(hereinafter Areeda) (legality of terminating price cutter should
not depend upon formal adoption of service obligations that
termination is assertedly designed to protect). In the precise case
of a vertical agreement to terminate other dealers, for example,
there is no conceivable reason why the existence of an exclusivity
commitment by the manufacturer to the one remaining dealer would
render anticompetitive effects less likely, or the procompetitive
effects on services more likely -- so that the dissent's line for
per se illegality fails to meet the requirement of
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. at
433 U. S. 59,
that it be based on "demonstrable economic effect." If anything,
the economic effect of the dissent's approach is perverse,
encouraging manufacturers to agree to otherwise inefficient
contractual provisions for the sole purpose of attaching to them
efficient nonprice vertical restraints which, only by reason of
such attachment, can avoid
per se invalidity as "naked"
restraints. The dissent's approach would therefore create precisely
the kind of "irrational dislocation in the market" that legal rules
in this area should be designed to avoid.
Monsanto Co. v.
Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U. S. 752,
465 U. S. 764
(1984).
[
Footnote 4]
The dissent apparently believes that whether a restraint is
horizontal depends upon whether its anticompetitive effects are
horizontal, and not upon whether it is the product of a horizontal
agreement.
Post at
485 U. S.
745-747, and n. 10. That is, of course, a conceivable
way of talking, but if it were the language of antitrust analysis,
there would be no such thing as an unlawful vertical restraint,
since all anticompetitive effects are, by definition, horizontal
effects. The dissent quotes a statement of Professor Areeda as
supposed adoption of its definition of horizontal restraint.
Post at
485 U. S.
745-746, n. 10, quoting Areeda § 1457d, p. 174. That
statement seems to us to be, to the contrary, Professor Areeda's
attempt to explain a peculiar usage of the term "horizontal" in
Cernuto, Inc. v. United Cabinet Corp., 595 F.2d at 168,
noting that (even though
Cernuto did not involve a
horizontal restraint) the use of the term "horizontal" was
"appropriate to capture the fact that dealer interests opposed to
those of the manufacturer were being served." Areeda § 1457d, p.
174. The dissent also seeks to associate Judge Bork with its
terminological confusion.
See post at
485 U. S. 746,
n. 10, quoting Bork 288. What the quoted passage says, however, is
that a facially vertical restraint imposed by a manufacturer only
because it has been coerced by a "horizontal carte[l]" agreement
among his distributors is in reality a horizontal restraint. That
says precisely what we say: that a restraint is horizontal not
because it has horizontal effects, but because it is the product of
a horizontal agreement.
[
Footnote 5]
Contrary to the dissent,
post at
485 U. S.
742-743,
485 U. S. 747,
General Motors does not differ from the present case
merely in that it involved a three-party, rather than a two-party,
agreement. The agreement was among competitors in
General
Motors; it was between noncompetitors here.
Cf. Bork
330 (defining "boycotts" as "agreements among competitors to refuse
to deal").
JUSTICE STEVENS, with whom JUSTICE WHITE joins, dissenting.
In its opinion, the majority assumes, without analysis, that the
question presented by this case concerns the legality of a
"vertical nonprice restraint." As I shall demonstrate, the
restraint that results when one or more dealers threaten to boycott
a manufacturer unless it terminates its relationship with a
price-cutting retailer is more properly viewed as a "horizontal
restraint." Moreover, an agreement to terminate a dealer because of
its price-cutting is most certainly not a "nonprice restraint." The
distinction between "vertical nonprice restraints" and "vertical
price restraints," on which the majority focuses its attention, is
therefore quite irrelevant to the outcome of this case. Of much
greater importance is the distinction between "naked restraints"
and "ancillary restraints" that has been a part of our law since
the landmark opinion written by Judge (later Chief Justice) Taft in
United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. 271
(CA6 1898),
aff'd, 175 U. S. 211
(1899).
I
The plain language of § 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits "every"
contract that restrains trade. [
Footnote 2/1] Because such a literal reading of the
statute would outlaw the entire body of private contract law, and
because Congress plainly intended
Page 485 U. S. 737
the Act to be interpreted in the light of its common law
background, the Court has long held that certain "ancillary"
restraints of trade may be defended as reasonable. As we recently
explained without dissent:
"The Rule of Reason suggested by
Mitchel v. Reynolds [1
P.Wms. 181, 24 Eng.Rep. 347 (1711)] has been regarded as a standard
for testing the enforceability of covenants in restraint of trade
which are ancillary to a legitimate transaction, such as an
employment contract or the sale of a going business. Judge (later
Mr. Chief Justice) Taft so interpreted the Rule in his classic
rejection of the argument that competitors may lawfully agree to
sell their goods at the same price as long as the agreed-upon price
is reasonable.
United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co. .
. ."
National Society of Professional Engineers v. United
States, 435 U. S. 679,
435 U. S. 689
(1978).
Judge Taft's rejection of an argument that a price-fixing
agreement could be defended as reasonable was based on a detailed
examination of common law precedents. He explained that, in
England, there had been two types of objection to voluntary
restraints on one's ability to transact business.
"One was that, by such contracts, a man disabled himself from
earning a livelihood, with the risk of becoming a public charge,
and deprived the community of the benefit of his labor. The other
was that such restraints tended to give to the covenantee, the
beneficiary of such restraints, a monopoly of the trade, from which
he had thus excluded one competitor, and by the same means might
exclude others."
85 F. at 279. Certain contracts, however, such as covenants not
to compete in a particular business, for a certain period of time,
within a defined geographical area, had always been considered
reasonable when necessary to carry out otherwise procompetitive
contracts, such as the sale of a business.
Id. at 280-282.
The difference between ancillary covenants that
Page 485 U. S. 738
may be justified as reasonable and those that are "void" because
there is "nothing to justify or excuse the restraint,"
id.
at 282-283, was described in the opinion's seminal discussion:
"[T]he contract must be one in which there is a main purpose, to
which the covenant in restraint of trade is merely ancillary. The
covenant is inserted only to protect one of the parties from the
injury which, in the execution of the contract or enjoyment of its
fruits, he may suffer from the unrestrained competition of the
other. The main purpose of the contract suggests the measure of
protection needed, and furnishes a sufficiently uniform standard by
which the validity of such restraints may be judicially determined.
In such a case, if the restraint exceeds the necessity presented by
the main purpose of the contract, it is void for two reasons:
first, because it oppresses the covenantor, without any
corresponding benefit to the covenantee, and, second, because it
tends to a monopoly. But where the sole object of both parties in
making the contract as expressed therein is merely to restrain
competition, and enhance or maintain prices, it would seem that
there was nothing to justify or excuse the restraint, that it would
necessarily have a tendency to monopoly, and therefore would be
void. In such a case, there is no measure of what is necessary to
the protection of either party, except the vague and varying
opinion of judges as to how much, on principles of political
economy, men ought to be allowed to restrain competition. There is
in such contracts no main lawful purpose, to subserve which partial
restraint is permitted, and by which its reasonableness is
measured, but the sole object is to restrain trade in order to
avoid the competition which it has always been the policy of the
common law to foster."
Ibid.
Although Judge Taft was writing as a Circuit Judge, his opinion
is universally accepted as authoritative. We affirmed
Page 485 U. S. 739
his decision without dissent, we have repeatedly cited it with
approval, [
Footnote 2/2] and it is
praised by a respected scholar as "one of the greatest, if not the
greatest, antitrust opinions in the history of the law." R. Bork,
The Antitrust Paradox 26 (1978). In accordance with the teaching in
that opinion, it is therefore appropriate to look more closely at
the character of the restraint of trade found by the jury in this
case.
II
It may be helpful to begin by explaining why the agreement in
this case does not fit into certain categories of agreement that
are frequently found in antitrust litigation. First, despite the
contrary implications in the majority opinion, this is not a case
in which the manufacturer is alleged to have imposed any vertical
nonprice restraints on any of its dealers. The term "vertical
nonprice restraint," as used in
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE
Sylvania Inc., 433 U. S. 36
(1977), and similar cases, refers to a contractual term that a
dealer must accept in order to qualify for a franchise. Typically,
the dealer must agree to meet certain standards in its advertising,
promotion, product display, and provision of repair and maintenance
services in order to protect the goodwill of the manufacturer's
product. Sometimes a dealer must agree to sell only to certain
classes of customers -- for example, wholesalers generally may only
sell to retailers and may be required not to sell directly to
consumers. In
Sylvania, to take another example, we
examined agreements between a manufacturer and its dealers that
included "provisions barring the retailers from selling franchised
products from locations other than those specified in agreements."
Id. at
433 U. S. 37.
Restrictions of that kind, which are a part of, or ancillary
to,
Page 485 U. S. 740
the basic franchise agreement, are perfectly lawful unless the
"rule of reason" is violated. Although vertical nonprice restraints
may have some adverse effect on competition, as long as they serve
the main purpose of a procompetitive distribution agreement, the
ancillary restraints may be defended under the rule of reason. And,
of course, a dealer who violates such a restraint may properly be
terminated by the manufacturer. [
Footnote 2/3]
In this case, it does not appear that respondent imposed any
vertical nonprice restraints upon either petitioner or Hartwell.
Specifically, respondent did not enter into any "exclusive"
agreement, as did the defendant in
Sylvania. It is true
that, before Hartwell was appointed and after petitioner was
terminated, the manufacturer was represented by only one retailer
in the Houston market, but there is no evidence that respondent
ever made any contractual commitment to give either of them any
exclusive rights. This therefore is not a case in which a
manufacturer's right to grant exclusive territories, or to change
the identity of the dealer in an established exclusive territory,
is implicated. The case is one in which one of two competing
dealers entered into an agreement with the manufacturer to
terminate a particular competitor without making any promise to
provide better or more efficient services and without receiving any
guarantee of exclusivity in the future. The contractual
relationship between respondent and Hartwell was exactly
Page 485 U. S. 741
the same after petitioner's termination as it had been before
that termination.
Second, this case does not involve a typical vertical price
restraint. As the Court of Appeals noted, there is some evidence in
the record that may support the conclusion that respondent and
Hartwell implicitly agreed that Hartwell's prices would be
maintained at a level somewhat higher than petitioner had been
charging before petitioner was terminated. 780 F.2d 1212, 1219 (CA5
1986). The illegality of the agreement found by the jury does not,
however, depend on such evidence. For purposes of analysis, we
should assume that no such agreement existed, and that respondent
was perfectly willing to allow its dealers to set prices at levels
that would maximize their profits. That seems to have been the
situation during the period when petitioner was the only dealer in
Houston. Moreover, after respondent appointed Hartwell as its
second dealer, it was Hartwell, rather than respondent, who
objected to petitioner's pricing policies.
Third, this is not a case in which the manufacturer acted
independently. Indeed, given the jury's verdict, it is not even a
case in which the termination can be explained as having been based
on the violation of any distribution policy adopted by respondent.
The termination was motivated by the ultimatum that respondent
received from Hartwell, and that ultimatum, in turn, was the
culmination of Hartwell's complaints about petitioner's competitive
price-cutting. The termination was plainly the product of coercion
by the stronger of two dealers, rather than an attempt to maintain
an orderly and efficient system of distribution. [
Footnote 2/4]
Page 485 U. S. 742
In sum, this case does not involve the reasonableness of any
vertical restraint imposed on one or more dealers by a manufacturer
in its basic franchise agreement. What the jury found was a simple
and naked "
agreement between Sharp and Hartwell to terminate
Business Electronics because of Business Electronics'
price-cutting.'" Ante at 485 U. S.
722.
III
Because naked agreements to restrain the trade of third parties
are seldom identified with such stark clarity as in this case,
there appears to be no exact precedent that determines the outcome
here. There are, however, perfectly clear rules that would be
decisive if the facts were changed only slightly.
Thus, on the one hand, if it were clear that respondent had
acted independently and decided to terminate petitioner because
respondent, for reasons of its own, objected to petitioner's
pricing policies, the termination would be lawful.
See United
States v. Parke, Davis & Co., 362 U. S.
29,
362 U. S. 43-45
(1960). On the other hand, it is equally clear that, if respondent
had been represented by three dealers in the Houston market instead
of only two, and if two of them had threatened to terminate their
dealerships "unless respondent ended its relationship with
petitioner within 30 days,"
ante at
485 U. S. 721,
an agreement to comply with the ultimatum would be an obvious
violation of the Sherman Act.
See, e.g., United States v.
General Motors Corp., 384 U. S. 127
(1966);
Klor's, Inc. v. Broadway-Hale Stores, Inc.,
359 U. S. 207
(1959). [
Footnote 2/5] The
Page 485 U. S. 743
question, then, is whether the two-party agreement involved in
this case is more like an illegal three-party agreement or a legal
independent decision. For me, the answer is plain.
The distinction between independent action and joint action is
fundamental in antitrust jurisprudence. [
Footnote 2/6]
Page 485 U. S. 744
Any attempt to define the boundaries of
per se
illegality by the number of parties to different agreements with
the same anticompetitive consequences can only breed uncertainty in
the law and confusion for the businessman.
More importantly, if, instead of speculating about irrelevant
vertical nonprice restraints, we focus on the precise character of
the agreement before us, we can readily identify its
anticompetitive nature. Before the agreement was made, there was
price competition in the Houston retail market for respondent's
products. The stronger of the two competitors was unhappy about
that competition; it wanted to have the power to set the price
level in the market, and therefore it "complained to respondent on
a number of occasions about petitioner's prices."
Ante at
485 U. S. 721.
Quite obviously, if petitioner had agreed with either Hartwell or
respondent to discontinue its competitive pricing, there would have
been no ultimatum from Hartwell and no termination by respondent.
It is equally obvious that either of those agreements would have
been illegal per se. [
Footnote 2/7]
Moreover, it is also reasonable to assume that, if respondent were
to replace petitioner with another price-cutting dealer, there
would soon be more complaints and another ultimatum from Hartwell.
Although respondent has not granted Hartwell an exclusive
dealership -- it retains the right to appoint multiple dealers --
its
Page 485 U. S. 745
agreement has protected Hartwell from price competition. Indeed,
given the jury's finding and the evidence in the record, that is
the sole function of the agreement found by the jury in this case.
It therefore fits squarely within the category of "naked restraints
of trade with no purpose except stifling of competition."
White
Motor Co. v. United States, 372 U. S. 253,
372 U. S. 263
(1963).
This is the sort of agreement that scholars readily characterize
as "inherently suspect." [
Footnote
2/8] When a manufacturer responds to coercion from a dealer,
instead of making an independent decision to enforce a
predetermined distribution policy, the anticompetitive character of
the response is evident. [
Footnote
2/9] As Professor Areeda has correctly noted, the fact that the
agreement is between only one complaining dealer and the
manufacturer does not prevent it from imposing a "horizontal"
restraint. [
Footnote 2/10] If two
critical facts are present -- a
Page 485 U. S. 746
naked purpose to eliminate price competition as such and
coercion of the manufacturer [
Footnote 2/11] -- the conflict with antitrust policy is
manifest. [
Footnote 2/12]
Page 485 U. S. 747
Indeed, since the economic consequences of Hartwell's ultimatum
to respondent are identical to those that would result from a
comparable ultimatum by two of three dealers in a market -- and
since a two-party price-fixing agreement is just as unlawful as a
three-party price-fixing agreement -- it is appropriate to employ
the term "boycott" to characterize this agreement. In my judgment,
the case is therefore controlled by our decision in
United
States v. General Motors Corp., 384 U.
S. 127 (1966).
The majority disposes quickly of both
General Motors
and
Klor's, Inc. v. Broadway-Hale Stores, Inc.,
359 U. S. 207
(1959), by concluding that "both cases involved horizontal
combinations."
Ante at
485 U. S. 734.
But this distinction plainly will
Page 485 U. S. 748
not suffice. In
General Motors, a group of Chevrolet
dealers conspired with General Motors to eliminate sales from the
manufacturer to discounting dealers. We held that "[e]limination,
by joint collaborative action, of discounters from access to the
market is a
per se violation of the Act," 384 U.S. at
384 U. S. 145,
and explained that
"inherent in the success of the combination in this case was a
substantial restraint upon price competition -- a goal unlawful
per se when sought to be effected by combination or
conspiracy."
Id. at
384 U. S. 147.
Precisely the same goal was sought and effected in this case -- the
elimination of price competition at the dealer level. Moreover, the
method of achieving that goal was precisely the same in both cases
-- the manufacturer's refusal to sell to discounting dealers. The
difference between the two cases is not a difference between
horizontal and vertical agreements -- in both cases, the critical
agreement was between market actors at the retail level on the one
hand and the manufacturer level on the other. Rather, the
difference is simply a difference in the number of conspirators.
Hartwell's coercion of respondent in order to eliminate petitioner
because of its same-level price competition is not different in
kind from the Chevrolet dealers' coercion of General Motors in
order to eliminate other, price-cutting dealers; the only
difference between the two cases -- one dealer seeking a naked
price-based restraint in today's case, many dealers seeking the
same end in
General Motors -- is merely a difference in
degree. Both boycotts lack any efficiency justification -- they are
simply naked restraints on price competition, rather than integral,
or ancillary, parts of the manufacturers' predetermined
distribution policies.
What is most troubling about the majority's opinion is its
failure to attach any weight to the value of intrabrand
competition. In
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE
Sylvania Inc.,
Page 485 U. S. 749
433 U. S. 36
(1977), we correctly held that a demonstrable benefit to interbrand
competition will outweigh the harm to intrabrand competition that
is caused by the imposition of vertical nonprice restrictions on
dealers. But we also expressly reaffirmed earlier cases in which
the illegal conspiracy affected only intrabrand competition.
[
Footnote 2/13] Not a word in the
Sylvania opinion implied that the elimination of
intrabrand competition could be justified as reasonable without any
evidence of a purpose to improve interbrand competition.
In the case before us today, the relevant economic market was
the sale at retail in the Houston area of calculators manufactured
by respondent. [
Footnote 2/14]
There is no dispute that an agreement
Page 485 U. S. 750
to fix prices in that market, either horizontally between
petitioner and Hartwell or vertically between respondent and either
or both of the two dealers, would violate the Sherman Act. The
"quite plausible" assumption,
see ante at
485 U. S. 729,
that such an agreement might enable the retailers to provide better
services to their customers would not have avoided the strict rule
against price-fixing that this Court has consistently enforced in
the past.
Page 485 U. S. 751
Under petitioner's theory of the case, an agreement between
respondent and Hartwell to terminate petitioner because of its
price-cutting was just as indefensible as any of those price-fixing
agreements. At trial, the jury found the existence of such an
agreement to eliminate petitioner's price competition. Respondent
had denied that any agreement had been made, and asked the jury to
find that it had independently decided to terminate petitioner
because of its poor sales performance, [
Footnote 2/15] but, after hearing several days of
testimony, the jury concluded that this defense was pretextual.
Neither the Court of Appeals nor the majority questions the
accuracy of the jury's resolution of the factual issues in this
case. Nevertheless, the rule the majority fashions today is based
largely on its concern that, in other cases, juries will be unable
to tell the difference between truthful and pretextual defenses.
Thus, it opines that
"even a manufacturer that agrees with one dealer to terminate
another for failure to provide contractually obligated services
exposes itself to the highly plausible claim that its real
motivation was to terminate a price-cutter."
Ante at
485 U. S. 728.
But such a "plausible" concern in a hypothetical case that is so
different from this one should not be given greater weight than
facts that can be established by hard evidence. If a dealer has, in
fact, failed to provide contractually obligated services, and if
the manufacturer has, in fact, terminated the dealer for that
reason, both of those objective facts should be provable by
admissible
Page 485 U. S. 752
evidence. [
Footnote 2/16] Both
in its disposition of this case and in its attempt to justify a new
approach to agreements to eliminate price competition, the majority
exhibits little confidence in the judicial process as a means of
ascertaining the truth. [
Footnote
2/17]
Page 485 U. S. 753
The majority fails to consider that manufacturers such as
respondent will only be held liable in the rare case in which the
following can be proved: First, the terminated dealer must overcome
the high hurdle of
Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service
Corp., 465 U. S. 752
(1984). A terminated dealer must introduce "evidence that tends to
exclude the possibility that the manufacturer and nonterminated
distributors were acting independently."
Id. at
465 U. S. 764.
Requiring judges to adhere to the strict test for agreement laid
down in
Monsanto, in their jury instructions or own
findings of fact, goes a long way toward ensuring that many
legitimate dealer termination decisions do not succumb improperly
to antitrust liability. [
Footnote
2/18]
Second, the terminated dealer must prove that the agreement was
based on a purpose to terminate it because of its price-cutting.
Proof of motivation is another commonplace in antitrust litigation
of which the majority appears apprehensive, but, as we have
explained or demonstrated many times,
see, e.g., 472 U.
S. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing
Page 485 U. S.
754
Corp., 472 U. S. 585,
472 U. S.
610-611 (1985);
McLain v. Real Estate Board of New
Orleans, Inc., 444 U. S. 232,
444 U. S. 243
(1980);
United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co.,
310 U. S. 150,
310 U. S.
224-226, n. 59 (1940);
Chicago Board of Trade v.
United States, 246 U. S. 231,
246 U. S. 238
(1918);
see also Piraino, The Case for Presuming the
Legality of Quality Motivated Restrictions on Distribution, 63
Notre Dame L.Rev. 1, 4, 16-19 (1988), in antitrust, as in many
other areas of the law, motivation matters and factfinders are able
to distinguish bad from good intent.
Third, the manufacturer may rebut the evidence tending to prove
that the sole purpose of the agreement was to eliminate a
price-cutter by offering evidence that it entered the agreement for
legitimate, nonprice-related reasons.
Although in this case the jury found a naked agreement to
terminate a dealer because of its price-cutting,
ante at
721-722, the majority boldly characterizes the same agreement as
"this nonprice vertical restriction."
Ante at
485 U. S. 729.
That characterization is surely an oxymoron when applied to the
agreement the jury actually found. Nevertheless, the majority
proceeds to justify it as "ancillary" to a "quite plausible purpose
. . . to enable Hartwell to provide better services under the sales
franchise agreement."
Ibid. There are two significant
reasons why that justification is unacceptable.
First, it is not supported by the jury's verdict. Although it
did not do so with precision, the District Court did instruct the
jury that, in order to hold respondent liable, it had to find that
the agreement's purpose was to eliminate petitioner because of its
price-cutting, and that no valid vertical nonprice restriction
existed to which the motivation to eliminate price competition at
the dealership level was merely ancillary. [
Footnote 2/19]
Page 485 U. S. 755
Second, the "quite plausible purpose" the majority hypothesizes
as salvation for the otherwise anticompetitive elimination of price
competition -- "to enable Hartwell to provide better services under
the sales franchise agreement,"
ibid., -- is simply not
the type of concern we sought to protect in
Continental T.V.,
Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U. S. 36
(1977). I have emphasized in this dissent the difference between
restrictions imposed in pursuit of a manufacturer's structuring of
its product distribution and those imposed at the behest of
retailers who care less about the general efficiency of a product's
promotion than their own profit margins.
Sylvania stressed
the importance of the former, not the latter; we referred to the
use that
manufacturers can
Page 485 U. S. 756
make of vertical nonprice restraints,
see id. at
433 U. S. 54-57,
and nowhere did we discuss the benefits of permitting dealers to
structure intrabrand competition at the retail level by coercing
manufacturers into essentially anticompetitive agreements. Thus,
while Hartwell may indeed be able to provide better services under
the sales franchise agreement with petitioner out of the way, one
would not have thought, until today, that the mere possibility of
such a result -- at the expense of the elimination of price
competition and absent the salutary overlay of a manufacturer's
distribution decision with the entire product line in mind -- would
be sufficient to legitimate an otherwise purely anticompetitive
restraint.
See n. 14,
supra. In fact, given the
majority's total reliance on "economic analysis,"
see ante
at
485 U. S. 735,
it is hard to understand why, if such a purpose were sufficient to
avoid the application of a
per se rule in this context,
the same purpose should not also be sufficient to trump the
per
se rule in all other price-fixing cases that arguably permit
cartel members to "provide better services."
If, however, we continue to accept the premise that competition
in the relevant market is worthy of legal protection -- that we
should not rely on competitive pressures exerted by sellers in
other areas and purveyors of similar but not identical products --
and if we are faithful to the competitive philosophy that has
animated our antitrust jurisprudence since Judge Taft's opinion in
Addyston Pipe, we can agree that the elimination of price
competition will produce wider gross profit margins for retailers,
but we may not assume that the retailer's self-interest will result
in a better marketplace for consumers.
"The Sherman Act reflects a legislative judgment that ultimately
competition will produce not only lower prices, but also better
goods and services. 'The heart of our national economic policy long
has been faith in the value of competition.'
Standard Oil Co.
v. FTC, 340 U. S. 231,
340 U. S.
248. The assumption that competition is the best
Page 485 U. S. 757
method of allocating resources in a free market recognizes that
all elements of a bargain -- quality, service, safety, and
durability -- and not just the immediate cost, are favorably
affected by the free opportunity to select among alternative
offers. Even assuming occasional exceptions to the presumed
consequences of competition, the statutory policy precludes inquiry
into the question whether competition is good or bad."
National Society of Professional Engineers v. United
States, 435 U.S. at
435 U. S.
695.
The "plausible purpose" posited by the majority as its sole
justification for this mischaracterized "nonprice vertical
restriction" is inconsistent with the legislative judgment that
underlies the Sherman Act itself. Under the facts as found by the
jury in this case, the agreement before us is one whose "sole
object is to restrain trade in order to avoid the competition which
it has always been the policy of the common law to foster."
United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. at
283.
V
In sum, this simply is not a case in which procompetitive
vertical nonprice restraints have been imposed; in fact, it is not
a case in which
any procompetitive agreement is at issue.
[
Footnote 2/20] The sole purpose
of the agreement between respondent
Page 485 U. S. 758
and Hartwell was to eliminate price competition at Hartwell's
level. As Judge Bork has aptly explained:
"Since the naked boycott is a form of predatory behavior, there
is little doubt that it should be a
per se violation of
the Sherman Act."
Bork, The Antitrust Paradox, at 334.
I respectfully dissent.
[
Footnote 2/1]
Section 1 of the Sherman Act, as set forth in 15 U.S.C. § 1,
provides:
"Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise,
or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several
States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal."
[
Footnote 2/2]
See, e.g., Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society,
457 U. S. 332,
457 U. S. 350,
n. 22 (1982);
United States v. Topco Associates, Inc.,
405 U. S. 596,
405 U. S. 608
(1972);
Northern Pacific R. Co. v. United States,
356 U. S. 1,
356 U. S. 5
(1958).
[
Footnote 2/3]
Thus, in
Morrison v. Murray Biscuit Co., 797 F.2d 1430
(CA7 1986), cited
ante at
485 U. S. 720,
n. 1, the plaintiff had been terminated because he violated a
lawful restriction on the customers to whom he could sell. As the
court correctly explained:
"As long as the supplier's motive is not to keep his established
dealers' prices up, but only to maintain his system of lawful
nonprice restrictions, he can terminate noncomplying dealers
without fear of antitrust liability even if he learns about the
violation from dealers whose principal or perhaps only concern is
with protecting their prices."
797 F.2d at 1440.
There was no such justification for the termination in this
case.
[
Footnote 2/4]
"When a manufacturer acts on its own in pursuing its own market
strategy, it is seeking to compete with other manufacturers by
imposing what may be defended as reasonable vertical restraints.
This would appear to be the rationale of the
GTE Sylvania
decision. However, if the action of a manufacturer or other
supplier is taken at the direction of its customer, the restraint
becomes primarily horizontal in nature, in that one customer is
seeking to suppress its competition by utilizing the power of a
common supplier. Therefore, although the termination in such a
situation is, itself, a vertical restraint, the desired impact is
horizontal, and on the dealer, not the manufacturer, level."
Cernuto, Inc. v. United Cabinet Corp., 595 F.2d 164,
168 (CA3 1979).
[
Footnote 2/5]
Thus, a boycott
"is not to be tolerated merely because the victim is just one
merchant whose business is so small that his destruction makes
little difference to the economy. Monopoly can as surely thrive by
the elimination of such small businessmen, one at a time, as it can
by driving them out in large groups."
Klor's, Inc. v. Broadway-Hale Stores, Inc., 359 U.S. at
359 U. S. 213
(footnote omitted). Again, Judge Adams' analysis in the
Cernuto opinion, n. 4,
supra, is relevant:
"The importance of the horizontal nature of this arrangement is
illustrated by
United States v. General Motors Corp.,
384 U. S.
127 . . . (1966). Although General Motors, the
manufacturer, was seemingly imposing vertical restraints when it
pressured recalcitrant automobile dealers not to deal with
discounters, the Supreme Court noted that, in fact, these
restraints were induced by the dealers seeking to choke off
aggressive competitors at their level, and found a
per se
violation, rejecting the suggestion that only unilateral restraints
were at issue. So here, if [the manufacturer and the sales
representative acted at the nonterminated dealer's] direction, both
the purpose and effect of the termination was to eliminate
competition at the retail level, and not, as in
GTE
Sylvania, to promote competition at the manufacturer level.
Accordingly, the pro-competitive redeeming virtues so critical in
GTE Sylvania may not be present here."
595 F.2d at 168 (footnote omitted).
As we said in
General Motors:
"The protection of price competition from conspiratorial
restraint is an object of special solicitude under the antitrust
laws. We cannot respect that solicitude by closing our eyes to the
effect upon price competition of the removal from the market, by
combination or conspiracy, of a class of traders. Nor do we propose
to construe the Sherman Act to prohibit conspiracies to fix prices
at which competitors may sell, but to allow conspiracies or
combinations to put competitors out of business entirely."
384 U.S. at
384 U. S.
148.
[
Footnote 2/6]
See United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.
S. 300,
250 U. S.
307-308 (1919). In
Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite
Service Corp., 465 U. S. 752,
465 U. S. 761
(1984), we noted that "the basic distinction between concerted and
independent action" was "not always clearly drawn by parties and
courts." In its opinion today, the majority virtually ignores that
basic distinction. Thus,
ante at
485 U. S. 728,
the majority discusses the manufacturer's risks arising out of its
agreement "with one dealer to terminate another for failure to
provide contractually obligated services." But if such a breach of
contract has occurred, the manufacturer should have an independent
motivation for acting, and need not enter into any agreement with a
dealer to do so. As we held in
Monsanto, the mere fact
that the breach of contract may have been called to the
manufacturer's attention by another dealer does not make the
manufacturer's independent decision to terminate a price-cutting
dealer unlawful.
[
Footnote 2/7]
"We have not wavered in our enforcement of the
per se
rule against price-fixing."
Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical
Society, 457 U.S. at
457 U. S. 347.
Thus, in
Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons
Co., 220 U. S. 373
(1911), the Court determined that vertical price fixing is
per
se invalid because resale price maintenance plans serve the
profit motives of the dealers, not the manufacturers, and are
thereby similar to plans pursuant to which the dealers themselves
conspire to fix prices.
Id. at
220 U. S.
407-408. There is no doubt that horizontal intrabrand
price fixing is
per se illegal, even if the conspirators
lack the market power to affect interbrand competition in a manner
that would violate the rule of reason.
[
Footnote 2/8]
"[S]cenarios that involve a firm or firms at one level of
activity using vertical restraints deliberately to confer market
power on firms at an adjacent level are inherently suspect. To do
so is, typically, to inflict self-injury, just as it would be for
consumers to confer market power on the retailers from whom they
buy."
Baxter, The Viability of Vertical Restraints Doctrine, 75
Calif.L.Rev. 933, 938 (1987).
[
Footnote 2/9]
"Termination responses reflecting the manufacturer's own
distribution policy differ greatly from those imposed upon him by a
complaining dealer. In the latter case, the manufacturer's
compliance with the complainer's demand is more likely to be
anticompetitive. There is a superficial resemblance to
Parke
Davis, in that three parties are involved, but my earlier
analysis suggested that the key to that case was 'complex
enforcement,' which is absent where a complaining dealer simply
threatens to abandon the manufacturer who continues selling to
discounting dealers."
7 P. Areeda, Antitrust Law § 1457, p. 166 (1986).
[
Footnote 2/10]
Commenting on Judge Adams' opinion in
Cernuto, see nn.
4 and 5,
supra, Professor Areeda wrote:
"That the complainer was a single firm did not weaken the
'horizontal' characterization. Because the elimination of price
competition was the purpose of the complaint and the termination,
the court declared that
per se illegality would be
appropriate. However, the court made clear that no illegal
agreement would be found if United was implementing its own
unilaterally chosen distribution policy. Thus, the court's implicit
theory was that an agreement arose when the manufacturer bowed to
the complainer's will. In that situation, the 'horizontal'
characterization is appropriate to capture the fact that dealer
interests opposed to those of the manufacturer were being
served."
Areeda,
supra, at 174 (footnotes omitted).
See
also R. Bork, The Antitrust Paradox 288 (1978):
"A restraint -- whether on price, territory, or any other term
-- is vertical, according to the usage employed here, when a firm
operating at one level of an industry places restraints upon
rivalry at another level for its own benefit. (This definition
excludes restraints, vertical in form only, that are actually
imposed by horizontal cartels at any level of the industry,
e.g., resale price maintenance that is compelled not by
the manufacturer, but by the pressure of organized retailers.)"
[
Footnote 2/11]
The two critical facts that had not yet been determined by a
jury in the
Cernuto case are perfectly plain in this case.
As Professor Areeda explained:
"The
Cernuto case was decided on summary judgment which
accepted the plaintiff's view of the facts. But two facts critical
for the court will often be obscure. First, was it the
manufacturer's purpose to eliminate price competition as such? Let
us assume that termination was not based on such completely
independent grounds as nonpayment of bills. Even so, the existence
of an inevitable price effect does not establish a purpose to
control prices in a forbidden way. A purpose to facilitate
point-of-sale services or to protect minimum economies of scale
could induce a manufacturer to limit intrabrand competition.
Notwithstanding price effects, such limitations are lawful when
reasonable and not subject to automatic condemnation. Indeed,
termination of one dealer in order to grant another exclusive
distribution rights in an area is generally lawful. Nevertheless,
so long as the manufacturer is not implementing his own interest,
but that of the complainer, the vice of eliminating 'horizontal'
competition with the complainer's rivals seems equally present when
the complainer thereby succeeds in eliminating horizontal
competition with respect to customers or territories. Second, was
the manufacturer coerced, or was he indulging his own preferences?
As we have seen, this question cannot be answered in the abstract.
The court correctly acknowledged that the manufacturer might also
be implementing his own unilateral vision of optimal distribution
without regard to the complainer's desires, and held that no
illegal agreement would arise if that were the case."
Areeda,
supra, at 174-175 (footnotes omitted).
[
Footnote 2/12]
"Let us defer for the moment problems of proof and assume that a
manufacturer does not wish to terminate the plaintiff dealer but
does so to placate the complaining dealer, who would otherwise
cease handling the product. This manufacturer would rather keep
both dealers, but, when forced to choose between them, concludes
that terminating the plaintiff hurts him less (considering sales
lost, transaction costs in finding and perhaps training a
replacement, and any spillover effects upon his relations with
other dealers) than losing the complainer's patronage."
"The present situation is
Colgate in reverse. In
Colgate, it was the supplier who was controlling the
dealer's behavior. Here a dealer is conditioning his patronage in a
way that controls the manufacturer's behavior. The agreement
concept seems parallel. But the economic effects can be very
different. From the policy viewpoint, it can matter greatly whether
manufacturer or dealer interests are being served. The former is
more likely to seek efficient distribution, which stimulates
interbrand competition; the latter is more likely to seek excess
profits, which dampen interbrand competition. Accordingly,
antitrust policy can be more hospitable toward manufacturer efforts
to control dealer prices, customers, or territories than toward the
efforts of dealers to control their competitors through the
manufacturer."
"Of course, manufacturer and dealer interests are not
necessarily antagonistic. Like the manufacturer, dealers might also
believe that restricted distribution increases dealer services and
sales, and thus strengthens interbrand competition. However, this
objective seems unlikely when the manufacturer is forced to violate
the distribution policy he thinks best. Although he might be
mistaken about what his optimal distribution policy ought to be, he
should be presumed a better judge of that than coercing dealers who
always desire excess profits unnecessary for efficient
distribution."
Areeda,
supra, at 167-168 (footnotes omitted).
[
Footnote 2/13]
See 433 U.S. at
433 U. S. 58, n.
28 (citing
United States v. General Motors Corp.,
384 U. S. 127
(1966), and
United States v. Topco Associates, Inc.,
405 U. S. 596
(1972)).
[
Footnote 2/14]
It might be helpful to note at this point that, although the
majority mentions only the reduction of interbrand competition as a
justification for a
per se rule against vertical price
restraints,
see ante at
485 U. S.
725-726, our opinion in
Sylvania was quite
different. As we stated then:
"The market impact of vertical restrictions is complex because
of their potential for a simultaneous reduction of intrabrand
competition and stimulation of interbrand competition.
Significantly, the Court in
Schwinn did not distinguish
among the challenged restrictions on the basis of their individual
potential for intrabrand harm or interbrand benefit. Restrictions
that completely eliminated intrabrand competition among Schwinn
distributors were analyzed no differently from those that merely
moderated intrabrand competition among retailers."
433 U.S. at
433 U. S. 51-52
(footnotes omitted). In the following pages, we pointed out that
because vertical nonprice restrictions imposed by manufacturers may
serve to advance interbrand competition, the restriction on
intrabrand competition should be subject only to a rule of reason
analysis. Along these same lines, we explained that
"[e]conomists also have argued that manufacturers have an
economic interest in maintaining as much intrabrand competition as
is consistent with the efficient distribution of their
products."
Id. at
433 U. S. 56.
Thus, although the majority neglects to mention it, fostering
intrabrand competition has been recognized as an important goal of
antitrust law, and although a manufacturer's efficiency-enhancing
vertical nonprice restraints may subject a reduction of intrabrand
competition only to a rule of reason analysis, a similar reduction
without the procompetitive "redeeming virtues" of
manufacturer-imposed vertical nonprice restraints,
id. at
433 U. S. 54,
causes nothing but economic harm. As one commentator has recently
stated:
"Intrabrand competition can benefit the consumer, and it is
therefore important to insure that a manufacturer's motive for a
vertical restriction is not simply to acquiesce in his
distributors' desires to limit competition among themselves. The
Supreme Court has recognized that restrictions on intrabrand
competition can only be tolerated because of the countervailing
positive impact on interbrand competition."
Piraino, The Case for Presuming the Legality of Quality
Motivated Restrictions on Distribution, 63 Notre Dame L.Rev. 1, 17
(1988) (footnotes omitted).
See also H.R.Rep. No. 100-421,
pp. 23, 38 (1987) (accompanying bill H.R. 585, the Freedom from
Vertical Price Fixing Act of 1987, passed by the House and
currently pending before the Senate; criticizing the Fifth
Circuit's decision in this case, and restating "plainly and
unequivocally that
all forms of resale price maintenance
are illegal
per se under the antitrust laws," including
"where a conspiracy exists between a supplier and distributor to
terminate or cut off supply to a second distributor because of the
second distributor's pricing policies") (emphasis in original);
Departments of Commerce, Justice, and State, the Judiciary and
Related Agencies Appropriation Act, 1986, Pub.L. 99-180, 99 Stat.
1169-1170 (congressional resolution that Department of Justice
Vertical Restraints Guidelines "are inconsistent with established
antitrust law, . . . in maintaining that such policy guidelines do
not treat vertical price fixing when, in fact, some provisions of
such policy guidelines suggest that certain price fixing
conspiracies are legal if such conspiracies are
limited' to
restricting intrabrand competition; . . . in stating that vertical
restraints that have an impact upon prices are subject to the
per se rule of illegality only if there is an `explicit
agreement as to the specific prices'"); Report of Attorney
General's National Committee to Study the Antitrust Laws 149-155
(1955) (criticizing laws that permit resale price maintenance as a
"throttling of price competition in the process of
distribution").
[
Footnote 2/15]
The court instructed the jury:
"Sharp, on the other hand, contends that it terminated Business
Electronics unilaterally, not as a result of any agreement or
understanding with Hartwell, but because of Business Electronics'
sales performance. If you find that Sharp did not terminate
Business Electronics pursuant to an agreement or understanding with
Hartwell to eliminate price-cutting by Business Electronics, then
you should answer 'no' to question number 1."
2 Record 1587.
See also nn.
485
U.S. 717fn2/18|>18-
485
U.S. 717fn2/19|>19,
infra.
[
Footnote 2/16]
In
Morrison v. Murray Biscuit Co., 797 F.2d 1430 (CA7
1986), cited
ante at 720, n. 1, Morrison, a wholesale
distributor, sued Murray Biscuit, a producer of cookies and
crackers, charging a conspiracy between Murray Biscuit and Feldman,
a food broker, to suppress price competition between Feldman and
Morrison. 797 F.2d at 1431. But it was quite clear that Murray
Biscuit
"had assigned particular customers to particular middlemen,
whether brokers [like Feldman] or warehouse distributors [like
Morrison]."
Id. at 1435. Judge Posner's opinion explained:
"Suppose that, after
Sylvania was decided, a seller
that had a price-fixing agreement (illegal
per se) with
its dealers adopted a lawful customer allocation agreement pursuant
to which it terminated a dealer. That dealer could not sue for
price-fixing, even if the price-fixing agreement had never been
rescinded,
unless he could show that his breach of the customer
allocation agreement was not the real reason for his termination;
maybe the agreement was a mask behind which the illegal price
fixing continued. The reason for Morrison's termination was
that he tried to take away a customer who had been assigned to
Feldman; there is no indication that the assignment was a mask for
resale price maintenance. Since Feldman had the exclusive right to
sell Murray Biscuit's products to the Certified account, Morrison
had no business selling to Certified at any price."
Id. at 1439 (emphasis added). Judge Posner thus made it
clear that, although Morrison had been terminated pursuant to a
valid vertical nonprice restraint, a terminated dealer might
prevail if it could prove that the nonprice agreement was "a mask
behind which the illegal price fixing continued."
Ibid.
[
Footnote 2/17]
"When faced with conflicting evidence, the jury must determine
whether the nonprice justifications for the termination advanced by
the defendant are legitimate, or are mere pretext to disguise a
per se illegal agreement with the nonterminated dealer to
maintain resale prices. It is the Court's duty under
Monsanto to decide whether sufficient evidence was
presented for a jury to make that determination."
McCabe's Furniture, Inc. v. La-Z-Boy Chair Co., 798
F.2d 323, 329 (CA8 1986), cited
ante at
485 U. S. 720,
n. 1.
See also L. Sullivan, Law of Antitrust 202 (1977)
("A shorthand method which may help to identify a restraint
affecting price as naked is to examine the arguments which are
being pressed in justification of the practice").
[
Footnote 2/18]
Although, at trial, respondent had asked the jury to find that
it had acted independently,
see 485
U.S. 717fn2/15|>n. 15,
supra, and accompanying
text, respondent has not disputed, either in the Court of Appeals
or here, the jury's finding of an agreement. (Respondent has, of
course, contended that no agreement was reached requiring some
level of resale price maintenance. As I have argued, though, such
an agreement is not needed to invoke the
per se rule in a
case such as this.) Respondent did argue before the District Court
for an instruction explaining that
"it must be shown that the manufacturer agreed with the
complaining dealer to terminate the existing dealer and that, in so
agreeing, the manufacturer shared with the complaining dealer the
same desire of eliminating price competition for the complaining
dealer."
1 Record 151. Respondent later objected to the court's decision
not to give this instruction,
id. at 54, 22 Record 1599,
but the court in fact had quite carefully explained to the jury
that
"[w]hat a preponderance . . . of the evidence in the case must
show in order to establish the existence of the required
combination, agreement, or understanding is that Sharp and Hartwell
knowingly came to a common and mutual understanding to accomplish
or to attempt to accomplish an unlawful purpose."
Id. at 1584-1585.
[
Footnote 2/19]
The Court instructed the jury:
"The Sherman Act is violated when a seller enters into an
agreement or understanding with one of its dealers to terminate
another dealer because of the other dealer's price-cutting.
Plaintiff contends that Sharp terminated Business Electronics in
furtherance of Hartwell's desire to eliminate Business Electronics
as a price-cutting rival."
"If you find that there was an agreement between Sharp and
Hartwell to terminate Business Electronics because of Business
Electronics' price-cutting, you should answer 'yes' to question
number 1."
"Sharp, on the other hand, contends that it terminated Business
Electronics unilaterally, not as a result of any agreement or
understanding with Hartwell, but because of Business Electronics'
sales performance. If you find that Sharp did not terminate
Business Electronics pursuant to an agreement or understanding with
Hartwell to eliminate price-cutting by Business Electronics, then
you should answer 'no' to question number 1."
22 Record 1587.
Respondent had asked for an instruction requiring the jury to
consider circumstantial evidence as proof of a motivation to
eliminate price competition only if such evidence could not
"equally be interpreted to show that Sharp terminated Business
Electronics Corporation for other business reasons, and not
pursuant to any agreement with Mr. Hartwell to fix resale prices of
calculators."
1 Record 148. Respondent objected to the failure to give this
instruction,
id. at 54, and also objected, more
specifically, to the instruction that was given on the ground
that
"it allows the jury to find against the defendant even if they
do not believe that Sharp cared about [Business Electronics']
price-cutting or if they believe that Sharp had a dual motive in
making the termination."
22 Record 1599. The instruction quoted above, though, makes it
highly unlikely that the jury would have found for petitioner
although finding respondent's motives to be mixed ones.
[
Footnote 2/20]
Thus, the Courts of Appeals decisions cited by the majority as
supporting its view,
see ante at
485 U. S. 720,
n. 1, are, in fact, consistent with the rule that a naked intent to
eliminate price competition is
per se invalid. Each of the
opinions contains a discussion that distinguishes between, on the
one hand, an agreement between manufacturer and dealer to eliminate
a price-cutting competitor based solely on an intent to eliminate
price competition, and, on the other hand, an agreement between
manufacturer and dealer to eliminate a price-cutting competitor
that is grounded not only in an antipathy to price competition, but
also in a purpose to implement a procompetitive system of vertical
nonprice restraints.
See McCabe's Furniture, Inc. v. La-Z-Boy
Chair Co., 798 F.2d at 329-330;
Morrison v. Murray Biscuit
Co., 797 F.2d at 1439-1440;
Westman Commission Co. v.
Hobart Int'l, Inc., 796 F.2d 1216, 1223 (CA10 1986). Moreover,
none of these opinions proposes the rule that the majority
sanctions today: that an agreement as to some level of resale price
maintenance is necessary for invocation of the
per se rule
in these situations.