Washington imposes a business and occupation (B & O) tax on
the privilege of engaging in business activities in the State,
including manufacturing in the State and making wholesale sales in
the State. The measure of the wholesale tax is the gross proceeds
of sales, and the measure of the manufacturing tax is the value of
the manufactured product. However, under the B & O tax's
"multiple activities exemption," local manufacturers are exempted
from the manufacturing tax for the portion of their output that is
subject to the wholesale tax. Application of the exemption results
in local manufacturers' paying the wholesale tax on local sales,
local manufacturers' paying only the manufacturing tax on their
out-of-state sales, and out-of-state manufacturers' paying the
wholesale tax on their sales in Washington. The same tax rate is
applicable to both wholesaling and manufacturing activities. In
both of the cases under review, which originated as state court tax
refund suits by appellants, local manufacturers who sold their
goods outside Washington and out-of-state manufacturers who sold
their goods in Washington, the trial court held that the multiple
activities exemption did not discriminate against interstate
commerce in violation of the Commerce Clause. In No. 85-1963,
appellant Tyler Pipe Industries, Inc. (Tyler) -- an out-of-state
manufacturer who sold its products in Washington but had no
property or employees in Washington, and whose solicitation of
business in Washington was conducted by an independent contractor
located in Washington -- also asserted that its business did not
have a sufficient nexus with Washington to justify the collection
of the tax on its wholesale sales there. The trial court upheld the
B & O tax. The Washington Supreme Court affirmed in both
cases.
Held:
1. Washington's manufacturing tax discriminates against
interstate commerce in violation of the Commerce Clause because,
through the operation of the multiple activities exemption, the tax
is assessed only on those products manufactured in Washington that
are sold to out-of-state customers. The exemption for local
manufacturers that sell their products
Page 483 U. S. 233
within the State has the same facially discriminatory
consequences as the West Virginia tax exemption that was
invalidated in
Armco Inc. v. Hardesty, 467 U.
S. 638, and the reasons for invalidating the tax in that
case also apply to the Washington tax. The facial
unconstitutionality of Washington's tax cannot be alleviated by
examining the effect of other States' tax legislation to determine
whether specific interstate transactions are subject to multiple
taxation. Nor can Washington's imposition of the manufacturing tax
on local goods sold outside the State be saved as a valid
"compensating tax." Manufacturing and wholesaling are not
"substantially equivalent events,"
id. at
467 U. S. 643,
such that taxing the manufacture of goods sold outside the State
can be said to compensate for the State's inability to impose a
wholesale tax on such goods.
Henneford v. Silas Mason Co.,
300 U. S. 577,
distinguished. To the extent that the ruling here is inconsistent
with the ruling in
General Motors Corp. v. Washington,
377 U. S. 436 --
where the B & O tax was upheld as against claims that it
unconstitutionally taxed unapportioned gross receipts and did not
bear a reasonable relation to the taxpayer's in-state activities --
that case is overruled. Pp.
483 U. S.
239-248.
2. The activities of Tyler's sales representative in Washington
adequately support the State's jurisdiction to tax Tyler's
wholesale sales to in-state customers. The showing of a sufficient
nexus cannot be defeated by the argument that the taxpayer's
representative was properly characterized as an independent
contractor, rather than an agent.
Cf. Scripto, Inc. v.
Carson, 362 U. S. 207. Nor
is there any merit to Tyler's contention that the B & O tax
does not fairly apportion the tax burden between its activities in
Washington and its activities in other States. Such contention
rests on the erroneous assumption that, through the B & O tax,
Washington is taxing the unitary activity of manufacturing and
wholesaling. The manufacturing tax and the wholesaling tax are not
compensating taxes for substantially equivalent events, and, thus,
the activity of wholesaling -- whether by an in-state or an
out-of-state manufacturer -- must be viewed as a separate activity
conducted wholly within Washington that no other State has
jurisdiction to tax. Pp.
483 U. S.
248-251.
3. Appellee's argument against retroactive application of any
adverse decision here should be considered, in the first instance,
by the Washington Supreme Court on remand.
Cf. Bacchus Imports,
Ltd. v. Dias, 468 U. S. 263. Pp.
483 U. S.
251-253.
105 Wash.
2d 318,
715
P.2d 123, and
105 Wash.
2d 327,
715 P.2d
128, vacated and remanded.
STEVENS, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
BRENNAN, WHITE, MARSHALL, BLACKMUN, and O'CONNOR, JJ., joined, and
in Part
Page 483 U. S. 234
IV of which SCALIA, J., joined. O'CONNOR, J., filed a concurring
opinion,
post p.
483 U. S. 253.
SCALIA, J., filed an opinion concurring in part and dissenting in
part, in Part I of which REHNQUIST, C.J., joined,
post p.
483 U. S. 254.
POWELL, J., took no part in the consideration or decision of the
cases.
JUSTICE STEVENS delivered the opinion of the Court.
In
Armco Inc. v. Hardesty, 467 U.
S. 638 (1984), we held that West Virginia's gross
receipts tax on the business of selling tangible property at
wholesale discriminated against interstate commerce because it
exempted local manufacturers. The principal question in these
consolidated appeals is whether Washington's manufacturing tax
similarly violates the Commerce Clause of the Constitution because
it is assessed only on those products manufactured within
Washington that are sold to out-of-state purchasers. We conclude
that our reasons for invalidating the West Virginia tax in
Armco also apply to the Washington tax challenged
here.
I
For over half a century, Washington has imposed a business and
occupation (B & O) tax on "the act or privilege of engaging
Page 483 U. S. 235
in business activities" in the State. Wash.Rev.Code § 82.04.220
(1985). The tax applies to the activities of extracting raw
materials in the State, [
Footnote
1] manufacturing in the State, [
Footnote 2] making wholesale sales in the State, [
Footnote 3] and making retail sales in
the State. [
Footnote 4] The
State has typically applied the same tax rates to these different
activities. The measure of the selling tax is the "gross proceeds
of sales," and the measure of the manufacturing tax is the value of
the manufactured products. §§ 82.04.220, 82.04.240.
Prior to 1950, the B & O tax contained a provision that
exempted persons who were subject to either the extraction tax or
the manufacturing tax from any liability for either the wholesale
tax or the retail tax on products extracted or manufactured in the
State. [
Footnote 5] Thus, the
wholesale tax applied to out-of-state manufacturers but not to
local manufacturers. In 1948, the Washington Supreme Court held
that this wholesale tax exemption for local manufacturers
discriminated against interstate commerce and therefore violated
the Commerce Clause of the Federal Constitution.
Columbia Steel
Co. v. State, 30 Wash. 2d 658, 192 P.2d 976 (1948). The State
Supreme Court rejected the State's argument that the taxpayer had
not suffered from discrimination against interstate commerce,
because it had not proved that it paid manufacturing
Page 483 U. S. 236
tax to another State. [
Footnote
6] The Washington Supreme Court also dismissed the State's
contention that, if the State in which a good was manufactured did
not impose a manufacturing tax, the seller of the good would have a
competitive advantage over Washington manufacturers:
"[T]he situation obtaining in another state is immaterial. We
must interpret the statute as passed by the legislature. In our
opinion, the statute marks a discrimination against interstate
commerce in levying a tax upon wholesale activities of those
engaged in interstate commerce, which tax is, because of the
exemption contained in § 8370-6, not levied upon those who perform
the same taxable act, but who manufacture in the state of
Washington."
Id. at 664, 192 P.2d at 979.
Two years later, in 1950, the Washington Legislature responded
to this ruling by turning the B & O tax exemption scheme inside
out. The legislature removed the wholesale tax exemption for local
manufacturers and replaced it with an exemption from the
manufacturing tax for the portion of manufacturers' output that is
subject to the wholesale tax. [
Footnote 7] The result, as before 1950, is that local
manufacturers pay the manufacturing tax on their interstate sales
and out-of-state manufacturers pay the wholesale tax on their sales
in Washington. Local manufacturer-wholesalers continue to
Page 483 U. S. 237
pay only one gross receipts tax, but it is now applied to the
activity of wholesaling, rather than the activity of manufacturing.
Although the tax rate has changed over the years -- it is now
forty-four hundredths of one percent, or 0.44%, of gross receipts
-- the relevant provisions of Washington's B & O tax are the
same today as enacted in 1950. [
Footnote 8]
The constitutionality of the B & O tax has been challenged
on several occasions, [
Footnote
9] most strenuously in
General Motors Corp. v.
Washington, 377 U. S. 436
(1964). In that case, a bare majority of the Court upheld the tax;
JUSTICE BRENNAN and Justice Goldberg filed dissenting opinions. The
bulk of the Court's opinion was devoted to rejecting the claims
that the statute unconstitutionally taxed unapportioned gross
receipts and did not bear a reasonable relation to the taxpayer's
in-state activities. At the end of its opinion, the Court declined
to reach the argument that the tax imposed multiple tax burdens on
interstate transactions, because the taxpayer had failed to
demonstrate "what definite
Page 483 U. S. 238
burden, in a constitutional sense" other States' laws had placed
on "the identical interstate shipments by which Washington measures
its tax."
Id. at
377 U. S. 449.
Justice Goldberg, joined by Justice Stewart and JUSTICE WHITE,
dissented because "[t]he burden on interstate commerce and the
dangers of multiple taxation" were apparent from the face of the
statute.
Id. at
377 U. S. 459.
[
Footnote 10] Comparing the
current statute
Page 483 U. S. 239
with its invalid predecessor, this dissent concluded that
the
"amended provision would seem to have essentially the same
economic effect on interstate sales, but has the advantage of
appearing nondiscriminatory."
Id. at
377 U. S. 460.
Today we squarely address the claim that this provision
discriminates against interstate commerce.
II
Two appeals are before us. In the first case (No. 852006), 71
commercial enterprises filed 53 separate actions for refunds of B
& O taxes paid to the State. The Thurston County Superior Court
joined the actions, found that the multiple activities exemption
did not violate the Commerce Clause, and granted the State
Department of Revenue's motion for summary judgment. In the second
case (No. 851963), Tyler Pipe Industries, Inc. (Tyler), sought a
refund of B & O taxes paid during the years 1976 through 1980
for its wholesaling activities in Washington. Again, the Superior
Court upheld the B & O tax. The Washington Supreme Court
affirmed in both cases.
105 Wash.
2d 327, 732 P.2d 134 (1986);
105 Wash.
2d 318,
715 P.2d
123 (1986).
The State Supreme Court concluded that the B & O tax was not
facially discriminatory, and rejected the appellants' arguments
that our decision invalidating West Virginia's exemption for local
wholesaler-manufacturers,
Armco Inc. v. Hardesty,
467 U. S. 638
(1984), required that the B & O tax be invalidated. The state
court expressed the view that the West Virginia wholesale tax
imposed on out-of-state manufacturers in
Armco could not
be justified as a compensating tax, because of the substantial
difference between the State's tax rates on manufacturing
activities (.0088) and wholesaling activities (.0027), and because
West Virginia did not provide for a reduction in its manufacturing
tax when the manufactured goods were sold out of State, but did
reduce the tax when the goods were partly manufactured out of
State. The Washington Supreme Court then concluded that our
requirement
Page 483 U. S. 240
that a tax must have
"'what might be called internal consistency -- that is, the
[tax] must be such that, if applied by every jurisdiction,' there
would be no impermissible interference with free trade,"
Armco, 467 U.S. at
467 U. S. 644,
was not dispositive because it merely relieved the taxpayer of the
burden of proving that a tax already demonstrated to be facially
discriminatory had, in fact, resulted in multiple taxation. The
Washington Supreme Court also rejected the taxpayers' arguments
that the B & O tax is not fairly apportioned to reflect the
amount of business conducted in the State, and is not fairly
related to the services rendered by Washington.
We noted probable jurisdiction of the taxpayers' appeals, 479
U.S. 810 (1986), and now reverse in part and affirm in part. We
first consider the claims of the taxpayers that have manufacturing
facilities in Washington and market their products in other States;
their challenge is directed to the fact that the manufacturing tax
is levied only on those goods manufactured in Washington that are
sold outside the State. We then consider Tyler's claims that its
activities in the State of Washington are not sufficient to subject
it to the State's taxing jurisdiction, and that the B & O tax
is not fairly apportioned.
III
A person subject to Washington's wholesale tax for an item is
not subject to the State's manufacturing tax for the same item.
This statutory exemption for manufacturers that sell their products
within the State has the same facially discriminatory consequences
as the West Virginia exemption we invalidated in
Armco.
West Virginia imposed a gross receipts tax at the rate of 0.27% on
persons engaged in the business of selling tangible property at
wholesale. Local manufacturers were exempt from the tax, but paid a
manufacturing tax of 0.88% on the value of products manufactured in
the State. Even though local manufacturers bore a higher tax burden
in dollars and cents, we held that their exemption from the
wholesale tax violated the principle that "a State may not tax
Page 483 U. S. 241
a transaction or incident more heavily when it crosses state
lines than when it occurs entirely within the State." 467 U.S. at
467 U. S.
642.
In explaining why the tax was discriminatory on its face, we
expressly endorsed the reasoning of Justice Goldberg's dissenting
opinion in
General Motors Corp. v. Washington, 377 U.S. at
377 U. S. 459.
We explained:
"The tax provides that two companies selling tangible property
at wholesale in West Virginia will be treated differently depending
on whether the taxpayer conducts manufacturing in the State or out
of it. Thus, if the property was manufactured in the State, no tax
on the sale is imposed. If the property was manufactured out of the
State and imported for sale, a tax of 0.27% is imposed on the sale
price.
See General Motors Corp. v. Washington,
377 U. S.
436,
377 U. S. 459 (1964)
(Goldberg, J., dissenting) (similar provision in Washington, 'on
its face, discriminated against interstate wholesale sales to
Washington purchasers for it exempted the intrastate sales of
locally made products while taxing the competing sales of
interstate sellers');
Columbia Steel Co. v. State, 30
Wash. 2d 658, 664, 192 P.2d 976, 979 (1948) (invalidating
Washington tax)."
467 U.S. at
467 U. S.
642.
Our square reliance in
Armco on Justice Goldberg's
earlier dissenting opinion is especially significant because that
dissent dooms appellee's efforts to limit the reasoning of
Armco to the precise statutory structure at issue in that
case. Justice Goldberg expressly rejected the distinction appellee
attempts to draw between an exemption from a wholesaling tax -- as
was present in
Armco -- and the exemption from a
manufacturing tax which was present in
General Motors and
is again present in these cases.
See 377 U.S. at
377 U. S.
459-460. Our holding in
Armco requires that we
now agree with Justice Goldberg's conclusion that the exemption
before us is the practical equivalent of the exemption that the
Washington Supreme Court invalidated in 1948.
Page 483 U. S. 242
General Motors is not a controlling precedent. As we
have already noted, the result in that case did not depend on the
Court's resolution of whether the tax burdened interstate commerce.
Our reason for not passing on that question was that the taxpayer
had
"not demonstrated what definite burden, in a constitutional
sense [the tax imposed by other States] places on the identical
shipments by which Washington measures its tax."
377 U.S. at
377 U. S. 449.
Thus, when
General Motors was decided, the Court required
the taxpayer to prove that specific interstate transactions were
subjected to multiple taxation in order to advance a claim of
discrimination.
See also Standard Pressed Steel Co. v.
Washington Revenue Dept., 419 U. S. 560,
419 U. S. 563
(1975) (rejecting Commerce Clause claim because taxpayer made no
showing of risk of multiple taxation). In
Armco, however,
we categorically rejected this requirement. The facial
unconstitutionality of Washington's gross receipts tax cannot be
alleviated by examining the effect of legislation enacted by its
sister States.
See Moorman Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437 U.
S. 267,
437 U. S.
276-278 (1978). [
Footnote 11]
We also reject the Department's contention that the State's
imposition of the manufacturing tax on local goods sold outside the
State should be saved as a valid "compensating tax." As we noted in
Maryland v. Louisiana, 451 U. S. 725,
451 U. S. 758
(1981), the "concept of a compensatory tax first requires
identification of the burden for which the State is attempting to
compensate." In these cases, the only burden
Page 483 U. S. 243
for which the manufacturing tax exemption is arguably
compensatory is the State's imposition of a wholesale tax on the
local sales of local manufacturers; absent the exemption, a local
manufacturer might be at an economic disadvantage because it would
pay both a manufacturing and a wholesale tax, while the
manufacturer from afar would pay only the wholesale tax. The
State's justification for thus taxing the manufacture of goods in
interstate commerce, however, fails under our precedents. The local
sales of out-of-state manufacturers are also subject to
Washington's wholesale tax, but the multiple activities exemption
does not extend its ostensible compensatory benefit to those
manufacturers. The exemption thus does not merely erase a tax
incentive to engage in interstate commerce instead of intrastate
commerce; it affirmatively places interstate commerce at a
disadvantage.
"[T]he common theme running through the cases in which this
Court has sustained compensating" taxes is "[e]qual treatment of
interstate commerce."
Boston Stock Exchange v. State Tax
Comm'n, 429 U. S. 318,
429 U. S. 331
(1977).
See also Maryland v. Louisiana, 451 U.S. at
451 U. S. 759.
In
Boston Stock Exchange, a New York transfer tax on
securities transactions taxed transactions involving an
out-of-state sale more heavily than other transactions involving an
in-state sale. We invalidated the tax, rejecting the State's claim
that it was compensatory legislation designed to neutralize the
competitive advantage enjoyed by stock exchanges outside New York.
We concluded:
"Because of the delivery or transfer in New York, the seller
cannot escape tax liability by selling out of State, but he can
substantially reduce his liability by selling in State. The obvious
effect of the tax is to extend a financial advantage to sales on
the New York exchanges at the expense of the regional exchanges.
Rather than 'compensating' New York for a supposed competitive
disadvantage resulting from § 270, the amendment forecloses
tax-neutral decisions and creates both an advantage
Page 483 U. S. 244
for the exchanges in New York and a discriminatory burden on
commerce to its sister States."
429 U.S. at
429 U. S.
331.
Similarly, in
Maryland v. Louisiana, we held that a tax
on the first use in Louisiana of gas brought into the State was not
a "complement of a severance tax in the same amount imposed on gas
produced within the State."
Armco, 467 U.S. at
467 U. S.
642-643, citing
Maryland v. Louisiana, 451 U.S.
at
451 U. S.
758-759. We relied on the observation that severance and
first use were not "substantially equivalent" events on which
mutually compensating taxes might be imposed. And in
Armco
we squarely held that manufacturing and wholesaling are not
substantially equivalent activities. As we wrote in that case:
"The gross sales tax imposed on
Armco cannot be deemed
a 'compensating tax' for the manufacturing tax imposed on its West
Virginia competitors. . . . Here, too, manufacturing and
wholesaling are not 'substantially equivalent events' such that the
heavy tax on in-state manufacturers can be said to compensate for
the admittedly lighter burden placed on wholesalers from out of
State. Manufacturing frequently entails selling in the State, but
we cannot say which portion of the manufacturing tax is
attributable to manufacturing, and which portion to sales."
467 U.S. at
467 U. S.
642-643.
See also Bacchus Imports, Ltd. v.
Dias, 468 U. S. 263,
468 U. S. 272
(1984). In light of the facially discriminatory nature of the
multiple activities exemption, we conclude, as we did in
Armco, that manufacturing and wholesaling are not
"substantially equivalent events" such that taxing the manufacture
of goods sold outside the State can be said to compensate for the
State's inability to impose a wholesale tax on those goods.
[
Footnote 12]
Page 483 U. S. 245
Appellee also contends that its B & O tax is valid because
of its asserted similarities to a tax and exemption system we have
upheld. The State assessed a use tax on personal property used
within the State but originally purchased elsewhere to compensate
for the burden that a sales tax placed on similar property
purchased within the State.
See Henneford v. Silas Mason
Co., 300 U. S. 577
(1937). Appellee's reliance on
Henneford v. Silas Mason
Co., however, does not aid its cause. That case addressed a
use tax imposed by the State of Washington on the "privilege of
using within this state any article of tangible personal property."
The tax did not apply to "the use of any article of tangible
personal property" the sale or use of which had already been taxed
at an equal or greater rate under the laws of Washington or some
other State.
Id. at
300 U. S.
580-581. We upheld the tax because, in the context of
the overall tax structure, the burden it placed on goods purchased
out-of-state was identical to that placed on an equivalent purchase
within the State. This identical impact was no fortuity; it was
guaranteed by the statutory exemption from the use tax for goods on
which a sales tax had already been paid, [
Footnote 13] regardless of whether the sales tax had
been paid to Washington or to another State. [
Footnote 14]
Page 483 U. S. 246
As we explained in
Halliburton Oil Well Cementing Co. v.
Reily, 373 U. S. 64,
373 U. S. 70
(1963):
"The conclusion is inescapable: equal treatment for in-state and
out-of-state taxpayers similarly situated is the condition
precedent for a valid use tax on goods imported from
out-of-state."
The parallel condition precedent for a valid multiple activities
exemption eliminating exposure to the burden of a multiple tax on
manufacturing and wholesaling would provide a credit against
Washington tax liability for wholesale taxes paid by local
manufacturers to any State, not just Washington. The multiple
activities exemption only operates to impose a unified tax
eliminating the risk of multiple taxation when the acts of
manufacturing and wholesaling are both carried out within the
State. The exemption excludes similarly situated manufacturers and
wholesalers which conduct one of those activities within Washington
and the other activity outside
Page 483 U. S. 247
the State. Washington's B & O tax scheme is therefore
inconsistent with our precedents holding that a tax violates the
Commerce Clause "when it unfairly burdens commerce by exacting more
than a just share from the interstate activity."
Washington
Dept. of Revenue v. Association of Washington Stevedoring
Cos., 435 U. S. 734,
435 U. S. 748
(1978).
As we explained in
Armco, our conclusion that a tax
facially discriminates against interstate commerce need not be
confirmed by an examination of the tax burdens imposed by other
States:
"Appellee suggests that we should require
Armco to
prove actual discriminatory impact on it by pointing to a State
that imposes a manufacturing tax that results in a total burden
higher than that imposed on
Armco's competitors in West
Virginia. This is not the test. In
Container Corp. of America
v. Franchise Tax Board, 463 U. S. 159,
463 U. S.
169 (1983), the Court noted that a tax must have 'what
might be called internal consistency -- that is, the [tax] must be
such that, if applied by every jurisdiction,' there would be no
impermissible interference with free trade. In that case, the Court
was discussing the requirement that a tax be fairly apportioned to
reflect the business conducted in the State. A similar rule applies
where the allegation is that a tax on its face discriminates
against interstate commerce. A tax that unfairly apportions income
from other States is a form of discrimination against interstate
commerce.
See also id. at
463 U. S.
170-171. Any other rule would mean that the
constitutionality of West Virginia's tax laws would depend on the
shifting complexities of the tax codes of 49 other States, and that
the validity of the taxes imposed on each taxpayer would depend on
the particular other States in which it operated."
467 U.S. at
467 U. S.
644-645 (footnote omitted). [
Footnote 15]
Page 483 U. S. 248
We conclude that Washington's multiple activities exemption
discriminates against interstate commerce as did the tax struck
down by the Washington Supreme Court in 1948 and the West Virginia
tax that we invalidated in
Armco. The current B & O
tax exposes manufacturing or selling activity outside the State to
a multiple burden from which only the activity of manufacturing
in-state and selling in-state is exempt. The fact that the B &
O tax "has the advantage of appearing nondiscriminatory,"
see
General Motors Corp., 377 U.S. at
377 U. S. 460
(Goldberg, J., dissenting), does not save it from invalidation. To
the extent that this conclusion is inconsistent with the Court's
ruling in the
General Motors case, that case is overruled.
[
Footnote 16]
IV
Our holding that Washington's tax exemption for a local
manufacturer-wholesaler violates the Commerce Clause disposes of
the issues raised by those appellants in
National Can that
manufacture goods in Washington and sell them outside the State, as
well as the claim of discrimination asserted by those appellants
that manufacture goods outside Washington and sell them within the
State. Compliance
Page 483 U. S. 249
with our holding on the discrimination issue, however, would not
necessarily preclude the continued assessment of a wholesaling tax.
Either a repeal of the manufacturing tax or an expansion of the
multiple activities exemption to provide out-of-state manufacturers
with a credit for manufacturing taxes paid to other States would
presumably cure the discrimination. We must therefore also consider
the alternative challenge to the wholesale tax advanced by Tyler
and the other appellants that manufacture products outside of
Washington for sale in the State.
Tyler seeks a refund of wholesale taxes it paid on sales to
customers in Washington for the period from January 1, 1976,
through September 30, 1980. These products were manufactured
outside of Washington. Tyler argues that its business does not have
a sufficient nexus with the State of Washington to justify the
collection of a gross receipts tax on its sales. Tyler sells a
large volume of cast iron, pressure and plastic pipe and fittings,
and drainage products in Washington, but all of those products are
manufactured in other States. Tyler maintains no office, owns no
property, and has no employees residing in the State of Washington.
Its solicitation of business in Washington is directed by
executives who maintain their offices out-of-state, and by an
independent contractor located in Seattle.
The trial court found that the in-state sales representative
engaged in substantial activities that helped Tyler to establish
and maintain its market in Washington. The State Supreme Court
concluded that those findings were supported by the evidence, and
summarized them as follows:
"The sales representatives acted daily on behalf of Tyler Pipe
in calling on its customers and soliciting orders. They have
long-established and valuable relationships with Tyler Pipe's
customers. Through sales contacts, the representatives maintain and
improve the name recognition, market share, goodwill, and
individual customer relations of Tyler Pipe. "
Page 483 U. S. 250
"Tyler Pipe sells in a very competitive market in Washington.
The sales representatives provide Tyler Pipe with virtually all
their information regarding the Washington market, including:
product performance; competing products; pricing, market conditions
and trends; existing and upcoming construction products; customer
financial liability; and other critical information of a local
nature concerning Tyler Pipe's Washington market. The sales
representatives in Washington have helped Tyler Pipe, and have a
special relationship to that corporation. The activities of Tyler
Pipe's agents in Washington have been substantial."
105 Wash. 2d at 325, 715 P.2d at 127.
As a matter of law, the Washington Supreme Court concluded that
this showing of a sufficient nexus could not be defeated by the
argument that the taxpayer's representative was properly
characterized as an independent contractor, instead of as an agent.
We agree with this analysis. In
Scripto, Inc. v. Carson,
362 U. S. 207
(1960), Scripto, a Georgia corporation, had no office or regular
employees in Florida, but it employed wholesalers or jobbers to
solicit sales of its products in Florida. We held that Florida may
require these solicitors to collect a use tax from Florida
customers. Although the "salesmen" were not employees of Scripto,
we determined that "such a fine distinction is without
constitutional significance."
Id. at
362 U. S. 211.
This conclusion is consistent with our more recent cases.
See
National Geographic Society v. California Equalization Board,
430 U. S. 551,
430 U. S.
556-558 (1977).
As the Washington Supreme Court determined,
"the crucial factor governing nexus is whether the activities
performed in this state on behalf of the taxpayer are significantly
associated with the taxpayer's ability to establish and maintain a
market in this state for the sales."
105 Wash. 2d at 323, 715 P.2d at 126. The court found this
standard was
Page 483 U. S. 251
satisfied because Tyler's "sales representatives perform any
local activities necessary for maintenance of Tyler Pipe's market
and protection of its interests. . . ."
Id. at 321, 715
P.2d at 125. We agree that the activities of Tyler's sales
representatives adequately support the State's jurisdiction to
impose its wholesale tax on Tyler.
Tyler also asserts that the B & O tax does not fairly
apportion the tax burden between its activities in Washington and
its activities in other States.
See Complete Auto Transit, Inc.
v. Brady, 430 U. S. 274,
430 U. S. 285
(1977). Washington taxes the full value of receipts from in-state
wholesaling or manufacturing; thus, an out-of-state manufacturer
selling in Washington is subject to an unapportioned wholesale tax
even though the value of the wholesale transaction is partly
attributable to manufacturing activity carried on in another State
that plainly has jurisdiction to tax that activity. This
apportionment argument rests on the erroneous assumption that,
through the B & O tax, Washington is taxing the unitary
activity of manufacturing and wholesaling. We have already
determined, however, that the manufacturing tax and wholesaling tax
are not compensating taxes for substantially equivalent events in
invalidating the multiple activities exemption. Thus, the activity
of wholesaling -- whether by an in-state or an out-of-state
manufacturer -- must be viewed as a separate activity conducted
wholly within Washington that no other State has jurisdiction to
tax.
See Moorman Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437 U.S. at
437 U. S.
280-281 (gross receipts tax on sales to customers within
State would be "plainly valid");
Standard Pressed Steel Co. v.
Washington Revenue Dept., 419 U.S. at
419 U. S. 564
(selling tax measured by gross proceeds of sales is "apportioned
exactly to the activities taxed").
V
The Department of Revenue argues that any adverse decision in
these cases should not he applied retroactively, because the taxes
at issue were assessed prior to our opinion in
Page 483 U. S. 252
Armco, and the holding in that case was not clearly
foreshadowed by earlier opinions.
See Chevron Oil Co. v.
Huson, 404 U. S. 97,
404 U. S.
106-107 (1971) (factors to consider in deciding whether
to impose decision prospectively only). The State's argument is
similar to an argument advanced by the State of Hawaii in
Bacchus Imports, Ltd. v. Dias, 468 U.S. at
468 U. S.
276-277. The State urged that, if we invalidated the tax
at issue, we should not require the payment of refunds to
taxpayers. We did not resolve the merits of that issue, concluding
that this Court should not take it upon itself in this complex area
of state tax structures to determine how to apply its holding:
"These refund issues, which are essentially issues of remedy for
the imposition of a tax that unconstitutionally discriminated
against interstate commerce, were not addressed by the state
courts. Also, the federal constitutional issues involved may well
be intertwined with, or their consideration obviated by, issues of
state law. Also, resolution of those issues, if required at all,
may necessitate more of a record than so far has been made in this
case. We are reluctant, therefore, to address them in the first
instance. Accordingly, we reverse the judgment of the Supreme Court
of Hawaii and remand for further proceedings not inconsistent with
this opinion."
Id. at
468 U. S. 277
(footnote omitted).
We followed this approach in
Williams v. Vermont,
472 U. S. 14
(1985), an opinion which invalidated the State's residency
restriction on the availability of a sales tax credit for use tax
paid to another State. We expressed no opinion on the appropriate
remedy, instead remanding to the Supreme Court of Vermont
"in light of the fact that the action was dismissed on the
pleadings, and given the possible relevance of state law,
see
Bacchus Imports, Ltd. v. Dias, 468 U. S.
263,
468 U. S. 277 (1984). . .
."
Id. at
472 U. S. 28.
Cf. Hooper v. Bernalillo County Assessor, 472 U.
S. 612,
472 U. S.
622-623 (1985). We conclude
Page 483 U. S. 253
that it is likewise appropriate for the Supreme Court of
Washington to address in the first instance the refund issues
raised by our rulings in these cases.
VI
We hold Washington's multiple activities exemption invalid
because it places a tax burden upon manufacturers in Washington
engaged in interstate commerce from which local manufacturers
selling locally are exempt. We reject appellant Tyler's nexus and
fair apportionment challenges to the State's wholesale tax. Our
partial invalidation of the State's taxing scheme raises remedial
issues that are better addressed by the State Supreme Court on
remand. Accordingly, we vacate the judgments of the Supreme Court
of Washington and remand for further proceedings not inconsistent
with this opinion.
It is so ordered.
JUSTICE POWELL took no part in the consideration or decision of
these cases.
* Together with No. 85-2006,
National Can Corp. et al. v.
Washington State Department of Revenue, also on appeal from
the same court.
[
Footnote 1]
Wash.Rev.Code § 82.04.230 (1985).
[
Footnote 2]
§ 82.04.240.
[
Footnote 3]
§ 82.04.270.
[
Footnote 4]
§ 82.04.250.
[
Footnote 5]
The statute provided:
"'Every person engaging in activities which are within the
purview of the provisions of two or more paragraphs (a), (b), (c),
(d), (e), (f) and (g) of section 4 [§ 8370-4], shall be taxable
under each paragraph applicable to the activities engaged in:
Provided, however, That persons taxable under paragraphs (a) or
(b) of said section shall not be taxable under paragraphs (c) or
(e) of said section with respect to making sales at retail or
wholesale of products extracted or manufactured within this state
by such persons. (Italics ours).'"
See Columbia Steel Co. v. State, 30 Wash. 2d 658, 661,
192 P.2d 976, 977-978 (1948).
[
Footnote 6]
"'The immunities implicit in the Commerce Clause and the
potential taxing power of a State can hardly be made to depend, in
the world of practical affairs, on the shifting incidence of the
varying tax laws of the various States at a particular moment.
Courts are not possessed of instruments of determination so
delicate as to enable them to weigh the various factors in a
complicated economic setting which, as to an isolated application
of a State tax, might mitigate the obvious burden generally created
by a direct tax on commerce.'"
Id. at 663, 192 P.2d at 978 (quoting
Freeman v.
Hewit, 329 U. S. 249,
329 U. S. 256
(1946)).
[
Footnote 7]
The Washington Supreme Court upheld this revised scheme against
constitutional challenge in
B. F. Goodrich Co. v.
State, 38 Wash. 2d
663,
231 P.2d
325,
cert. denied, 342 U.S. 876 (1951).
[
Footnote 8]
The multiple activities exemption provides:
"(1) [E]very person engaged in activities which are within the
purview of the provisions of two or more of sections RCW 82.04.230
to 82.04.290, inclusive, shall be taxable under each paragraph
applicable to the activities engaged in."
"(2) Persons taxable under RCW 82.04.250 [tax on retailers] or
82.04.270 [tax on wholesalers and distributors] shall not be
taxable under RCW 82.04.230 [tax on extractors], 82.04.240 [tax on
manufacturers] or subsection (2), (3), (4), (5), or (7) of RCW
82.04.260 [tax on certain food processing activities] with respect
to extracting or manufacturing of the products so sold."
"(3) Persons taxable under RCW 82.04.240 or RCW 82.04.260
subsection (4) shall not be taxable under RCW 82.04.230 with
respect to extracting the ingredients of the products so
manufactured."
Wash.Rev.Code § 82.04.440 (1985).
[
Footnote 9]
See, e.g., B. F. Goodrich Co. v. State, supra; General
Motors Corp. v. Washington, 377 U. S. 436
(1964);
Standard Pressed Steel Co. v. Washington Dept. of
Revenue, 419 U. S. 560
(1975);
Chicago Bridge & Iron Co. v. Washington Dept. of
Revenue, 98 Wash. 2d
814,
659 P.2d
463,
appeal dism'd, 464 U.S. 1013 (1983).
[
Footnote 10]
Justice Goldberg explained the functional equivalency for
Commerce Clause purposes of the invalidated pre-1950 statute and
its successor:
"The burden on interstate commerce and the dangers of multiple
taxation are made apparent by considering Washington's tax
provisions. The Washington provision here involved -- the 'tax on
wholesalers' -- provides that every person 'engaging within this
state in the business of making sales at wholesale' shall pay a tax
on such business 'equal to the gross proceeds of sales of such
business multiplied by the rate of one-quarter of one per cent.'
Rev.Code Wash. 82.04.270; Wash. Laws 1949, c. 228, § 1 (e). In the
same chapter, Washington imposes a 'tax on manufacturers' which
similarly provides that every person 'engaging within this state in
business as a manufacturer' shall pay a tax on such business 'equal
to the value of the products . . . manufactured, multiplied by the
rate of one-quarter of one per cent.' Rev.Code Wash. 82.04.240;
Wash.Laws 1949, c. 228, § 1 (b). Then, in a provision entitled
'Persons taxable on multiple activities,' the statute endeavors to
insure that local Washington products will not be subjected both to
the 'tax on manufacturers' and to the 'tax on wholesalers.'
Rev.Code Wash. 82.04.440; Wash.Laws 1949, c. 228, § 2-A. Prior to
its amendment in 1950, the exemptive terms of this 'multiple
activities' provision were designed so that a Washington
manufacturer-wholesaler would pay the manufacturing tax and be
exempt from the wholesale tax. This provision, on its face,
discriminated against interstate wholesale sales to Washington
purchasers, for it exempted the intrastate sales of locally made
products while taxing the competing sales of interstate sellers. In
1950, however, the 'multiple activities' provision was amended,
reversing the tax and the exemption, so that a Washington
manufacturer-wholesaler would first be subjected to the wholesale
tax and then, to the extent that he is taxed thereunder, exempted
from the manufacturing tax. Rev.Code Wash. 82.04.440; Wash.Laws
1950 (special session), c. 5, § 2.
See McDonnell &
McDonnell v. State, 62 Wash. 2d
553, 557,
383 P.2d
905, 908. This amended provision would seem to have essentially
the same economic effect on interstate sales, but has the advantage
of appearing nondiscriminatory."
General Motors Corp. v. Washington, 377 U.S. at
377 U. S.
459-460 (dissenting opinion).
[
Footnote 11]
In
Armco, Inc. v. Hardesty, 467 U.
S. 638 (1984), we quoted with approval the following
sentence from the Court's opinion in
Freeman v. Hewit,
329 U. S. 249,
324 U. S. 256
(1946):
"The immunities implicit in the Commerce Clause and the
potential taxing power of a State can hardly be made to depend, in
the world of practical affairs, on the shifting incidence of the
varying tax laws of the various States at a particular moment."
See 467 U.S. at
467 U. S. 645,
n. 8. The Washington Supreme Court also relied on
Freeman v.
Hewit in
Columbia Steel Co. v. State, 30 Wash. 2d at
663, 192 P.2d at 978.
[
Footnote 12]
Nor may the tax be justified as an attempt to compensate the
State for its inability to impose a similar burden on out-of-state
manufacturers whose goods are sold in Washington, for Washington
subjects those sales to wholesale tax.
[
Footnote 13]
Many States provide tax credits that alleviate or eliminate the
potential multiple taxation that results when two or more
sovereigns have jurisdiction to tax parts of the same chain of
commercial events. For example, the District of Columbia and all
but three States with sales and use taxes provide a credit against
their own use taxes for sales taxes paid to another State, although
reciprocity may be required.
See CCH State Tax Guide
6013-6014 (1986);
Williams v. Vermont, 472 U. S.
14,
472 U. S. 22
(1985).
See also Halliburton Oil Well Cementing Co. v.
Reilly 373 U. S. 64,
373 U. S. 74-75
(1963).
[
Footnote 14]
In his opinion for the Court in
Henneford v. Silas Mason
Co., Justice Cardozo carefully described the relationship
between the 2% "tax on retail sales" imposed by Title III of
Washington's 1935 tax code and the "compensating tax" imposed by
Title IV on the privilege of use. The compensating use tax was
imposed on the use of an article of tangible personal property
which had been purchased at retail but had not been subjected to a
sales tax that was equal to or in excess of that imposed by the
State of Washington. If the rate of the tax imposed by another
jurisdiction was less than 2%, the rate of the compensating tax was
measured by the difference. Explaining why such a compensating tax
does not discriminate against interstate commerce, Justice Cardozo
wrote:
"Equality is the theme that runs through all the sections of the
statute. There shall be a tax upon the use, but subject to an
offset if another use or sales tax has been paid for the same
thing. This is true where the offsetting tax became payable to
Washington by reason of purchase or use within the state.
It is
true in exactly the same measure where the offsetting tax has been
paid to another state by reason of use or purchase there. No
one who uses property in Washington after buying it at retail is to
be exempt from a tax upon the privilege of enjoyment except to the
extent that he has paid a use or sales tax somewhere. Everyone who
has paid a use or sales tax anywhere, or, more accurately, in any
state, is to that extent to be exempt from the payment of another
tax in Washington."
"When the account is made up, the stranger from afar is subject
to no greater burdens as a consequence of ownership than the
dweller within the gates. The one pays upon one activity or
incident, and the other upon another, but the sum is the same when
the reckoning is closed."
300 U.S. at
300 U. S.
583-584 (emphasis added).
[
Footnote 15]
Even the solitary dissenting opinion in the
Armco case
did not question the proposition that the constitutionality of the
West Virginia tax could properly be discerned merely by referring
to the text of the tax statute itself:
"It is plain that West Virginia's tax would be
unconstitutionally discriminatory if it levied no tax on
manufacturing or taxed manufacturing at a lower rate than
wholesaling, for then the out-of-state wholesaler would be paying a
higher tax than the in-state manufacturer-wholesaler."
467 U.S. at
467 U. S. 646
(REHNQUIST, J., dissenting).
Instead, the dissent argued that West Virginia's taxing scheme,
taken in its entirety, did not discriminate against out-of-state
manufacturers, because the manufacturing tax paid by a local
manufacturer-wholesaler was much higher than the wholesale tax
exacted from an out-of-state manufacturer.
[
Footnote 16]
In view of our holding on the discrimination issue, we need not
reach the claim of local state manufacturers selling to interstate
markets that the tax scheme does not fairly apportion tax
liabilities between Washington and other States.
JUSTICE O'CONNOR, concurring.
I join the Court's opinion holding that, "[i]n light of the
facially discriminatory nature of the multiple activities
exemption,"
ante at
483 U. S. 244,
see Maryland v. Louisiana, 451 U.
S. 725,
451 U. S.
756-757 (1981), the Washington taxpayers need not prove
actual discriminatory impact "by an examination of the tax burdens
imposed by other States."
Ante at
483 U. S. 247.
I do not read the Court's decision as extending the "internal
consistency" test described in
Armco Inc. v. Hardesty,
467 U. S. 638,
467 U. S.
644-645 (1984), to taxes that are not facially
discriminatory,
contra, post at
483 U. S.
257-258 (SCALIA, J., concurring in part and dissenting
in part), nor would I agree with such a result in these cases.
See American Trucking Assns., Inc. v. Scheiner, post p.
483 U. S. 298
(O'CONNOR, J., dissenting).
Page 483 U. S. 254
JUSTICE SCALIA, with whom THE CHIEF JUSTICE joins in Part I,
concurring in part and dissenting in part.
I join Part IV of the Court's opinion, upholding Washington's
unapportioned wholesale tax and rejecting Tyler Pipe's claim that
it did not have a sufficient nexus with Washington to give the
State taxing jurisdiction. I dissent, however, from the remainder
of the opinion, invalidating the State's manufacturing tax as
unconstitutionally discriminatory under the Commerce Clause. The
standard for discrimination adopted by the Court, which drastically
limits the States' discretion to structure their tax systems, has
no basis in the Constitution, and is not required by our past
decisions.
I
Implicitly in these cases,
ante at
483 U. S.
245-248, and explicitly in
American Trucking Assns.,
Inc. v. Scheiner, post at
483 U. S. 284,
the Court imposes on state taxes a requirement of "internal
consistency," demanding that they "
be such that, if applied by
every jurisdiction,' there would be no impermissible interference
with free trade." Armco Inc. v. Hardesty, 467 U.
S. 638, 467 U. S. 644
(1984) (quoting Container Corp. of America v. Franchise Tax
Board, 463 U. S. 159,
463 U. S. 169
(1983)). [Footnote 2/1] It is
clear, for the reasons given by the Court, ante at
483 U. S.
246-247, that the Washington business and occupation (B
& O) tax fails that test. So would any unapportioned flat tax
on multistate activities, such as the axle tax or marker fee at
issue in Scheiner, post p. 483 U. S. 266. It
is equally clear to me, however, that this internal consistency
principle is nowhere to be found in the Constitution. Nor is it
plainly required by our prior decisions. Indeed, in order to apply
the internal consistency
Page 483 U. S. 255
rule in this case, the Court is compelled to overrule a rather
lengthy list of prior decisions, from
Hinson v.
Lott, 8 Wall. 148 (1869), to
General Motors
Corp. v. Washington, 377 U. S. 436
(1964), and including, as is made explicit in
Scheiner,
post p.
483 U. S. 266,
Capitol Greyhound Lines v. Brice, 339 U.
S. 542 (1950),
Aero Mayflower Transit Co. v. Board
of Railroad Comm'rs, 332 U. S. 495
(1947), and
Aero Mayflower Transit Co. v. Georgia Public
Service Comm'n, 295 U. S. 285
(1935). Moreover, the Court must implicitly repudiate the approval
given in dicta 10 years ago to New York's pre-1968 transfer tax on
securities.
See Boston Stock Exchange v. State Tax Comm'n,
429 U. S. 318,
429 U. S. 330
(1977). [
Footnote 2/2] Finally, we
noted only two Terms ago -- and one Term after
Armco,
supra, was decided -- that we had never held that "a State
must credit a sales tax paid to another State against its own use
tax."
Williams v. Vermont, 472 U. S.
14,
472 U. S. 21-22
(1985).
See Southern Pacific Co. v. Gallagher,
306 U. S. 167,
306 U. S. 172
(1939). If we had applied an internal consistency rule at that
time, the need for such a credit would have followed as a matter of
mathematical necessity. The Court's presumed basis for creating
this rule now, 198 years after adoption of the Constitution, is
that the reasoning of
Armco requires it.
See Scheiner,
post at
483 U. S. 284.
In my view, however, that reasoning was dictum, which we should
explicitly reject. And if one insists on viewing it as holding, and
thus
Page 483 U. S. 256
as conflicting with decades of precedents upholding internally
inconsistent state taxes, it seems to me that
Armco,
rather than those numerous other precedents, ought to be
overruled.
Prior to
Armco, the internal consistency test was
applied only in cases involving apportionment of the net income of
businesses that more than one State sought to tax. That was the
issue in
Container Corp., see 463 U.S. at
463 U. S.
169-171, the only case cited by
Armco in
support of an internal consistency rule,
see 467 U.S. at
467 U. S.
644-645, and there is no reason automatically to require
internal consistency in other contexts. A business can, of course,
earn net income in more than one State, but the total amount of
income is a unitary figure. Hence, when more than one State has
taxing jurisdiction over a multistate enterprise, an inconsistent
apportionment scheme could result in taxation of more than 100% of
that firm's net income. Where, however, tax is assessed not on
unitary income but on discrete events such as sale, manufacture,
and delivery, which can occur in a single State or in different
States, that apportionment principle is not applicable; there is
simply no unitary figure or event to apportion. That we have not
traditionally applied the internal consistency test outside the
apportionment context is amply demonstrated by the lengthy list of
cases that the Court has (openly or tacitly) had to overrule here
and in
Scheiner.
It is possible to read
Armco as requiring such a test
in all contexts, but it is assuredly not necessary to do so.
Armco dealt with West Virginia's 0.27% selling tax and
0.88% manufacturing tax, and its exemption from the selling tax for
in-state, but not out-of-state, manufacturers. We discussed the
internal consistency of that taxing scheme only after finding the
selling tax discriminatory "[o]n its face," 467 U.S. at
467 U. S. 642,
because
"[t]he tax provides that two companies selling tangible property
at wholesale in West Virginia will be treated differently depending
on whether the taxpayer conducts manufacturing in the State or out
of it."
Ibid. Combined with the finding that the selling tax
imposed on
Page 483 U. S. 257
out-of-state producers could not be deemed to "compensate" for
the higher manufacturing tax imposed only on West Virginia
producer/sellers,
id. at
467 U. S.
642-643, that was enough to invalidate the tax. We went
on to address the internal consistency rule in response to the
State's argument that the taxpayer had not shown
"actual discriminatory impact on it by pointing to a State that
imposes a manufacturing tax that results in a total burden higher
than that imposed on
Armco's competitors in West
Virginia."
Id. at
467 U. S. 644.
After reciting the internal consistency principle applicable in
apportionment cases, we said that "[a] similar rule applies where
the allegation is that a tax on its face discriminates against
interstate commerce,"
ibid., regardless of "the shifting
complexities of the tax codes of 49 other States. . . ."
Id. at
467 U. S. 645.
The holding of
Armco thus establishes only that a facially
discriminatory taxing scheme that is not internally consistent will
not be saved by the claim that, in fact, no adverse impact on
interstate commerce has occurred. To expand that brief discussion
into a holding that internal consistency is always required, and
thereby to revolutionize the law of state taxation, is
remarkable.
Rather than use isolated language, written with no evident
consideration of its potential significance if adopted as a general
rule, to overturn a lengthy list of settled decisions, one would
think that we would instead use the settled decisions to limit the
scope of the isolated language. As the cases from the past few
Terms indicate, the internal consistency test invalidates a host of
taxing methods long relied upon by the States and left unhampered
by Congress. We are already on shaky ground when we invoke the
Commerce Clause as a self-operative check on state legislation,
See Part II,
infra, requiring us to develop rules unconstrained
by the text of the Constitution. Prudence counsels in favor of the
least intrusive rule possible.
Applying more traditional tests, the Washington B & O tax is
valid. It is not facially discriminatory. Unlike the
Page 483 U. S. 258
West Virginia tax in
Armco, Washington's selling tax is
imposed on all goods, whether produced in-state or out-of-state. No
manufacturing tax is (or could be) imposed on out-of-state
manufacturers, so no discrimination is present (or possible) there.
All the State does is to relieve local producer/sellers from the
burden of double taxation by declining to assess a manufacturing
tax on local businesses with respect to goods on which a selling
tax is paid. Nor does this arrangement, notwithstanding its
nondiscriminatory appearance, have discriminatory effects in and of
itself. An in-state manufacturer selling in-state pays one tax to
Washington; an in-state manufacturer selling out-of-state pays one
tax to Washington; and an out-of-state manufacturer selling
in-state pays one tax to Washington. The State collects the same
tax whether interstate or intrastate commerce is involved. The tax
can be considered to have discriminatory effects only if one
consults what other States are in fact doing (a case-by-case
inquiry that appeals to no one,
ante at
483 U. S. 247)
or unless one adopts an assumption as to what other States are
doing. It is the latter course that the internal consistency rule
adopts, assuming, for purposes of our Commerce Clause
determination, that other States have the same tax as the tax under
scrutiny. As noted earlier, I see no basis for that assumption in
the tradition of our cases; and I see little basis for it in logic
as well. Specifically, I see no reason why the fact that other
States, by adopting a
similar tax, might cause
Washington's tax to have a discriminatory effect on interstate
commerce, is of any more significance than the fact that other
States, by adopting a
dissimilar tax, might produce such a
result. The latter, of course, does not suffice to invalidate a
tax. To take the simplest example: a tax on manufacturing (without
a tax on wholesaling) will have a discriminatory effect upon
interstate commerce if another State adopts a tax on wholesaling
(without a tax on manufacturing) -- for then a company
manufacturing and selling in the former State would pay only a
single tax, while a company
Page 483 U. S. 259
manufacturing in the former State but selling in the latter
State would pay two taxes. When this very objection was raised in
Armco, we replied that, unlike the situation in
Armco itself, "such a result would not arise from
impermissible discrimination against interstate commerce. . . ."
467 U.S. at
467 U. S. 645.
That response was possible there because the West Virginia tax was
facially discriminatory; it is not possible here, because the
Washington B & O tax is not.
It seems to me that we should adhere to our long tradition of
judging state taxes on their own terms, and that there is even less
justification for striking them down on the basis of assumptions as
to what other States
might do than there is for striking
them down on the basis of what other States
in fact do.
Washington's B & O tax is plainly lawful on its own. It may
well be that other States will impose similar taxes that will
increase the burden on businesses operating interstate -- just as
it may well be that they will impose dissimilar taxes that have the
same effect. That is why the Framers gave Congress the power to
regulate interstate commerce. Evaluating each State's taxing scheme
on its own gives this Court the power to eliminate evident
discrimination, while at the same time leaving the States an
appropriate degree of freedom to structure their revenue measures.
Finer tuning than this is for the Congress.
II
I think it particularly inappropriate to leap to a restrictive
"internal consistency" rule, since the platform from which we
launch that leap is such an unstable structure. It takes no more
than our opinions this Term, and the number of prior decisions they
explicitly or implicitly overrule, to demonstrate that the
practical results we have deduced from the so-called "negative"
Commerce Clause form not a rock but a "quagmire,"
Northwestern
States Portland Cement Co. v. Minnesota, 358 U.
S. 450,
358 U. S. 458
(1959). Nor is this a recent liquefaction. The fact is that, in the
114 years since
Page 483 U. S. 260
the doctrine of the negative Commerce Clause was formally
adopted as holding of this Court,
See
Case of the State
Freight Tax, 15 Wall. 232 (1873), and in the 50
years prior to that in which it was alluded to in various dicta of
the Court,
See Cooley v. Board of
Wardens, 12 How. 299,
53 U. S. 319
(1852);
Gibbons v.
Ogden, 9 Wheat. 1,
22
U. S. 209 (1824);
id. at
22 U. S. 226-229,
22 U. S. 235-239
(Johnson, J., concurring in judgment), our applications of the
doctrine have, not to put too fine a point on the matter, made no
sense.
See generally D. Currie, The Constitution in the
Supreme Court: The First Hundred Years 1789-1888, pp. 168-181,
222-236, 330-342, 403-416 (1985). [
Footnote 2/3]
That uncertainty in application has been attributable in no
small part to the lack of any clear theoretical underpinning for
judicial "enforcement" of the Commerce Clause. The text of the
Clause states that
"Congress shall have Power . . . To regulate Commerce with
foreign Nations, and among the several States, and with the Indian
Tribes."
Art. I, § 8, cl. 3. On its face, this is a charter for Congress,
not the courts, to ensure "an area of trade free from interference
by the States."
Boston Stock Exchange, 429 U.S. at
429 U. S. 328.
The preemption of state legislation would automatically follow,
Page 483 U. S. 261
of course, if the grant of power to Congress to regulate
interstate commerce were exclusive, as Charles Pinckney's draft
constitution would have provided,
see Abel, The Commerce
Clause in the Constitutional Convention and in Contemporary
Comment, 25 Minn.L.Rev. 432, 434 (1941), and as John Marshall at
one point seemed to believe it was.
See Gibbons v. Ogden,
supra, at
22 U. S. 209.
However, unlike the District Clause, which empowers Congress "To
exercise exclusive Legislation," Art. I, § 8, cl. 17, the language
of the Commerce Clause gives no indication of exclusivity.
See License Cases,
5 How. 504,
46 U. S. 579
(1847) (opinion of Taney, C.J.). Nor can one assume generally that
Congress' Article I powers are exclusive; many of them plainly
coexist with concurrent authority in the States.
See Kewanee
Oil Co. v. Bicron Corp., 416 U. S. 470,
416 U. S. 479
(1974) (patent power);
Goldstein v. California,
412 U. S. 546,
412 U. S. 560
(1973) (copyright power);
Houston v.
Moore, 5 Wheat. 1,
18 U. S. 25 (1820)
(court-martial jurisdiction over the militia);
Sturges v.
Crowninshield, 4 Wheat. 122,
17 U. S.
193-196 (1819) (bankruptcy power). Furthermore, there is
no correlative denial of power over commerce to the States in Art.
I, § 10, as there is, for example, with the power to coin money or
make treaties. And both the States and Congress assumed from the
date of ratification that at least some state laws regulating
commerce were valid.
See License Cases, supra, at
46 U. S.
580-581. The exclusivity rationale is infinitely less
attractive today than it was in 1847. Now that we know interstate
commerce embraces such activities as growing wheat for home
consumption,
Wickard v. Filburn, 317 U.
S. 111 (1942), and local loan sharking,
Perez v.
United States, 402 U. S. 146
(1971), it is more difficult to imagine what state activity would
survive an exclusive Commerce Clause than to imagine what would be
precluded.
Another approach to theoretical justification for judicial
enforcement of the Commerce Clause is to assert, as did Justice
Curtis in dicta in
Cooley v. Board of Wardens, supra, at
53 U. S. 319,
that
"[w]hatever subjects of this power are in their
Page 483 U. S. 262
nature national, or admit only of one uniform system, or plan of
regulation, may justly be said to be of such a nature as to require
exclusive legislation by Congress."
That would perhaps be a wise rule to adopt (though it is hard to
see why judges, rather than legislators, are fit to determine what
areas of commerce "in their nature" require national regulation),
but it has the misfortune of finding no conceivable basis in the
text of the Commerce Clause, which treats "Commerce . . . among the
several States" as a unitary subject. And attempting to limit the
Clause's preemptive effect to state laws intended to regulate
commerce (as opposed to those intended, for example, to promote
health),
see Gibbons v. Ogden, supra, at
22 U. S. 203,
while perhaps a textually possible construction of the phrase
"regulate Commerce," is a most unlikely one. Distinguishing between
laws with the purpose of regulating commerce and "police power"
statutes with that effect is, as Taney demonstrated in the
License Cases, supra, at
46 U. S.
582-583, more interesting as a metaphysical exercise
than useful as a practical technique for marking out the powers of
separate sovereigns.
The least plausible theoretical justification of all is the idea
that, in enforcing the negative Commerce Clause, the Court is not
applying a constitutional command at all, but is merely
interpreting the will of Congress, whose silence in certain fields
of interstate commerce (but not in others) is to be taken as a
prohibition of regulation. There is no conceivable reason why
congressional inaction under the Commerce Clause should be deemed
to have the same preemptive effect elsewhere accorded only to
congressional action. There, as elsewhere, "Congress' silence is
just that -- silence. . . ."
Alaska Airlines, Inc. v.
Brock, 480 U. S. 678,
480 U. S. 686
(1987).
See Currie,
supra, n. 3, at 334 (noting
"the recurring fallacy that, in some undefined cases, congressional
inaction was to be treated as if it were permissive or prohibitory
legislation -- though
Page 483 U. S. 263
the Constitution makes clear that Congress can act only by
affirmative vote of both Houses" (footnotes omitted)). [
Footnote 2/4]
The historical record provides no grounds for reading the
Commerce Clause to be other than what it says -- an authorization
for Congress to regulate commerce. The strongest evidence in favor
of a negative Commerce Clause -- that version of it which renders
federal authority over interstate commerce exclusive -- is
Madison's comment during the Convention:
"Whether the States are now restrained from laying tonnage
duties depends on the extent of the power 'to regulate commerce.'
These terms are vague, but seem to exclude this power of the
States."
2 M. Farrand, Records of the Federal Convention of 1787, p. 625
(1937). This comment, however, came during discussion of what
became Art. I, § 10, cl. 3: "No State shall, without the Consent of
Congress, lay any Duty of Tonnage. . . ." The fact that it is
difficult to conceive how the power to regulate commerce would not
include the power to impose duties; and the fact that, despite this
apparent coverage, the Convention went on to adopt a provision
prohibiting States from levying duties on tonnage without
congressional approval; suggest that Madison's assumption
Page 483 U. S. 264
of exclusivity of the federal commerce power was ill-considered,
and not generally shared.
Against this mere shadow of historical support, there is the
overwhelming reality that the Commerce Clause, in its broad
outlines, was not a major subject of controversy, neither during
the constitutional debates nor in the ratifying conventions.
Instead, there was "nearly universal agreement that the federal
government should be given the power of regulating commerce," Abel,
25 Minn.L.Rev. at 443-444, in much the form provided. "The records
disclose no constructive criticisms by the states of the commerce
clause as proposed to them." F. Frankfurter, The Commerce Clause
under Marshall, Taney and Waite 12 (1937). In The Federalist,
Madison and Hamilton wrote numerous discourses on the virtues of
free trade and the need for uniformity and national control of
commercial regulation,
see The Federalist No. 7, pp. 62-63
(C. Rossiter ed.1961);
id. No. 11, pp. 8990;
id.
No. 22, pp. 143-145;
id. No. 42, pp. 267-269;
id.
No. 53, p. 333, but said little of substance specifically about the
Commerce Clause -- and that little was addressed primarily to
foreign and Indian trade.
See generally Abel,
supra, at 470-474. Madison does not seem to have
exaggerated when he described the Commerce Clause as an addition to
the powers of the National Government "which few oppose and from
which no apprehensions are entertained." The Federalist No. 45, p.
293. I think it beyond question that many "apprehensions" would
have been "entertained" if supporters of the Constitution had
hinted that the Commerce Clause, despite its language, gave this
Court the power it has since assumed. As Justice Frankfurter
pungently put it:
"the doctrine that state authority must be subject to such
limitations as the Court finds it necessary to apply for the
protection of the national community . . . [is] an audacious
doctrine, which, one may be sure, would hardly have been publicly
avowed in support of the adoption of the Constitution."
Frankfurter,
supra, at 19.
Page 483 U. S. 265
In sum, to the extent that we have gone beyond guarding against
rank discrimination against citizens of other States -- which is
regulated not by the Commerce Clause but by the Privileges and
Immunities Clause, U.S.Const., Art. IV, § 2, cl. 1 ("The Citizens
of each State shall be entitled to all Privileges and Immunities of
Citizens in the several States") -- the Court for over a century
has engaged in an enterprise that it has been unable to justify by
textual support or even coherent nontextual theory, that it was
almost certainly not intended to undertake, and that it has not
undertaken very well. It is astonishing that we should be expanding
our beachhead in this impoverished territory, rather than being
satisfied with what we have already acquired by a sort of
intellectual adverse possession.
[
Footnote 2/1]
The majority finds Washington's manufacturing tax exemption for
local wholesalers discriminatory because it
"excludes similarly situated manufacturers and wholesalers which
conduct one of those activities within Washington and the other
activity outside the State."
Ante at
483 U. S.
246-247. That exclusion, however, can only be deemed
facially discriminatory if one assumes that every State's
taxing scheme is identical to Washington's.
[
Footnote 2/2]
The New York statute taxed,
inter alia, both the sale
and delivery of securities if either event occurred in New York,
429 U.S. at
429 U. S. 321,
but imposed only one tax if both events occurred in that State.
While the Court invalidated as discriminatory an amendment to that
law reducing the tax for in-state sales by nonresidents and placing
a cap on the tax payable on transactions involving in-state sales,
it also declared that the statute prior to the amendment "was
neutral as to in-state and out-of-state sales."
Id. at
429 U. S. 330.
That is plainly not true if internal consistency is a requirement
of neutrality: assuming that all States had New York's pre-1968
scheme, if sale and delivery both took place in New York, there
would be a single tax, while if sale took place in New York and
delivery in New Jersey, there would be double taxation.
[
Footnote 2/3]
Professor Currie's discussion of the Commerce Clause decisions
of the Marshall and Taney Courts is summed up by his assessment of
the leading Taney Court decision:
"Taken by itself,
Cooley \[v. Board of
Wardens, 12 How. 299 (1852),] may appear arbitrary,
conclusory, and irreconcilable with the constitutional text.
Nevertheless, anyone who has slogged through the Augean
agglomeration preceding Curtis's labors must find them scarcely
less impressive than those of the old stable-cleaner himself."
D. Currie, The Constitution in the Supreme Court: The First
Hundred Years 1789-1888, p. 234 (1985). He concludes his discussion
of the Chase Court's Commerce Clause jurisprudence by noting: "In
doctrinal terms, the Court's efforts in this field can be described
only as a disaster."
Id. at 342 (footnote omitted). And
the Waite Court receives the following testimonial:
"It is a relief that, with the
Bowman decision
[
Bowman v. Chicago Northwestern R. Co., 125 U. S.
465 (1888),] we have reached the end of the commerce
clause decisions of the Waite period, for they do not make
elevating reading."
Id. at 416 (footnote omitted). Future commentators are
not likely to treat recent eras much more tenderly.
[
Footnote 2/4]
Unfortunately, this "legislation by inaction" theory of the
negative Commerce Clause seems to be the only basis for the
doctrine, relied upon by the Court in
Scheiner, post at
483 U. S. 289,
n. 23, that Congress can authorize States to enact legislation that
would otherwise violate the negative Commerce Clause.
See
Prudential Ins. Co. v. Benjamin, 328 U.
S. 408 (1946). Nothing else could explain the
Benjamin principle that what was invalid state action can
be rendered valid state action through "congressional consent."
There is surely no area in which Congress can permit the States to
violate the Constitution. Thus, in
Cooley v.
Board of Wardens, 12 How. 299 (1852), Justice
Curtis, to whom there had not occurred the theory of congressional
legislation by inaction, wrote of the relationship between States
and the negative Commerce Clause as follows:
"If the States were divested of the power to legislate on this
subject by the grant of the commercial power to Congress, it is
plain this Act could not confer upon them power thus to legislate.
If the Constitution excluded the States from making any law
regulating commerce, certainly Congress cannot regrant, or in any
manner reconvey to the States that power."
Id. at
53 U. S.
318.