Lawful economic strikes were called at two of respondent Allis
Chalmers' plants in accordance with duly authorized union
procedures by the locals of the union representing the employees.
Some union members crossed picket lines and worked during the
strikes. After the strikes were over, the locals brought
proceedings against these members, imposed fines of $20 to $100,
and sued in state courts to collect the fines. The collective
bargaining agreement contained a union security clause which
required each employee to become and remain "a member of the union
to the extent of paying his monthly dues." Allis-Chalmers filed
unfair labor practice charges against the locals alleging violation
of § 8(b)(1)(A) of the National Labor Relations Act. The NLRB held
that, even if the union action were restraint or coercion
proscribed by that section, the conduct came within the proviso
that the section "shall not impair the right of a labor
organization to prescribe its own rules with respect to the
acquisition or retention of membership therein." The Court of
Appeals reversed, holding that the union conduct violated § 8(b)
(1)(A).
Held:
1. The history of legislative action surrounding § 8(b)(1)(A)'s
prohibition of union activity to "restrain or coerce" employees in
the exercise of rights guaranteed by § 7 justifies the conclusion,
in light of the imprecision of the words "restrain or coerce," and
the repeated refrain throughout the debates that Congress did not
propose limitations on the internal affairs of unions, that
Congress did not intend § 8(b)(1)(A) to prohibit the imposition of
reasonable fines on full union members who decline to honor an
authorized strike or to prohibit attempts to collect such fines.
Pp.
388 U. S.
178-195.
2. Since Allis-Chalmers offered no evidence that the fined
employees enjoyed other than full union membership, the contrary
will not be presumed. The question of the applicability of the
statute to employees whose membership was limited to the obligation
to pay monthly dues is not presented here. Pp.
388 U. S.
196-197.
358 F.2d 656, reversed.
Page 388 U. S. 176
MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN delivered the opinion of the Court.
The question here is whether a union which threatened and
imposed fines, and brought suit for their collection, against
members who crossed the union's picket line and went to work during
an authorized strike against their employer committed the unfair
labor practice under § 8(b)(1)(A) of the National Labor Relations
Act of engaging in conduct "to restrain or coerce" employees in the
exercise of their right guaranteed by § 7 to "refrain from"
concerted activities. [
Footnote
1]
Page 388 U. S. 177
Employees at the West Allis, and La Crosse, Wisconsin, plants of
respondent Allis-Chalmers Manufacturing Company were represented by
locals of the United Automobile Workers. Lawful economic strikes
were conducted at both plants in support of new contract demands.
In compliance with the UAW constitution, the strikes were called
with the approval of the International Union after at least
two-thirds of the members of each local voted by secret ballot to
strike. Some members of each local crossed the picket lines and
worked during the strikes. After the strikes were over, the locals
brought proceedings against these members charging them with
violation of the International constitution and bylaws. The charges
were heard by local trial committees in proceedings at which the
charged members were represented by counsel. No claim of unfairness
in the proceedings is made. The trials resulted in each charged
member being found guilty of "conduct unbecoming a Union member"
and being fined in a sum from $20 to $100. Some of the fined
members did not pay the fines, and one of the locals obtained a
judgment in the amount of the fine against one of its members,
Benjamin Natzke, in a test suit brought in the Milwaukee County
Court. An appeal from the judgment is pending in the Wisconsin
Supreme Court.
Allis-Chalmers filed unfair labor practice charges against the
locals alleging violation of § 8(b)(1)(A). [
Footnote 2]
Page 388 U. S. 178
A complaint issued and, after hearing, a trial examiner
recommended its dismissal. The National Labor Relations Board
sustained the examiner on the ground that, in the circumstances of
this case, the actions of the locals, even if restraint or coercion
prohibited by § 8(b)(1)(A), constituted conduct excepted from the
section's prohibitions by the proviso that such prohibitions "shall
not impair the right of a labor organization to prescribe its own
rules with respect to the acquisition or retention of membership
therein." 149 N.L.R.B. 67. Upon Allis-Chalmers' petition for review
to the Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit, a panel of that
court upheld the Board's decision. Following a rehearing en banc,
however, the court, three judges dissenting, withdrew the panel
opinion, held that the locals' conduct violated § 8(b)(1)(A), and
remanded to the Board for appropriate proceedings. 358 F.2d 656. We
granted certiorari, 385 U.S. 810. We reverse.
I
The panel and the majority en banc of the Court of Appeals
thought that reversal of the NLRB order would be required under a
literal reading of §§ 7 and 8(b)(1)(A); under that reading, union
members who cross their own picket lines would be regarded as
exercising their rights under § 7 to refrain from engaging in a
particular concerted activity, and union discipline in the form of
fines for such activity would therefore "restrain or coerce" in
violation of § 8(b)(1)(A) if the section's proviso is read to
sanction no form of discipline other
Page 388 U. S. 179
than expulsion from the union. The panel rejected that literal
reading. The majority en banc adopted it, stating that the panel
"mistakenly took the position that such a literal reading was
unwarranted in the light of the history and purposes" of the
sections, 358 F.2d at 659, and holding that
"[t]he statutes in question present no ambiguities whatsoever,
and therefore do not require recourse to legislative history for
clarification."
Id. at 660.
It is highly unrealistic to regard § 8(b)(1), and particularly
its words "restrain or coerce," as precisely and unambiguously
covering the union conduct involved in this case. On its face,
court enforcement of fines imposed on members for violation of
membership obligations is no more conduct to "restrain or coerce"
satisfaction of such obligations than court enforcement of
penalties imposed on citizens for violation of their obligations as
citizens to pay income taxes or court awards of damages against a
contracting party for nonperformance of a contractual obligation
voluntarily undertaken. But even if the inherent imprecision of the
words "restrain or coerce" may be overlooked, recourse to
legislative history to determine the sense in which Congress used
the words is not foreclosed. We have only this Term again
admonished that labor legislation is peculiarly the product of
legislative compromise of strongly held views,
Local 1976,
Carpenters' Union v. Labor Board, 357 U. S.
93,
357 U. S.
99-100, and that legislative history may not be
disregarded merely because it is arguable that a provision may
unambiguously embrace conduct called in question.
National
Woodwork Mfrs Assn. v. NLRB, 386 U. S. 612,
386 U. S.
619-620. Indeed, we have applied that principle to the
construction of 8(b)(1)(A) itself in holding that the section must
be construed in light of the fact that it
"is only one of many interwoven sections in a complex Act,
mindful of the manifest purpose of
Page 388 U. S. 180
the Congress to fashion a coherent national labor policy."
Labor Board v. Drivers Local Union, 362 U.
S. 274,
362 U. S.
292.
National labor policy has been built on the premise that, by
pooling their economic strength and acting through a labor
organization freely chosen by the majority, the employees of an
appropriate unit have the most effective means of bargaining for
improvements in wages, hours, and working conditions. The policy
therefore extinguishes the individual employee's power to order his
own relations with his employer, and creates a power vested in the
chosen representative to act in the interests of all employees.
"Congress has seen fit to clothe the bargaining representative
with powers comparable to those possessed by a legislative body
both to create and restrict the rights of those whom it represents.
. . ."
Steele v. Louisville & N. R. Co., 323 U.
S. 192,
323 U. S. 202.
Thus, only the union may contract the employee's terms and
conditions of employment, [
Footnote
3] and provisions for processing his grievances; the union may
even bargain away his right to strike during the contract term
[
Footnote 4] and his right to
refuse to cross a lawful picket line. [
Footnote 5] The employee may disagree with many of the
union decisions, but is bound by them. "The majority-rule concept
is today unquestionably at the center of our federal labor policy."
[
Footnote 6]
"The complete satisfaction of all who are represented is hardly
to be expected. A wide range of reasonableness must be allowed a
statutory bargaining representative in serving the unit it
represents, subject always to complete good faith and honesty of
purpose in the exercise of its discretion."
Ford Motor Co. v. Huffman, 345 U.
S. 330,
345 U. S.
338.
Page 388 U. S. 181
It was because the national labor policy vested unions with
power to order the relations of employees with their employer that
this Court found it necessary to fashion the duty of fair
representation. That duty
"has stood as a bulwark to prevent arbitrary union conduct
against individuals stripped of traditional forms of redress by the
provisions of federal labor law."
Vaca v. Sipes, 386 U. S. 171,
386 U. S. 182.
For the same reason, Congress, in the 1959 Landrum-Griffin
amendments, 73 Stat. 519, enacted a code of fairness to assure
democratic conduct of union affairs by provisions guaranteeing free
speech and assembly, equal rights to vote in elections, to attend
meetings, and to participate in the deliberations and voting upon
the business conducted at the meetings.
Integral to this federal labor policy has been the power in the
chosen union to protect against erosion its status under that
policy through reasonable discipline of members who violate rules
and regulations governing membership. [
Footnote 7] That power is particularly vital when the
members engage in strikes. The economic strike against the employer
is the ultimate weapon in labor's arsenal for achieving agreement
upon its terms, and "[t]he power to fine or expel strikebreakers is
essential if the union is to be an effective bargaining agent. . .
." [
Footnote 8] Provisions
in
Page 388 U. S. 182
union constitutions and bylaws for fines and expulsion of
recalcitrants, including strikebreakers, are therefore commonplace,
and were commonplace at the time of the Taft-Hartley amendments.
[
Footnote 9]
In addition, the judicial view current at the time § 8(b)(1)(A)
was passed was that provisions defining punishable conduct and the
procedures for trial and appeal constituted part of the contract
between member and union, and that "The courts' role is but to
enforce the contract." [
Footnote
10] In
Machinists v. Gonzales, 356 U.
S. 617,
356 U. S. 618,
we recognized that "[t]his contractual conception of the relation
between a member and his union widely prevails in this country. . .
." Although state courts were reluctant to intervene in internal
union affairs, a body of law establishing standards of fairness in
the enforcement of union discipline grew up around this
contract
Page 388 U. S. 183
doctrine.
See Parks v. Electrical Workers, 314 F.2d
886, 902-903. [
Footnote
11]
To say that Congress meant in 1947 by the § 7 amendments and §
8(b)(1)(A) to strip unions of the power to fine members for
strikebreaking, however lawful the strike vote and however fair the
disciplinary procedures and penalty, is to say that Congress
preceded the Landrum-Griffin amendments with an even more pervasive
regulation of the internal affairs of unions. It is also to
attribute to Congress an intent at war with the understanding of
the union-membership relation which has been at the heart of its
effort "to fashion a coherent labor policy" and which has been a
predicate underlying action by this Court and the state courts.
More importantly, it is to say that Congress limited unions in the
powers necessary to the discharge of their role as exclusive
statutory bargaining agents by impairing the usefulness of labor's
cherished strike weapon. It is no answer that the proviso to
8(b)(1)(A) preserves to the union the power to expel the offending
member. Where the union is strong, and membership therefore
valuable, to require expulsion of the member visits a far more
severe penalty upon the member than a reasonable fine. Where the
union is weak, and membership therefore of little value, the union,
faced with further depletion of its ranks, may have no real choice
except to condone the member's disobedience. [
Footnote 12]
Page 388 U. S. 184
Yet it is just such weak unions for which the power to execute
union decisions taken for the benefit of all employees is most
critical to effective discharge of its statutory function.
Congressional meaning is, of course, ordinarily to be discerned
in the words Congress uses. But when the literal application of the
imprecise words "restrain or coerce" Congress employed in §
8(b)(1)(A) produces the extraordinary results we have mentioned, we
should determine whether this meaning is confirmed in the
legislative history of the section.
II
The explicit wording of § 8(b)(2), which is concerned with union
powers to affect a member's employment, is in sharp contrast with
the imprecise words of § 8(b)(1)(A). Section 8(b)(2) limits union
power to compel an employer to discharge a terminated member other
than for
"failure [of the employee] to tender the periodic dues and the
initiation fees uniformly required as a condition of acquiring or
retaining membership."
It is significant that Congress expressly disclaimed in this
connection any intention to interfere with union self-government or
to regulate a union's internal affairs. The Senate Report
stated:
"The committee did not desire to limit the labor organization
with respect to either its selection of membership or expulsion
therefrom. But the committee did wish to protect the employee in
his job if unreasonably expelled or denied membership. The tests
provided by the amendment are based upon facts readily
ascertainable, and
do not require
Page 388 U. S. 185
the employer to inquire into the internal affairs of the
union."
S.Rep. No. 105, 80th Cong., 1st Sess., 20, I Legislative History
of the Labor Management Relations Act, 1947 (hereafter Leg.Hist.)
426. (Emphasis supplied.) Senator Taft, in answer to protestations
by Senator Pepper that § 8(b)(2) would intervene in the union's
internal affairs and "deny it the right to protect itself against a
man in the union who betrays the objectives of the union . . . ,"
stated:
"
The pending measure does not propose any limitation with
respect to the internal affairs of unions. They still will be
able to fire any members they wish to fire,
and they still will
be able to try any of their members. All that they will not be
able to do, after the enactment of this bill, is this: if they fire
a member for some reason other than nonpayment of dues, they cannot
make his employer discharge him from his job and throw him out of
work. That is the only result of the provision under discussion.
[
Footnote 13]"
(Emphasis supplied.) Section 8(b)(1)(A) was under consideration
when Senator Taft said this. Congressional emphasis that § 8(b)(2)
insulated an employee's membership from his job, but left internal
union affairs to union self-government, is therefore significant
evidence against reading § 8(b)(1)(A) as contemplating regulation
of internal discipline. This is borne out by the fact that
provision was also made in the Taft-Hartley Act for a special
committee to study, among other things, "the internal organization
and administration of labor unions. . . ." § 402(3), 61 Stat.
160.
What legislative materials there are dealing with § 8(b)(1)(A)
contain not a single word referring to the
Page 388 U. S. 186
application of its prohibitions to traditional internal union
discipline in general, or disciplinary fines in particular. On the
contrary there are a number of assurances by its sponsors that the
section was not meant to regulate the internal affairs of
unions.
The provision was not contained in the Senate or House bills
reported out of committee, but was introduced as an amendment on
the Senate floor by Senator Ball. The amendment was adopted in the
Conference Committee, without significant enlightenment from the
report of that committee. The first suggestion that restraint or
coercion of employees in the exercise of § 7 rights should be an
unfair labor practice appears in the Statement of Supplemental
Views to the Senate Report in which a minority of the Senate
Committee, including Senators Ball, Taft, and Smith, concurred. The
mischief against which the Statement inveighed was restraint and
coercion by unions in organizational campaigns.
"The committee heard many instances of union coercion of
employees, such as that brought about by threats of reprisal
against employees and their families in the course of organizing
campaigns; also direct interference by mass picketing and other
violence."
S.Rep. No. 105,
supra, at 50, I Leg.Hist. 456. Senator
Ball proposed § 8(b)(1)(A) as an amendment to the Senate bill, and
stated,
"The purpose of the amendment is simply to provide that, where
unions, in their organizational campaigns, indulge in practices
which, if an employer indulged in them, would be unfair labor
practices, such as making threats or false promises or false
statements, the unions also shall be guilty of unfair labor
practices."
93 Cong.Rec. 4016, II Leg.Hist. 1018. Senator Ball gave numerous
examples of the kind of union conduct the amendment was to cover.
Each one related to union conduct during organizational campaigns.
[
Footnote 14]
Page 388 U. S. 187
Senator Ball reiterated this purpose several times thereafter,
[
Footnote 15] including
remarks added after passage of the amendment. [
Footnote 16] The consistent thrust of his
arguments was the necessity of controlling union conduct in
organizational campaigns. Indeed, when Senator Holland introduced
the proviso eliminating from the reach of 8(b)(1)(A) "the right of
a labor organization to prescribe its own rules with respect to the
acquisition or retention of membership . . . ," Senator Ball
replied,
"I merely wish to state to the Senate that the amendment offered
by the Senator from Florida is perfectly agreeable to me.
It
was never the intention of the sponsors of the pending amendment to
interfere with the internal affairs or organization of unions.
[
Footnote 17]"
(Emphasis supplied.) After acceptance of the proviso, and on the
same day as the vote on the amendment itself, Senator Ball said of
the proviso:
"That modification is designed to make it clear that we are not
trying to interfere with the internal affairs of a union which is
already organized. All we are trying to cover is the coercive and
restraining acts of the union in its effort to organize unorganized
employees. [
Footnote
18]"
Another co-sponsor of the amendment, Senator Smith, echoed this
purpose:
"The pending measure is designed
Page 388 U. S. 188
to protect employees in their freedom to decide whether or not
they desire to join labor organizations, to prevent them from being
restrained or coerced. [
Footnote
19]"
Senator Taft also initially confined his comments on the
amendment to examples of organizational tactics. [
Footnote 20] However, in debate with
Senator Pepper, he suggested a broader but still limited
application:
"If there is anything clear in the development of labor union
history in the past 10 years, it is that more and more labor union
employees have come to be subject to the orders of labor union
leaders. The bill provides for the right to protest against
arbitrary powers which have been exercised by some of the labor
union leaders. [
Footnote
21]"
(Emphasis supplied.) In reply to Senator Pepper's protest that
union members can protect themselves against such "tyranny,"
Senator Taft stated,
"I think it is fair to say that, in the case of many of the
unions, the employee has a good deal more of an opportunity to
select his employer than he has to select his labor union leader.
[
Footnote 22]"
Senator Taft further observed that union leaders sometimes
penalize those who vote against them. Senator Pepper then attempted
to draw an analogy between union members and shareholders in a
corporation, to which Senator Taft replied,
"The Congress has gone much further in protecting the rights of
minority stockholders in corporations than it has in protecting the
rights of members of unions.
Even
Page 388 U. S. 189
in this bill, we do not tell the unions how they shall vote
or how they shall conduct their affairs. . . . [
Footnote 23]"
(Emphasis supplied.) Senator Pepper attempted twice to clarify
the effect of the amendment on internal affairs, but Senator Taft
answered only that the amendment applied to nonunion men as well.
[
Footnote 24]
It was one week after this debate between Senator Taft and
Senator Pepper that § 8(b)(1)(A) was adopted by the Senate as an
amendment to the bill. There was no further reference in the
debates to the applicability of the section to internal union
affairs, by Senator Taft or anyone else, despite the repeated
statements by Senator Ball that it bore no relationship to the
conduct of such affairs. At one point, Senator Saltonstall asked
Senator Taft to provide examples of the kind of union conduct
covered by the section. Senator Taft responded with examples of
threats of bodily harm, economic coercion, and mass picketing in
organizational campaigns and coercion which prevented employees not
involved in a labor dispute from going to work. [
Footnote 25] But any inference
Page 388 U. S. 190
that Senator Taft envisioned that 8(b)(1)(A) intruded into and
regulated internal union affairs is negated by his categorical
statements to the contrary in the contemporaneous debates on §
8(b)(2).
It is true that there are references in the Senate debate on §
8(b)(1)(A) to an intent to impose the same prohibitions on unions
that applied to employers as regards restraint and coercion of
employees in their exercise of § 7 rights. [
Footnote 26] However apposite this parallel
might be when applied to organizational tactics, it clearly is
inapplicable
Page 388 U. S. 191
to the relationship of a union member to his own union. Union
membership allows the member a part in choosing the very course of
action to which he refuses to adhere, but he has, of course, no
role in employer conduct, and nonunion employees have no voice in
the affairs of the union. [
Footnote 27]
Cogent support for an interpretation of the body of 8(b)(1) as
not reaching the imposition of fines and attempts at court
enforcement is the proviso to § 8(b)(1). It states that nothing in
the section shall "impair the right of a labor organization to
prescribe its own rules with respect to the acquisition or
retention of membership therein. . . ." Senator Holland offered the
proviso during debate, and Senator Ball immediately accepted it,
stating that it was not the intent of the sponsors in any way to
regulate the internal affairs of unions. [
Footnote 28] At the very least, it can be said that
the proviso preserves the rights of unions to impose fines, as a
lesser penalty than
Page 388 U. S. 192
expulsion, and to impose fines which carry the explicit or
implicit threat of expulsion for nonpayment. Therefore, under the
proviso, the rule in the UAW constitution governing fines is valid,
and the fines themselves and expulsion for nonpayment would not be
an unfair labor practice. Assuming that the proviso cannot also be
read to authorize court enforcement of fines, a question we need
not reach, [
Footnote 29] the
fact remains that to interpret the body of § 8(b)(1) to apply to
the imposition and collection of fines would be to impute to
Congress a concern with the permissible
means of
enforcement of union fines and to attribute to Congress a narrow
and discrete interest in banning court enforcement of such fines.
Yet there is not one word in the legislative history evidencing any
such congressional concern. And, as we have pointed out, a
distinction between court enforcement and expulsion would have been
anomalous for several reasons. First, Congress was operating within
the context of the "contract theory" of the union-member
relationship which widely prevailed at that time. The efficacy of a
contract is precisely its legal enforceability. A lawsuit is, and
has been, the ordinary way by which performance of private money
obligations is compelled. Second, as we have noted, such a
distinction would visit upon the member of a strong union a
potentially more severe punishment than court enforcement of fines,
while impairing the bargaining facility of the weak union by
requiring it either to condone misconduct or deplete its ranks.
There may be concern that court enforcement may permit the
collection of unreasonably large fines. [
Footnote 30] However,
Page 388 U. S. 193
even were there evidence that Congress shared this concern,
[
Footnote 31]this would not
justify reading the Act also to bar court enforcement of reasonable
fines. [
Footnote 32]
The 1959 Landrum-Griffin amendments, thought to be the first
comprehensive regulation by Congress of the conduct of internal
union affairs, [
Footnote 33]
also negate the reach
Page 388 U. S. 194
given § 8(b)(1)(A) by the majority en banc below.
"To be sure, what Congress did in 1959 does not establish what
it meant in 1947. However, as another major step in an evolving
pattern of regulation of union conduct, the 1959 Act is a relevant
consideration. Courts may properly take into account the later Act
when asked to extend the reach of the earlier Act's vague language
to the limits which, read literally, the words might permit."
Labor Board v. Drivers Local Union, 362 U.
S. 274,
362 U. S.
291-292. In 1959, Congress did seek to protect union
members in their relationship to the union by adopting measures to
insure the provision of democratic processes in the conduct of
union affairs and procedural due process to members subjected to
discipline. Even then, some Senators emphasized that,
"in establishing and enforcing statutory standards, great care
should be taken not to undermine union self-government or weaken
unions in their role as collective bargaining agents."
S.Rep. No. 187, 86th Cong., 1st Sess., 7. The Eighty-sixth
Congress was thus plainly of the view that union self-government
was not regulated in 1947. Indeed, that Congress expressly
recognized that a union member may be "fined, suspended, expelled,
or otherwise disciplined," and enacted only procedural requirements
to be observed. 73 Stat. 523, 29 U.S.C. § 411(a)(5). Moreover,
Congress added a proviso to the guarantee of freedom of speech and
assembly disclaiming any intent
"to impair the right of a labor organization to adopt and
enforce reasonable rules as to the responsibility of every member
toward the organization as an institution. . . ."
29 U.S.C. § 411(a)(2).
The 1959 provisions are significant for still another reason. We
have seen that the only indication in the debates over § 8(b)(1)(A)
of a reach beyond organizational tactics which restrain or coerce
nonmembers was Senator Taft's concern with arbitrary and
undemocratic
Page 388 U. S. 195
union leadership. The 1959 amendments are addressed to that
concern. The kind of regulation of internal union affairs which
Senator Taft said protected stockholders of a corporation, and made
necessary a "right of protest against arbitrary powers which have
been exercised by some of the labor union leaders," [
Footnote 34] is embodied in the 1959 Act.
The requirements of adherence to democratic principles, fair
procedures and freedom of speech apply to the election of union
officials and extend into all aspects of union affairs. [
Footnote 35] In the present case,
the procedures followed for calling the strikes and disciplining
the recalcitrant members fully comported with these requirements,
and were in every way fair and democratic. Whether § 8(b)(1)(A)
proscribes arbitrary imposition of fines, or punishment for
disobedience of a fiat of a union leader, are matters not presented
by this case, and upon which we express no view.
Thus, this history of congressional action does not support a
conclusion that the Taft-Hartley prohibitions against restraint or
coercion of an employee to refrain from concerted activities
included a prohibition against the imposition of fines on members
who decline to honor an authorized strike and attempts to collect
such fines. Rather, the contrary inference is more justified in
light of the repeated refrain throughout the debates on §
8(b)(1)(A) and other sections that Congress did not propose any
limitations with respect to the internal affairs of unions, aside
from barring enforcement of a union's internal regulations to
affect a member's employment status.
Page 388 U. S. 196
III
The collective bargaining agreements with the locals incorporate
union security clauses. Full union membership is not compelled by
the clauses: an employee is required only to become and remain "a
member of the Union . . . to the extent of paying his monthly dues.
. . ." The majority en banc below nevertheless regarded full
membership to be
"the result not of individual voluntary choice, but of the
insertion of [this] union security provision in the contract under
which a substantial minority of the employees may have been forced
into membership."
358 F.2d at 660. But the relevant inquiry here is not what
motivated a member's full membership, but whether the Taft-Hartley
amendments prohibited disciplinary measures against a full member
who crossed his union's picket line. It is clear that the fined
employees involved herein enjoyed full union membership. Each
executed the pledge of allegiance to the UAW constitution and took
the oath of full membership. Moreover, the record of the Milwaukee
County Court case against Benjamin Natzke discloses that two
disciplined employees testified that they had fully participated in
the proceedings leading to the strike. They attended the meetings
at which the secret strike vote and the renewed strike vote were
taken. It was upon this and similar evidence that the Milwaukee
County Court found that Natzke "had, by his actions, become a
member of the union for all purposes. . . ." Allis-Chalmers offered
no evidence in this proceeding that any of the fined employees
enjoyed other than full union membership. We will not presume the
contrary.
Cf. Machinists v. Street, 367 U.
S. 740,
367 U. S. 774.
[
Footnote 36] Indeed, it
Page 388 U. S. 197
is and has been Allis-Chalmers' position that the Taft-Hartley
prohibitions apply whatever the nature of the membership. Whether
those prohibitions would apply if the locals had imposed fines on
members whose membership was, in fact, limited to the obligation of
paying monthly dues is a question not before us, and upon which we
intimate no view. [
Footnote
37]
The judgment of the Court of Appeals is
Reversed.
[
Footnote 1]
The relevant provisions of §§ 7 and 8(b)(1)(A), 61 Stat. 140,
141, 29 U.S.C. §§ 157 and 158(b)(1)(A), are
"SEC. 7. Employees shall have the right to . . . engage in . . .
concerted activities . . . and shall also have the right to refrain
from any or all of such activities. . . ."
"SEC. 8(b). It shall be an unfair labor practice for a labor
organization or its agents -- "
"(1) to restrain or coerce (A) employees in the exercise of the
rights guaranteed in section 7:
Provided, That this
paragraph shall not impair the right of a labor organization to
prescribe its own rules with respect to the acquisition or
retention of membership therein. . . ."
[
Footnote 2]
Two locals were involved, Local 248 at the West Allis plant, and
Local 401 at the La Crosse plant. Although Allis-Chalmers' charges
of unfair labor practices mentioned threats of fines as well as
imposition of fines, the only proof that fines were specifically
threatened during a strike consisted of a letter to strike-breaking
West Allis members of Local 248 in 1959. As to the 1962 strike at
West Allis and both the 1959 and 1962 strikes at La Crosse, mention
of fines first occurred after the strikes were over. The threat of
court enforcement of the fines was first made in 1960 in letters
sent to fined members of Local 248 who had not paid their fines;
the letter informed them of the outcome of a Wisconsin Supreme
Court opinion holding fines enforceable,
UAW, Local 756 v.
Woychik, 5 Wis.2d 528, 93 N.W.2d 336 (1958). Local 401's test
suit was brought after the 1962 strike.
[
Footnote 3]
See J. I. Case Co. v. Labor Board, 321 U.
S. 332,
Medo Photo Supply Corp. v. Labor Board,
321 U. S. 678;
ILGWU v. Labor Board, 366 U. S. 731,
366 U. S.
737.
[
Footnote 4]
See Mastro Plastics Corp. v. Labor Board, 350 U.
S. 270,
350 U. S.
280.
[
Footnote 5]
See Labor Board v. Rockaway News Co., 345 U. S.
71.
[
Footnote 6]
Wellington, Union Democracy and Fair Representation: Federal
Responsibility in Federal System, 67 Yale L.J. 1327, 1333
(1958).
[
Footnote 7]
See, e.g., Summers, Legal Limitations on Union
Discipline, 64 Harv.L.Rev. 1049 (1951); Philip Taft, The Structure
and Government of Labor Unions 117-180 (1954); Taylor, The Role of
Unions in a Democratic Society, Selected Readings on Government
Regulation of Internal Union Affairs Affecting the Rights of
Members, prepared for the Subcommittee on Labor of the Senate
Committee on Labor and Public Welfare 17 (Committee Print, 85th
Cong., 2d Sess., 1958) (hereafter Selected Readings); Kerr, Unions
and Union Leaders of Their Own Choosing, Selected Readings,
supra, at 106, 109.
[
Footnote 8]
Summers,
supra, n
7, at 1049.
"Strikebreaking is uniformly considered sufficient reason for
expulsion, whether or not there is an express prohibition, for it
undercuts the union's principal weapon and defeats the economic
objective for which the union exists."
Summers, Disciplinary Powers of Unions, 3 Ind. &
Lab.Rel.Rev. 483, 495 (1950).
[
Footnote 9]
National Industrial Conference Board, The Union, The Leader, and
The Members, Selected Readings, at 40, 69-71; Summers, Disciplinary
Powers of Unions, 3 Ind.Lab.Rel.Rev. 483, 508-512 (1950);
Disciplinary Powers and Procedures in Union Constitutions, U.S.
Dept. of Labor Bulletin No. 1350, Bur.Lab.Statistics (1963).
It is suggested that, while such provisions for fines and
expulsion were a common element of union constitutions at the time
of the enactment of § 8(b)(1), such background loses its cogency
here, because such provisions did not explicitly call for court
enforcement. However the potentiality of resort to courts for
enforcement is implicit in any binding obligation. Surely it cannot
be said that the absence of a "court enforceability" clause in a
contract of sale implies that the parties do not foresee resort to
the courts as a possible means of enforcement. It is also suggested
that court enforcement of fines is "a rather recent innovation."
Yet such enforcement was known as early as 1867.
Master
Stevedores' Assn. v. Walsh, 2 Daly 1 (N.Y.).
[
Footnote 10]
Summers, The Law of Union Discipline: What the Courts Do in
Fact, 70 Yale L.J. 175, 180 (1960).
[
Footnote 11]
See generally Chafee, The Internal Affairs of
Associations Not for Profit, 43 Harv.L.Rev. 993 (1930); Note,
Judicial Control of Actions of Private Associations, 76 Harv.L.Rev.
983 (1963); Cox, Internal Affairs of Labor Unions Under the Labor
Reform Act of 1959, 58 Mich.L.Rev. 819, 835-836 (1960).
[
Footnote 12]
"Since the union's effectiveness is based largely on the degree
to which it controls the available labor, expulsions tend to weaken
the union. If large numbers are expelled, they become a threat to
union standards by undercutting union rates, and, in case of a
strike, they may act as strikebreakers. . . . Therefore, expulsions
must be limited to very small numbers unless the union is so
strongly entrenched that it cannot be effectively challenged by the
employer or another union."
Summers, Disciplinary Powers of Unions, 3 Ind. &
Lab.Rel.Rev. 483, 487-488 (1950).
[
Footnote 13]
93 Cong.Rec. 4193, II Leg.Hist. 1097.
[
Footnote 14]
93 Cong.Rec. 4016-4017, II Leg.Hist. 1018-1021. Examples were
given in debate of threats by unions to double the dues of
employees who waited until later to join. It is suggested that this
is no less within the ambit of internal union affairs than the
fines imposed in the present case. But the significant distinction
is that the cited examples necessarily concern threats against
nonmembers designed to coerce them into joining, and are therefore
further evidence of the primary concern of Congress with
organizational tactics.
[
Footnote 15]
93 Cong.Rec. 4271, 4432, 4434, II Leg.Hist. 1139, 1199,
1203.
[
Footnote 16]
93 Cong.Rec. A-2252, II Leg.Hist. 1524-1525.
[
Footnote 17]
93 Cong.Rec. 4272, II Leg.Hist. 1141.
[
Footnote 18]
93 Cong.Rec. 4433, II Leg.Hist. 1200.
[
Footnote 19]
93 Cong.Rec. 4435, II Leg.Hist. 1204.
[
Footnote 20]
93 Cong.Rec. 4021-4022, II Leg.Hist. 1025-1027.
[
Footnote 21]
93 Cong.Rec. 4023, II Leg.Hist. 1028.
See Summers, Disciplinary Powers of Unions, 3
Ind.Lab.Rel.Rev. 483:
"It is significant that among the major changes made in the
Wagner Act by the Labor Management Relations Act of 1947 was the
addition of sections purported to be aimed at protecting individual
union members against undemocratic and corrupt leaders."
[
Footnote 22]
93 Cong.Rec. 4023, II Leg.Hist. 1028.
[
Footnote 23]
93 Cong.Rec. 4024, II Leg.Hist. 1030. It was in the context of
the quoted limiting statements that, in answer to Senator Ives'
suggestion that the matter of union coercion should be further
investigated, Senator Taft made the broad remark that
"[m]erely to require that unions be subject to the same rules
that govern employers, and that they do not have the right to
interfere with or coerce employees, either their own members or
those outside their union, is such a clear matter, and seems to me
so easy to determine, that I would hope we would all agree."
93 Cong.Rec. 4025, II Leg.Hist. 1032.
[
Footnote 24]
93 Cong.Rec. 4023, 4024, II Leg.Hist. 1029, 1030. It is this
colloquy to which the dissent apparently refers in its statement
that, in answer to Senator Pepper's charge that the amendment
protected workers against their own leaders, "Senator Taft did not
deny it." It may be more accurate to say that Senator Taft evaded
the issue.
[
Footnote 25]
93 Cong.Rec. 4435-4436, II Leg.Hist. 1205-1206. The following
statement of Senator Taft had no reference to the conduct of a
union
vis-a-vis a member who crossed the union's picket
line, but referred to union conduct in preventing employees not in
the bargaining unit from going to work -- "mass picketing, which
absolutely prevents all the office force from going into the office
of a plant."
"The effect of the pending amendment is that the Board may call
the union before them, exactly as it has called the employer, and
say,"
"Here are the rules of the game. You must cease and desist from
coercing and restraining the employees who want to work from going
to work and earning the money which they are entitled to earn."
"The Board may say,"
"You can persuade them; you can put up signs; you can conduct
any form of propaganda you want to in order to persuade them, but
you cannot, by threat of force or threat of economic reprisal,
prevent them from exercising their right to work."
"As I see it, that is the effect of the amendment."
93 Cong.Rec. 4436, II Leg.Hist. 1206.
His statements in a colloquy with Senator Morse were made in the
same context. 93 Cong.Rec. 4436, II Leg.Hist. 1207. We read his
"Supplementary Analysis of Labor Bill as Passed" as also referring
to coercion of nonmembers of the striking bargaining unit. 93
Cong.Rec. 6859, II Leg.Hist. 1623. That he distinguished members
from nonmembers also appears from his statement concerning the
section that
"[i]ts application to
labor organizations may have a
slightly different implication, but it seems to me perfectly clear
that, from the point of view of the
employee, the two
cases are parallel."
93 Cong.Rec. 4023, II Leg.Hist. 1028. (Emphasis supplied.)
It is not true that "the sponsors of the section repeatedly
announced that it would protect union members from their leaders."
Only Senator Taft's statements provide limited support for the
proposition.
[
Footnote 26]
S.Rep. No. 105, 80th Cong., 1st Sess., 50, I Leg.Hist. 456; 93
Cong.Rec. 4025, 4436, II Leg.Hist. 1032, 1207.
[
Footnote 27]
Cf. statement of Justice Stone in
South Carolina
Hwy. Dept. v. Barnwell Bros., 303 U.
S. 177,
303 U. S.
184-185, n. 2:
"State regulations affecting interstate commerce, whose purpose
or effect is to gain for those within the state an advantage at the
expense of those without, or to burden those out of the state
without any corresponding advantage to those within, have been
thought to impinge upon the constitutional prohibition even though
Congress has not acted."
[Citations omitted.]
"Underlying the stated rule has been the thought, often
expressed in judicial opinion, that,
when the regulation is of
such a character that its burden falls principally upon those
without the state, legislative action is not likely to be subjected
to those political restraints which are normally exerted on
legislation where it affects adversely some interests within the
state."
(Emphasis supplied.) A commentator has noted that "the ballot in
a free election is the individual union member's weapon for
inducing performance in accordance with his desire." Wellington,
Union Democracy and Fair Representation: Federal Responsibility in
a Federal System, 67 Yale L.J. 1327, 1329 (1958).
[
Footnote 28]
93 Cong.Rec. 4272, 4433, II Leg.Hist. 1141, 1200.
[
Footnote 29]
Our conclusion that § 8(b)(1)(A) does not prohibit the locals'
actions makes it unnecessary to pass on the Board holding that the
proviso protected such actions.
[
Footnote 30]
The notification by Local 248 to its strikebreaking employees
that each day they continued to work might constitute a separate
offense punishable by a fine of $100 was sent only to members of
Local 248, not those of Local 401, and only during one of the two
strikes called by Local 248. The notification was sent only to
those employees who had already decided to work during the strike.
Most important, no inference can be drawn from that notification
that court enforcement would be the means of collection. Therefore,
at least under the proviso, if not the body of § 8(b)(1), such
notification would not be an unfair labor practice. It is not
argued that the fines for which court enforcement was actually
sought were unreasonably large.
[
Footnote 31]
Senator Wiley's reference in a speech after § 8(b)(1) was passed
to $20,000 fines for crossing a picket line was not directed to the
section. 93 Cong.Rec. 5000, II Leg.Hist. 1471.
[
Footnote 32]
It has been noted that the state courts, in reviewing the
imposition of union discipline, find ways to strike down
"discipline [which] involves a severe hardship." Summers, Legal
Limitations on Union Discipline, 64 Harv.L.Rev. 1049, 1078
(1951).
It is suggested that reading § 8(b)(1) to allow court
enforcement of fines adds a "new weapon to the union's economic
arsenal," and is inconsistent with the mood of Congress to curtail
the powers of unions. The question here, however, is not whether
Congress gave to unions a new power, but whether it eliminated,
without debate, a power which the unions already possessed.
[
Footnote 33]
In 1958, in
Machinists v. Gonzales, 356 U.
S. 617,
356 U. S. 620,
we said:
"[T]he protection of union members in their rights as members
from arbitrary conduct by unions and union officers has not been
undertaken by federal law, and indeed the assertion of any such
power has been expressly denied."
See Cox, Internal Affairs of Labor Unions Under the
Labor Reform Act of 1959, 58 Mich.L.Rev. 819, 852:
"The act is the first major step in the regulation of the
internal affairs of labor unions. It expands the national labor
policy into the area of relations between the employees and the
labor union. Previously national policy was confined to
relationships between management and union."
[
Footnote 34]
93 Cong.Rec. 4023, II Leg.Hist. 1028.
[
Footnote 35]
29 U.S.C. §§ 411-415, 431(c), 461-464, 481-482. Significantly,
the Landrum-Griffin amendments expressly rendered it unlawful for
any union "to fine, suspend, expel, or otherwise discipline any of
its member for exercising any right to which he is entitled . . ."
under that Act. 29 U.S.C. § 529.
[
Footnote 36]
In
Machinists v. Street, we held that employees who
were members of a union under a union security agreement authorized
by the Railway Labor Act, had a right to relief against a union
using their dues payments for political purposes. We said, at
367 U. S.
774:
"Any remedies, however, would properly be granted only to
employees who have made known to the union officials that they do
not desire their funds to be used for political causes to which
they object. The safeguards of [the Act] . . . were added for the
protection of dissenters' interest, but dissent is not to be
presumed -- it must affirmatively be made known to the union by the
dissenting employee. . . . Thus, we think that only those who have
identified themselves, as opposed to political uses of their funds
are entitled to relief in this action."
[
Footnote 37]
Under § 8(a)(3), the extent of an employee's obligation under a
union security agreement is
"expressly limited to the payment of initiation fees and monthly
dues. . . . 'Membership' as a condition of employment is whittled
down to its financial core."
Labor Board v. General Motors Corp., 373 U.
S. 734,
373 U. S.
742.
Not before us is the question of the extent to which union
action for enforcement of disciplinary penalties is preempted by
federal labor law.
Compare Machinists v. Gonzales,
356 U. S. 617;
Plumbers' Union v. Borden, 373 U.
S. 690.
MR. JUSTICE WHITE, concurring.
It is true that § 8(b)(1)(A) makes it an unfair labor practice
for a union to restrain or coerce any employees in the exercise of
§ 7 rights, but the proviso permits the union to make its own rules
with respect to acquisition and retention of membership. Hence, a
union may expel to enforce its own internal rules, even though a
particular rule limits the § 7 rights of its members and
Page 388 U. S. 198
even though expulsion to enforce it would be a clear and serious
brand of "coercion" imposed in derogation of those § 7 rights. Such
restraint and coercion Congress permitted by adding the proviso to
§ 8(b)(1)(A). Thus, neither the majority nor the dissent in this
case questions the validity of the union rule against its members'
crossing picket lines during a properly called strike, or the
propriety of expulsion to enforce the rule. Section 8(b)(1)(A),
therefore, does not bar
all restraint and coercion by a
union to prevent the exercise by its members of their § 7 rights.
"Coercive" union rules are enforceable at least by expulsion.
The dissenting opinion in this case, although not questioning
the enforceability of coercive rules by expulsion from membership,
questions whether fines for violating such rules are enforceable at
all, by expulsion or otherwise. The dissent would at least hold
court collection of fines to be an unfair labor practice,
apparently for the reason that fines collectible in court may be
more coercive than fines enforceable by expulsion. My Brother
BRENNAN, for the Court, takes a different view, reasoning that,
since expulsion would in many cases -- certainly in this one
involving a strong union -- be a far more coercive technique for
enforcing a union rule and for collecting a reasonable fine than
the threat of court enforcement, there is no basis for thinking
that Congress, having accepted expulsion as a permissible technique
to enforce a rule in derogation of § 7 rights, nevertheless
intended to bar enforcement by another method which may be far less
coercive.
I do not mean to indicate, and I do not read the majority
opinion otherwise, that every conceivable internal union rule which
impinges upon the § 7 rights of union members is valid and
enforceable by expulsion and court action. There may well be some
internal union rules which, on their face, are wholly invalid and
unenforceable.
Page 388 U. S. 199
But the Court seems unanimous in upholding the rule against
crossing picket lines during a strike and its enforceability by
expulsion from membership. On this premise, I think the opinion
written for the Court is the more persuasive and sensible
construction of the statute, and I therefore join it, although I am
doubtful about the implications of some of its generalized
statements.
MR. JUSTICE BLACK, whom MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS, MR. JUSTICE HARLAN,
and MR. JUSTICE STEWART join, dissenting.
The United Automobile Workers went on a lawful economic strike
against the Allis-Chalmers Manufacturing Co. Some union members,
refusing to engage in the concerted strike activities, crossed the
picket lines, and continued to work for Allis-Chalmers. The right
to refrain from engaging in such "concerted activities" is
guaranteed all employees by the language of § 7 of the National
Labor Relations Act, as amended, 61 Stat. 140, and § 8(b)(1)(A) of
the Act, 61 Stat. 141, makes it an unfair labor practice for a
union to "restrain or coerce" employees in their exercise of their
§ 7 rights. Despite these emphatic guarantees of the Act, the union
filed charges against the employees and imposed fines against those
who had crossed its picket lines to go back to work. Though the
proviso to § 8(b)(1)(A) preserves the union's "right . . . to
prescribe its own rules with respect to the . . . retention of
membership therein," the union did not attempt to exercise its
right under the proviso to expel the disciplined members when they
refused to pay the fines. Instead, it brought legal proceedings in
state courts to compel the payment of the fines. The Court now
affirms the Labor Board's action in refusing to find the union
guilty of an unfair labor practice under 8(b)(1)(A) for fining its
members because they
Page 388 U. S. 200
crossed its picket lines. I cannot agree, and therefore would
affirm the judgment of the Court of Appeals which set aside the
Labor Board's order.
I
In determining what the Court here holds, it is helpful to note
what it does not hold. Since the union resorted to the courts to
enforce its fines instead of relying on its own internal sanctions
such as expulsion from membership, the Court correctly assumes that
the proviso to § 8(b)(1)(A) cannot be read to authorize its
holding. Neither does the Court attempt to sustain its holding by
reference to § 7, which gives employees the right to refrain from
engaging in concerted activities. To be sure, the Court, in
characterizing the union-member relationship as "contractual" and
in emphasizing that its holding is limited to situations where the
employee is a "full member" of the union, implies that, by joining
a union, an employee gives up or waives some of his § 7 rights. But
the Court does not say that a union member is without the § 7 right
to refrain from participating in such concerted activity as an
economic strike called by his union. Such a holding would be
clearly unwarranted even by resort to the legislative history of
the 1947 addition to § 7 of "the right to refrain from any or all
of such activities." According to Senator Taft, that phrase was
added by the Conference Committee to
"make the prohibition contained in section 8(b)(1) apply to
coercive acts of unions against employees who did not wish to join
or did not care to participate in a strike or picket
line."
93 Cong.Rec. 6859, II Leg.Hist. 1623. (Emphasis added.)
With no reliance on the proviso to § 8(b)(1)(A) or on the
meaning of § 7, the Court's holding boils down to this: a
court-enforced reasonable fine for nonparticipation in a strike
does not "restrain or coerce" an employee in the
Page 388 U. S. 201
exercise of his right not to participate in the strike. In
holding as it does, the Court interprets the words "restrain or
coerce" in a way directly opposed to their literal meaning, for the
Court admits that fines are as coercive as penalties imposed on
citizens for the nonpayment of taxes. Though Senator Taft, in
answer to charges that these words were ambiguous, said their
meaning "is perfectly clear," 93 Cong.Rec. 4021, II Leg.Hist. 1025,
and though any union official with sufficient intelligence and
learning to be chosen as such could hardly fail to comprehend the
meaning of these plain, simple English words, the Court insists on
finding an "inherent imprecision" in these words. And that
characterization then allows the Court to resort to "[w]hat
legislative materials there are." In doing so, the Court finds
three significant things: (1) there is "not a single word" to
indicate that § 8(b)(1)(A) was intended to apply to "traditional
internal union discipline in general, or disciplinary fines in
particular"; (2) the "repeated refrain" running through the debates
on the section was that Congress did not intend to impose any
limitations on the "internal affairs of unions"; (3) the Senators
who supported the section were primarily concerned with union
coercion during organizational drives, and with union violence in
general.
Even were I to agree with the Court's three observations about
the legislative history of § 8(b)(1)(A), I do not think they alone
justify disregarding the plain meaning of the section, and it seems
perfectly clear to me that the Court does not think so either. The
real reason for the Court's decision is its policy judgment that
unions, especially weak ones, need the power to impose fines on
strikebreakers and to enforce those fines in court. It is not
enough, says the Court, that the unions have the power to expel
those members who refuse to participate in a strike or who fail to
pay fines imposed on them for such
Page 388 U. S. 202
failure to participate; it is essential that weak unions have
the choice between expulsion and court-enforced fines, simply
because the latter are more effective, in the sense of being more
punitive. Though the entire mood of Congress in 1947 was to curtail
the power of unions, as it had previously curtailed the power of
employers, in order to equalize the power of the two, the Court is
unwilling to believe that Congress intended to impair "the
usefulness of labor's cherished strike weapon." [
Footnote 2/1] I cannot agree with this conclusion,
or subscribe to the Court's unarticulated premise that the Court
has power to add a new weapon to the union's economic arsenal
whenever the Court believes that the union needs that weapon. That
is a job for Congress, not this Court.
II
Though the Court recognizes that a union fine is, in fact,
coercive, it seeks support for its holding -- that court-enforced
fines are not prohibited by § 8(b)(1)(A) -- by reference to the
proviso which authorizes a union to prescribe its own rules with
respect to the retention of membership. The Court first assumes
that the proviso protects the union's right to expel members for
the express purpose of discouraging them from going to work. From
that assumption, the Court then suggests that
"[a]t the very least . . . , the proviso preserves the rights of
unions to impose fines, as a lesser penalty than expulsion,
Page 388 U. S. 203
and to impose fines which carry the . . . threat of expulsion
for nonpayment."
And finally, departing a third step further from the literal
language of the proviso, the Court arrives at its holding that
Congress could not have meant to preclude unions from the
alternative of judicially enforcing fines.
Contrary to the Court, I am not at all certain that a union's
right under the proviso to prescribe rules for the retention of
membership includes the right to restrain a member from working by
trying him on the vague charge of "conduct unbecoming a union
member" and fining him for exercising his § 7 right of refusing to
participate in a strike, even though the fine is only enforceable
by expulsion from membership. It is one thing to say that Congress
did not wish to interfere with the union's power, similar to that
of any other kind of voluntary association, to prescribe specific
conditions of membership. It is quite another thing to say that
Congress intended to leave unions free to exercise a court-like
power to try and punish members with a direct economic sanction for
exercising their right to work. Just because a union might be free,
under the proviso, to expel a member for crossing a picket line
does not mean that Congress left unions free to threaten their
members with fines. Even though a member may later discover that
the threatened fine is only enforceable by expulsion, and in that
sense a "lesser penalty," the direct threat of a fine, to a member
normally unaware of the method the union might resort to for
compelling its payment, would often be more coercive than a threat
of expulsion.
Even on the assumption that § 8(b)(1)(A) permits a union to fine
a member as long as the fine is only enforceable by expulsion, the
fundamental error of the Court's opinion is its failure to
recognize the practical and theoretical difference between a
court-enforced fine, as here, and a fine enforced by expulsion or
less drastic
Page 388 U. S. 204
intra-union means. [
Footnote
2/2] As the Court recognizes, expulsion for nonpayment of a
fine may, especially in the case of a strong union, be more severe
than judicial collection of the fine. But, if the union membership
has little value and if the fine is great, then court enforcement
of the fine may be more effective punishment, and that is precisely
why the Court desires to provide weak unions with this alternative
to expulsion, an alternative which is similar to a criminal court's
power to imprison defendants who fail to pay fines.
In this case, each strikebreaking employee was fined from $20 to
$100, and the union initiated a "test case" in state court to
collect the fines. In notifying the employees of the charges
against them, however, the union warned them that each day they
crossed the picket line and went to work might be considered a
separate offense punishable by a fine of $100. In several of the
cases, the strikes lasted for many months. Thus, although the union
here imposed minimal fines for the purpose of its "test case," it
is not too difficult to imagine a case where the fines will be so
large that the threat of their imposition will absolutely restrain
employees from going to work during a strike. Although an employee
might be willing to work even if it meant the loss of union
membership, he would have to be well paid indeed to work at the
risk that he would have to pay his union $100 a day for each day
worked. Of course, as the Court suggests, he might be able to
defeat the union's attempt at judicial enforcement of the fine by
showing it was "unreasonable" or that he was not a "full member" of
the union, but few employees would have the courage or the
financial means to be willing to take that risk.
Cf. Ex parte
Young, 209 U. S. 123.
Page 388 U. S. 205
The Court disposes of this tremendous practical difference
between court-enforced and union-enforced fines by suggesting that
Congress was not concerned with "the permissible means of
enforcement of union fines," and that court-enforcement of fines is
a necessary consequence of the "contract theory" of the
union-member relationship. And then the Court cautions that its
holding may only apply to court enforcement of "reasonable fines."
Apparently the Court believes that these considerations somehow
bring reasonable court-enforced fines within the ambit of "internal
union affairs." There is no basis either historically or logically
for this conclusion or the considerations upon which it is based.
First, the Court says that disciplinary fines were commonplace at
the time the Taft-Hartley Act was passed, and thus Congress could
not have meant to prohibit these "traditional internal union
discipline" measures without saying so. Yet there is not one word
in the authorities cited by the Court that indicates that court
enforcement of fines was commonplace or traditional in 1947, and,
to the contrary, until recently, unions rarely resorted to court
enforcement of union fines. [
Footnote
2/3] Second, Congress' unfamiliarity in 1947 with this recent
innovation and consequent failure to make any distinction between
union-enforced and court-enforced fines cannot support the
conclusion that Congress was unconcerned with the "means" a union
uses to enforce its fines. Congress was expressly concerned with
enacting "rules of the game" for unions to abide by. 93 Cong.Rec.
4436, II Leg.Hist. 1206. As noted by the Labor Board the year after
§ (b)(1)(A)
Page 388 U. S. 206
was passed, "[i]n that Section Congress was aiming at means, not
at ends."
Perry Norvell Co., 80 N.L.R.B. 225, 239. At the
very least, Congress intended to preclude a union's use of certain
means to collect fines. It is clear, as the Court recognizes, that
Congress, in enacting § 8(b)(2), was concerned with insulating an
employee's job from his union membership. If the union here had
attempted to enforce the payment of the fines by persuading the
employer to discharge the nonpaying employees or to withhold the
fines from their wages, it would have clearly been guilty of an
unfair labor practice under § 8(b)(2). [
Footnote 2/4] If the union here, operating under a union
shop contract, had applied the employees' dues to the satisfaction
of the fines and then charged them extra dues, that, under Board
decisions, would have been a violation of § 8(b)(1)(A), since it
would have jeopardized the employees' jobs. [
Footnote 2/5] Yet here, the union has resorted to
equally effective outside assistance to enforce the payment of its
fines, and the Court holds that within the ambit of "internal union
discipline." I have already pointed to the impact that $100 per day
court-enforced fines may have on an employee's job -- they would
totally discourage him from working at all -- and I fail to see how
court enforcement of union fines is any more "internal" than
employer enforcement. The undeniable fact is that the union resorts
to outside help when it is not strong enough to enforce obedience
internally. And even if the union does not resort to outside help,
but uses threats of physical violence by its officers or other
members to compel payment of its fines,
Page 388 U. S. 207
I do not doubt that this too would be a violation of §
8(b)(1)(A).
Finally, the Court attempts to justify court-enforcement of
fines by comparing it to judicial enforcement of the provisions of
an ordinary commercial contract -- a comparison which, according to
the Court's own authority, is simply "a legal fabrication."
[
Footnote 2/6] The contractual
theory of union membership, at least until recently, was a fiction
used by the courts to justify judicial intervention in union
affairs to protect employees, not to help unions. I cannot believe
that Congress intended the effectiveness of § 8(b)(1)(A) to be
impaired by such a fiction, [
Footnote
2/7] or that it was content to rely on the state courts' use of
this fiction to protect members from union coercion. [
Footnote 2/8] Particularly is that so where
the "contract" between the union and the employee is the
involuntary
Page 388 U. S. 208
product of a union shop. Although the Court of Appeals held that
to be the case here, the Court takes the surprising position that
"what motivated" the full union member to make the "contract" is
immaterial. I doubt that even an ordinary commercial contract is
enforceable against a party who entered into it involuntarily. But
I am certain that Congress did not intend to insulate union
coercion from the literal language of § 8(b)(1)(A) merely because
the union has secured a "full" but involuntary contract from those
it desires to coerce.
III
While the Court may be correct in saying that resort to
legislative history is proper here, it is certainly not justified
in ignoring the plain meaning of § 8(b)(1)(A) on the basis of the
inconclusive legislative history it points to. In the first place,
"[w]hat legislative materials there are dealing with § 8(b)(1)(A)"
are only the remarks of a few Senators during the debate on the
floor. The section was added on the floor after the bill had
cleared the Senate Committee. There were no debates on the section
in the House, there were no committee reports on the section, and
debate in the Senate was brief. In the second place, though the
Court deems the words "restrain or coerce" to be "imprecise," it
somehow is willing to attribute a magical quality of clarity to the
refrain "internal affairs of unions." The Court is thus willing to
attribute more certainty and careful consideration to a refrain
used by several Senators in a heated debate in response to certain
criticism than it is to the words repeatedly used in the Act
itself.
The repeated refrain of the debates on § 8(b)(1)(A) was actually
that it was aimed to secure "equality . . . between employers and
employees." [
Footnote 2/9] Over and
over
Page 388 U. S. 209
again, Senator Taft and others emphasized that, if a union
indulges in conduct that would be an unfair labor practice on the
part of an employer, it too should be guilty of an unfair labor
practice. [
Footnote 2/10]
Although the Court deems "this parallel . . . clearly . . .
inapplicable to the relationship of a union member to his own
union," it is clear that the sponsors of § 8(b)(1)(A) did not think
so. Several times, Senator Pepper tried to persuade Senator Taft
that there was a difference between an employee's relation to his
employer and his relation to his union. On each occasion, Senator
Taft replied, "I cannot see any difference." 93 Cong.Rec. 4022, II
Leg.Hist. 1026, 1027. When Senator Pepper asked whether the words
"restrain or coerce" might have a different application to unions
than to employers, Senator Taft replied:
"The Board has been defining those words for 12 years, ever
since it [the Act] came into existence. Its application to labor
organizations may have a slightly different implication, but it
seems to me perfectly clear that, from the point of view of the
employee, the two cases are parallel. . . . If there is anything
clear in the development of labor union history in the past 10
years, it is that more and more
labor union employees have
come to be subject to the orders of labor union leaders. The bill
provides for the right of protest against arbitrary powers which
have been exercised by some of the labor union leaders. Certainly
it seems to me that, if we are willing to accept the principle that
employees are entitled to the same protection against labor union
leaders as against employers, then I can see no reasonable
objection to the amendment. . . ."
93 Cong.Rec. 4023, II Leg.Hist. 1028. (Emphasis added.)
Page 388 U. S. 210
When Senator Pepper replied that Senator Taft was overlooking
"the fact that the workers elect their own officers, whereas they
do not elect their employers" -- precisely the fact that the Court
points to in finding the parallel between unions and employers
inapplicable -- Senator Taft replied:
"I think it is fair to say that, in the case of many of the
unions, the employee has a good deal more of an opportunity to
select his employer than he has to select his labor union leader,
and even if he has that opportunity . . . , the man who is elected
may have been voted against by various of the employees who did not
desire to have that particular man elected as the union leader. In
such cases, the very fact that they did vote against that man is
often used later by the union as a means of coercing such
employees, and,
in some cases, the union expels them from the
union or subjects them to treatment which interferes with their
rights as American citizens."
93 Cong.Rec. 4023, II Leg.Hist. 1028. (Emphasis added.) And
finally, when Senator Pepper charged that the "amendment is an
effort to protect the workers against their own leaders," Senator
Taft did not deny it. [
Footnote
2/11] He clearly stated that the bill was designed to warn
unions "that they do not have the right to interfere with or coerce
employees, either
their own members or those outside their
union." 93 Cong.Rec. 4025, II Leg.Hist. 1032. (Emphasis added.)
It is true that the Senate sponsors of § 8(b)(1)(A) were
primarily concerned with coercive organizational tactics of unions,
and that most of the examples of abuse referred to in the debates
concerned threats of violence
Page 388 U. S. 211
by unions against nonmember employees. But to say that §
8(b)(1)(A) covers
only coercive organizational tactics,
which the Court comes very close to doing, is to ignore much of the
legislative history. It is clear that § 8(b)(1)(A) was intended to
protect union as well as nonunion employees from coercive tactics
of unions, and such protection would hardly be provided if the
section applied only to organizational tactics. Also, it is clear
that Congress was much more concerned with nonviolent economic
coercion than with threats of physical violence. As Senator Ball,
who introduced the section, put it: "But we are less concerned here
with actual acts of violence than we are with threats. . . ."
[
Footnote 2/12] And Senator Taft
noted: "There are plenty of methods of coercion short of actual
physical violence." [
Footnote
2/13] Examples were given of cases where unions threatened to
double the dues of employees who waited until later to join.
[
Footnote 2/14] It is difficult
to see how fining a member is less coercive than doubling his dues,
or how the one is "within the ambit of internal union affairs" and
the other is not. After the bill was passed, in commenting on some
of the abuses it was designed to correct, Senator Wiley said there
are
"instances in which unions . . . have imposed fines upon their
members up to $20,000 because they crossed picket lines -- dared to
go to the place of employment. [
Footnote 2/15]"
Twice during the debate, Senator Taft emphatically stated that
the section guarantees employees who wished to work during a strike
the right to do so. [
Footnote
2/16] Though on neither occasion did he expressly
Page 388 U. S. 212
limit his examples to organizational strikes, the Court reads
them as having such a limited reference. [
Footnote 2/17] Once again, the Court utilizes
ambiguous, extemporaneous legislative comments to circumvent the
unambiguous language of a carefully drafted statute. Congress
certainly knew how to limit expressly the applicability of the
section to organizational coercion if it intended to do so.
[
Footnote 2/18]
The Court finds the strongest support for its position in
statements of Senator Ball when he accepted the proviso proposed by
Senator Holland. When Senator Holland observed,
"Apparently it is not intended by the sponsors of the amendment
to affect
at least that part of the internal
administration which has to do with the admission or the
expulsion of members, [
Footnote
2/19]"
Senator Ball replied, "It was never the intention of the
sponsors of the pending amendment to interfere with the internal
affairs or organization of unions." [
Footnote 2/20] From this statement by Senator Ball
accepting the proviso, the Court unjustifiably implies an intent to
broaden it. First, there is no reason to suppose that Senator Ball
was referring to any "part" of internal affairs other than that to
which Senator Holland had referred. Second, the sponsors of the
section repeatedly announced that it would protect union members
from their leaders, and that protection would be impossible if the
section did not to some extent interfere with the internal affairs
of unions. As Senator Wiley said,
"None of these provisions interferes
unduly with union
affairs,
except to the extent necessary to protect the
individual rights of employees. [
Footnote 2/21]"
Third, the Court recognizes -- without holding
Page 388 U. S. 213
-- that the section may protect union members from "arbitrary"
action of union leaders. However, it is difficult to understand how
the arbitrariness or nonarbitrariness of a fine determines whether
it is within the scope of "internal union affairs." [
Footnote 2/22]
What the Court does today is to write a new proviso to §
8(b)(1)(A):
"this paragraph shall not impair the right of a labor
organization nonarbitrarily to restrain or coerce its members in
their exercise of § 7 rights."
Nothing in the legislative history supports the creation of this
new proviso.
IV
The Court seeks further support for its holding by reference to
the fact that the 1959 Landrum-Griffin
Page 388 U. S. 214
amendments were "thought to be the first comprehensive
regulation by Congress of the conduct of internal union affairs."
And the Court thinks that to construe § 8(b)(1)(A) according to its
literal language to prohibit fines
"is to say that Congress preceded the Landrum-Griffin amendments
with an even more pervasive regulation of the internal affairs of
unions. [
Footnote 2/23]"
But again the Court fails to distinguish between court-enforced
fines and fines enforced by the traditional method of expulsion.
Although both kinds of fines are coercive, I have already indicated
that the proviso to § 8(b)(1)(A) may preserve the union's right to
impose fines which are enforceable only by expulsion, and that
expulsion was the common mode of enforcing fines at the time the
section was adopted. If one assumes that the only fines prohibited
by the section are court-enforced fines, then the section was not a
pervasive regulation of union internal affairs. If court
enforcement of fines is within the ambit of internal union affairs,
which I doubt, then those affairs were only incidentally regulated
by a flat prohibition of this seldom-used method of union
discipline. If the common forms of union discipline -- expulsion
and fines enforceable by expulsion -- were not prohibited or
regulated by Taft-Hartley, then Landrum-Griffin was indeed the
first comprehensive regulation of them.
V
The union here had a union security clause in its contract with
Allis-Chalmers. That clause made it necessary
Page 388 U. S. 215
for all employees, including the ones involved here, to pay dues
and fees to the union. But § 8(a)(3) and § 8(b)(2) make it clear
that "Congress intended to prevent utilization of union security
agreements for any purpose other than to compel payment of union
dues and fees."
Radio Officers' Union v. Labor Board,
347 U. S. 17,
347 U. S. 41. If
the union uses the union security clause to compel employees to pay
dues, characterizes such employees as members, and then uses such
membership as a basis for imposing court-enforced fines upon those
employees unwilling to participate in a union strike, then the
union security clause is being used for a purpose other than "to
compel payment of union dues and fees." It is being used to coerce
employees to join in union activity in violation of § 8(b)(2).
The Court suggests that this problem is not present here,
because the fined employees failed to prove they enjoyed other than
full union membership, that their role in the union was not, in
fact, limited to the obligation of paying dues. For several
reasons, I am unable to agree with the Court's approach. Few
employees forced to become "members" of the union by virtue of the
union security clause will be aware of the fact that they must
somehow "limit" their membership to avoid the union's
court-enforced fines. Even those who are brash enough to attempt to
do so may be unfamiliar with how to do it. Must they refrain from
doing anything but paying dues, or will signing the routine union
pledge still leave them with less than full membership? And
finally, it is clear that what restrains the employee from going to
work during a union strike is the union's threat that it will fine
him and collect the fine from him in court. How many employees in a
union shop whose names appear on the union's membership rolls will
be willing to ignore that threat in the hope that they will later
be able to convince the Labor Board or
Page 388 U. S. 216
the state court that they were not full members of the union? By
refusing to decide whether § 8(b)(1)(A) prohibits the union from
fining an employee who does nothing more than pay union dues as a
condition to retaining his job in a union shop, the Court adds
coercive impetus to the union's threat of fines. Today's decision
makes it highly dangerous for an employee in a union shop to
exercise his § 7 right to refrain from participating in a strike
called by a union in which he is a member in name only.
VI
The National Labor Relations Act, as originally passed and
amended from time to time, is the work product of draftsmen skilled
by long experience in labor affairs. These draftsmen thoroughly
understood labor legislation terminology, especially the oft-used
words "restrain or coerce." Sections 7 and 8 together bespeak a
strong purpose of Congress to leave workers wholly free to
determine in what concerted labor activities they will engage or
decline to engage. This freedom of workers to go their own way in
this field, completely unhampered by pressures of employers or
unions, is and always has been a basic purpose of the labor
legislation now under consideration. In my judgment, it ill
behooves this Court to strike so diligently to defeat this
unequivocally declared purpose of Congress merely because the Court
believes that too much freedom of choice for workers will impair
the effective power of unions.
Cf. Vaca v. Sipes,
386 U. S. 171,
386 U. S. 203
(dissenting opinion). A court-enforced fine is certainly coercive,
certainly affects the employee's job, and certainly is not a
traditional method of internal union discipline. When applied by a
union to an employee who has joined it as a condition of obtaining
employment in a union shop, it defeats the provisions of the Act
designed to prevent union security clauses
Page 388 U. S. 217
from being used for purposes other than to compel payment of
dues. In such a situation, it cannot be justified on any theory
that the employee has contracted away or waived his § 7 rights.
Where there is clear legislative history to justify it, courts
often decline to follow the literal meaning of a statute. But this
practice is fraught with dangers when the legislative history is,
at best, brief, inconclusive, and ambiguous. This is precisely such
a case, and I dissent because I am convinced that the Court has
ignored the literal language of § 8(b)(1)(A) in order to give
unions a power which the Court, but not Congress, thinks they
need.
[
Footnote 2/1]
Those members of the Senate who opposed § 8(b)(1)(A) shared the
Court's concern that it would impair the effectiveness of strikes.
To that concern, Senator Taft replied:
"I can see nothing in the pending measure which . . . would in
some way outlaw strikes. It would outlaw threats against employees.
It would not outlaw anybody striking who wanted to strike. It would
not prevent anyone using the strike in a legitimate way. . . . All
it would do would be to outlaw such restraint and coercion as would
prevent people from going to work if they wished to go to
work."
93 Cong.Rec. 4436, II Leg.Hist. 1207.
[
Footnote 2/2]
See generally Comment, 115 U.Pa.L.Rev. 47 (1966); 80
Harv.L.Rev. 683 (1967).
[
Footnote 2/3]
These authorities are cited at
n 9 of the Court's opinion. One of them notes that the
union's "discipline power has its own practical limitations" simply
because the union's ultimate sanction at that time was limited to
expulsion. Summers, Disciplinary Powers of Unions, 3
Ind.Lab.Rel.Rev. 483, 487 (1950). That practical limitation is
today removed by the Court's holding.
[
Footnote 2/4]
See, e.g., NLRB v. Bell Aircraft Corp., 206 F.2d 235
(collective bargaining agreement between employer and union
provided that employer could not promote employee who had
disciplinary charges pending against him by union).
[
Footnote 2/5]
See, e.g., Associated Home Builders of Greater Green
Bay, 145 N.L.R.B. 1775,
remanded on other grounds,
352 F.2d 745.
[
Footnote 2/6]
"The contract of membership is . . . a legal fabrication. . . .
What are the terms of the contract? The constitutional provisions,
particularly those governing discipline, are so notoriously vague
that they fall far short of the certainty ordinarily required of a
contract. The member has no choice as to terms, but is compelled to
adhere to the inflexible ones presented. Even then, the union is
not bound, for it retains the unlimited power to amend any term at
any time. . . . In short, membership is a special relationship. It
is as far removed from the main channel of contract law as the
relationships created by marriage. . . ."
Summers, Legal Limitations on Union Discipline, 64 Harv.L.Rev.
1049, 1055-1056 (1951).
[
Footnote 2/7]
Although the Court states that Congress was operating within the
context of the "contract theory," I have been unable to find any
reference to this theory in the legislative history, even by the
opponents to curtailing union power. When Senator Pepper suggested
that the section should not apply to union members because they
elect their own leaders, Senator Taft rejected that premise as a
frequent fiction.
See p.
388 U. S. 210,
infra.
[
Footnote 2/8]
Congress was, indeed, primarily concerned with the kind of
coercion state courts were unable to cope with. 93 Cong.Rec. 4016,
4024, II Leg.Hist. 1018, 1031.
[
Footnote 2/9]
93 Cong.Rec. 4021, II Leg.Hist. 1025.
See generally 93
Cong.Rec. 4432-4436, II Leg.Hist. 1199-1207.
[
Footnote 2/10]
93 Cong.Rec. 4016, II Leg.Hist. 1018; 93 Cong.Rec. 4021, II
Leg.Hist. 1025; 93 Cong.Rec. 4023, II Leg.Hist. 1028.
[
Footnote 2/11]
93 Cong.Rec. 4023, II Leg.Hist. 1029. Senator Taft merely
responded that the section protects nonunion employees as well as
union members.
[
Footnote 2/12]
93 Cong.Rec. 4017, II Leg.Hist. 1020.
[
Footnote 2/13]
93 Cong.Rec. 4024, II Leg.Hist. 1031.
[
Footnote 2/14]
93 Cong.Rec. 4017, II Leg.Hist. 1020; 93 Cong.Rec. 4433, II
Leg.Hist. 1200.
[
Footnote 2/15]
93 Cong.Rec. 5000, II Leg.Hist. 1471.
[
Footnote 2/16]
See 388
U.S. 175fn2/1|>n. 1,
supra; statement by Senator
Taft quoted in
n 25 of the
Court's opinion.
[
Footnote 2/17]
See n 25 of the
Court's opinion.
[
Footnote 2/18]
See, e.g., § 8(b)(4)(b)
[
Footnote 2/19]
93 Cong.Rec. 4271, II Leg.Hist. 1139 (emphasis added).
[
Footnote 2/20]
93 Cong.Rec. 4272, II Leg.Hist. 1141.
[
Footnote 2/21]
93 Cong.Rec. 5001, II Leg.Hist. 1472 (emphasis added).
[
Footnote 2/22]
The NLRB has itself recognized that a union "fine is, by nature,
coercive." In
Local 138, Operating Engineers, 148 N.L.R.B.
679, and
H. B. Roberts, Business Manager of Local 925,
Operating Engineers, 148 N.L.R.B. 674,
enforced, 121
U.S.App.D.C. 297, 350 F.2d 427, the Board held § 8(b)(1)(A)
prohibited a union from fining members who violated an internal
union rule against filing charges with the NLRB. The Board
concluded that
"the imposition of a fine by a labor organization upon a member
who files charges with the Board does restrain and coerce that
member in the exercise of his right to file charges. The union's
conduct is no less coercive where the filing of the charge is
alleged to be in conflict with an internal union rule or policy and
the fine is imposed allegedly to enforce that internal policy."
Local 138, 148 N.L.R.B. at 682. In the present case,
the Board distinguished
Local 138 and
Roberts on
the ground that the union rules involved there were "beyond the
competence of the union to enforce," and were "not the legitimate
concern of a union." 149 N.L.R.B. 67, 69. My Brother WHITE seems to
take a similar position in resting his concurrence on the Court's
holding that the union rule against crossing a picket line is
"valid." But neither Congress' aim in § 8(b)(1)(A) of proscribing
certain means used to accomplish legitimate ends nor the Court's
view that Congress intended no interference with internal union
affairs would allow the application of the section to depend on the
Board's or this Court's views of whether a particular internal
union rule is "valid" or not.
[
Footnote 2/23]
Although the Landrum-Griffin Act might be resorted to for the
purpose of determining the limits of "vague language" in the
Taft-Hartley Act, it should not be used, as the Court here uses it,
to deprive employees of rights unequivocally granted them by the
earlier Act. Section 103 of the Landrum-Griffin Act, 73 State, 523
(1959), 29 U.S.C. § 413, expressly provides: "Nothing contained in
this title shall limit the rights and remedies of any member of a
labor organization under any . . . Federal law. . . ."