The Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) brought proceedings
under § 11(b)(1) of the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935
to determine the extent to which respondent New England Electric
System (NEES), a holding company registered under § 5, could
lawfully retain control over its electric, gas, and other
properties. The SEC held that NEES' subsidiaries supplying
electricity to retail customers in four New England States composed
an "integrated electric utility system," and both the SEC and NEES
agree that its gas utility subsidiaries serving retail customers in
Massachusetts constitute an "integrated gas utility system" under
the Act. The SEC, after hearing, ordered divestment of Nees' gas
utilities under § 11(b)(1)(A), which limits a holding company
system to a single integrated public utility system unless the SEC
finds,
inter alia, that an additional system cannot be
operated independently "without the loss of substantial economies."
Construing that provision to require a showing that the additional
system cannot be operated under separate ownership without the loss
of economies so important as to cause a serious impairment of that
system, the SEC found that the gas companies could be economically
operated independently of NEES, and that any losses of economies
would be offset by the benefits from competition between the
independently controlled gas and electric companies. The Court of
Appeals reversed, interpreting "loss of substantial economies" to
be satisfied by "a business judgment of what would be a significant
loss."
Held: the SEC was warranted in ruling that the Act
prohibits a public utility holding company from retaining an
integrated gas utility system in addition to its integrated
electric utility system unless the gas utility system sought to be
retained could not be soundly and economically operated
independently of the principal system. Pp.
384 U. S.
179-185.
(a) The "single integrated" public utility system requirement,
as the legislative history shows, is the heart of the Act,
retention of an additional system being the decided exception, and
the SEC has consistently adhered to that view. Pp.
384 U. S.
180-182.
Page 384 U. S. 177
(b) Control by a single holding company of both gas and electric
companies was one of the anticompetitive evils at which the Act was
aimed. P.
384 U. S.
183.
(c) Though competitive advantage from separating the gas system
from the principal holding company system are hard to forecast, it
is for the SEC, which has expertise on the total competitive
situation and has the task of practically applying an intricate
statutory scheme, to gauge whether the gains to competition through
separation are in the public interest and might offset the
estimated loss in economies of operation. Pp.
384 U. S.
184-185.
346 F.2d 399 reversed and remanded.
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS delivered the opinion of the Court.
New England Electric System (NEES) is a holding company
registered under § 5 of the Public Utility Holding Company Act of
1935. [
Footnote 1] Its holdings
include both electric and gas utility properties. The electric
companies serve retail customers in New Hampshire, Massachusetts,
Rhode Island, and Connecticut. The gas companies serve retail
customers in Massachusetts alone. [
Footnote 2] The Commission, proceeding under § 11 of the
Act, [
Footnote 3] held that the
electric utility subsidiaries of NEES constituted an "integrated
electric utility system" as defined in
Page 384 U. S. 178
§ 2(a)(29)(A). [
Footnote 4]
38 S.E.C. 193. The question in this case does not concern these
electric utility subsidiaries, but only the gas utility
subsidiaries of NEES, which both NEES and the Commission agree
constitute an "integrated gas utility system" within the meaning of
§ 2(a)(29)(B) of the Act. [
Footnote
5]
By § 11(b)(1), [
Footnote 6]
a holding company system is to be limited in operations by the
Commission "to a single integrated public utility system,"
[
Footnote 7] provided, however,
that it may be permitted to control one or more additional
Page 384 U. S. 179
"integrated public utility systems" if the Commission finds,
inter alia, that
"[e]ach of such additional system cannot be operated as an
independent system
without the loss of substantial
economies which can be secured by the retention of control by
such holding company of such system."
§ 11(b)(1)(A). (Italics supplied.) It is on the meaning of this
proviso that the present controversy depends. The Commission found
that divestment of NEES' gas utilities would not result in a "loss
of substantial economies" to these companies within the meaning of
§ 11(b)(1)(A). It construed Clause (A) to require a showing that
the
"additional system cannot be operated under separate ownership
without the loss of economies so important as to cause a serious
impairment of that system."
The Commission ruled that it was unable "to find that the gas
companies could not be soundly and economically operated
independently of NEES." It found that any losses of economies would
be offset by the benefits that would flow from the healthy
competition between the independently controlled gas and electric
companies, promotion of competition between gas utilities and
electric utilities being an important purpose of the Act.
Accordingly, it ordered that the gas utilities be divested.
On petition for review, the Court of Appeals reversed on the
ground that the Commission had misinterpreted the statutory phrase
"loss of substantial economies." 346 F.2d 399. The court held that
Clause (A) "called for a business judgment of what would be a
significant loss, not for a finding of total loss of economy or
efficiency" (346 F.2d at 406), and, believing that, on this record
and with the statute so interpreted, there could have been a
finding in favor of NEES, remanded the case to the Commission. We
granted certiorari, 382 U.S. 953.
We agree with the Commission's reading of Clause (A), and remand
the cause to the Court of Appeals so that
Page 384 U. S. 180
there may be a review of the challenged order in light of the
proper meaning of the statutory term.
The requirement in § 11 of a "single integrated" system is the
"very heart" of the Act. [
Footnote
8] The retention of an "additional" integrated system is
decidedly the exception. [
Footnote
9] As originally passed by the Senate, § 11 would have limited
all registered holding companies to a single "geographically and
economically integrated public utility system." [
Footnote 10] The House version differed, in
that it permitted the Commission to make exceptions where
limitation of the operations of the holding company was not found
to be "in the public interest." [
Footnote 11] The version with which we deal emerged from
a conference committee. The scope of the exception as it appears in
the bill's final form was thus explained to the House:
"Section 11 of both bills [
i.e., the House and Senate
versions], therefore, authorizes the Securities and Exchange
Commission to require a holding company to limit its control over
operating utility companies to
one integrated public utility
system."
"
* * * *"
"The conference substitute meets the House desire to provide for
further flexibility by the statement of additional definite and
concrete circumstances under which exception should be made to the
form of one integrated system. . . ."
"The substitute, therefore, makes provision to meet the
situation where a holding company
can
Page 384 U. S. 181
show a real economic need on the part of additional
integrated systems for permitting the holding company to keep these
additional systems. . . ."
H.R.Rep.No. 1903, 74th Cong., 1st Sess., 70-71. (Italics
supplied.)
Additional light is shed on the purpose of § 11 by the remarks
of Senator Wheeler, a member of the conference committee:
"Since both bills accepted the proposition that a holding
company should normally be limited to one integrated system, my
colleagues and I conceived it to be our task to find what concrete
exceptions, if any, could be made to this rule that would satisfy
the demand of the House for some greater flexibility. After
considerable discussion, the Senate conferees concluded that the
furthest concession they could make would be to permit the
Commission to allow a holding company to control more than one
integrated system if [among other tests] the additional systems
were in the same region as the principal system and were so small
that they were
incapable of independent economical
operation. . . ."
79 Cong.Rec. 14479. (Italics supplied.) As the Commission said
in 1948:
"The legislative history of Section 11(b)(1) indicates that it
was the intent of Congress to create only a limited exception to
the general rule confining holding companies to a single system,
and that this exception was created to deal with the situation in
which the proven inability of the additional system to stand by
itself would result in substantial hardship to investors and
consumers were its relationship with the holding company
terminated."
Philadelphia Co., 28 S.E.C. 35, 46.
Page 384 U. S. 182
While the Commission has variously phrased the rule, it has
consistently adhered to that view. [
Footnote 12]
This suggests a much more stringent test than "a business
judgment of what would be a significant loss," to quote the Court
of Appeals. 346 F.2d at 406. Promotion of "economy of management
and operation" and "the integration and coordination of
related operating properties" (§ 1(b)(4), 49 Stat. 804, 15
U.S.C. § 79a(b)(4)
Page 384 U. S. 183
(italics supplied)) is a theme that runs throughout the Act. But
so does the theme of elimination of "restraint of free and
independent competition." [
Footnote 13] § 1(b)(2), 49 Stat. 803-804, 15 U.S.C. §
79a(b)(2). One of the evils that had resulted from control of
utilities by holding companies was the retention in one system of
both gas and electric properties and the favoring of one of these
competing forms of energy over the other. [
Footnote 14]
Page 384 U. S. 184
In the present case, the Commission said on this phase of the
controversy:
"Although the NEES Gas Division handles sales and promotional
activities and various other matters for the gas subsidiaries
separately from the electric companies, final authority on all
important matters rests in the top NEES management. The basic
competitive position that exists between gas and electric utility
service within the same locality is affected by such vital
management decisions as the amount of funds to be raised for or
allocated to the expansion or promotion of each type of service.
[
Footnote 15]"
Competitive advantages to be gained by a separation are
difficult to forecast. The gains to competition might
Page 384 U. S. 185
well be in the public interest, and might well offset the
estimated loss in economies of operation [
Footnote 16] resulting from a separation of the gas
properties from the utility system. This is a matter for Commission
expertise on the total competitive situation, not merely
on a prediction whether, for example, a gas company in a holding
company system may make more for investors than a gas company
converted into an independent regime.
The phrase "without the loss of substantial economies" is
admittedly not crystal clear. But the Commission's construction
seems to us to be well within the permissible range given to those
who are charged with the task of giving an intricate statutory
scheme practical sense and application.
Power Reactor Co. v.
Electricians, 367 U. S. 396,
367 U. S. 408.
And see Philadelphia Co. v. SEC, 85 U.S.App.DC. 327, 177
F.2d 720, 725.
Reversed and remanded.
[
Footnote 1]
49 Stat. 812, 15 U.S.C. § 79e (1964 ed.).
[
Footnote 2]
NEES, the electric companies, and the gas companies are all
parties respondent, and are hereafter referred to as
respondent.
[
Footnote 3]
49 Stat. 820, 15 U.S.C. § 79k (1964 ed.).
[
Footnote 4]
49 Stat. 810, 15 U.S.C. § 79b(2)(29)(A) (1964 ed.). An
"integrated public utility system," as applied to electric utility
companies, is defined by § 2(a)(29)(A) as
"a system consisting of one or more units of generating plants
and/or transmission lines and/or distributing facilities, whose
utility assets, whether owned by one or more electric utility
companies, are physically interconnected or capable of physical
interconnection and which under normal conditions may be
economically operated as a single interconnected and coordinated
system confined in its operations of a single area or region, in
one or more States, not so large as to impair (considering the
state of the art and the area or region affected) the advantages of
localized management, efficient operation, and the effectiveness of
regulation."
[
Footnote 5]
49 Stat. 810, 15 U.S.C. § 79b(a)(29)(B) (1964 ed.). An
"integrated public utility system," as applied to gas utility
companies, is defined by § 2(a)(29)(B) as
"a system consisting of one or more gas utility companies which
are so located and related that substantial economies may be
effectuated by being operated as a single coordinated system
confined in its operations to a single area or region, in one or
more States, not so large as to impair (considering the state of
the art and the area or region affected) the advantages of
localized management, efficient operation, and the effectiveness of
regulation."
[
Footnote 6]
49 Stat. 820, 15 U.S.C. § 79k(b)(1) (1964 ed.).
[
Footnote 7]
The Commission has long held that a single "integrated public
utility system" cannot include both gas and electric properties.
See Columbia Gas & Electric Corp., 8 S.E.C. 443,
462-463;
The United Gas Improvement Co., 9 S.E.C. 52,
77-83;
Philadelphia Co., 28 S.E.C. 35, 44. Respondent does
not contest this aspect of the Commission's reading of the Act.
[
Footnote 8]
North American Co. v. SEC, 327 U.
S. 686,
327 U. S. 704,
n. 14; S.Rep. No. 621, 74th Cong., 1st Sess., 11.
[
Footnote 9]
North American Co. v. SEC, supra, at
327 U. S.
696-697.
[
Footnote 10]
S. 2796, § 11(b), 74th Cong., 1st Sess.
And see S.Rep.
No. 621, 74th Cong., 1st Sess., 32.
[
Footnote 11]
S. 2796, § 11(b), as passed by the House of Representatives and
sent to the Senate on July 9, 1935.
And see H.R.Rep. No.
1318, 74th Cong., 1st Sess., 17.
[
Footnote 12]
Respondent concedes that the Commission has, since 1948,
"articulated" a test "like the present test."
See Philadelphia
Co., 28 S.E.C. 35, 46-47, 53-74;
General Public Utilities
Corp., 32 S.E.C. 807, 814-815, 826-827, 831;
Middle South
Utilities, Inc., 35 S.E.C. 1, 11-13. Respondent contends,
however, that previous decisions of the Commission applied a less
restrictive standard of "substantial economies." The Commission
disagrees, urging that, while there was "some variation in choice
of words," it has maintained a basically consistent position, and
that any semantic differences are due largely to "the varying
contentions with which the Commission was dealing." The cases
referred to are
North American Co., 11 S.E.C. 194,
208-213;
Engineers Public Service Co., 12 S.E.C. 41;
Cities Service Power & Light Co., 14 S.E.C. 28, 37;
Middle West Corp., 15 S.E.C. 309, 319;
Cities Service
Co., 15 S.E.C. 962, 984;
American Gas & Electric
Co., 21 S.E.C. 575, 596-597. We do not read those cases as
being inconsistent with the Commission's position since 1948. In
each of these cases, the Commission found no showing of
"substantial economies" under whatever test might be applied; thus,
it was not there compelled to go further. There are, to be sure, a
few cases in which the Commission permitted retention of small
additional systems on the ground that the requirements of §
11(b)(1) were met; in these, however, the Commission did not
articulate any standard.
See, e.g., Federal Light &
Traction Co., 15 S.E.C. 675, 683;
Republic Service
Corp., 23 S.E.C. 436, 451.
But cf. North American
Co., 11 S.E.C. 194, 243-244.
We cannot say that these early decisions show any clear
inconsistency with the standard which the Commission today applies,
and has applied since 1948. Under these circumstances, we feel
justified in regarding the Commission's reading of the statute as
supported by consistent administrative practice.
[
Footnote 13]
Section 1(b) provides
". . . [I]t is hereby declared that the national public
interest, the interest of investors in the securities of holding
companies and their subsidiary companies and affiliates, and the
interest of consumers of electric energy and natural and
manufactured gas, are or may be adversely affected . . . (2) when
subsidiary public utility companies are subjected to excessive
charges for services, construction work, equipment, and materials,
or enter into transactions in which evils result from an absence of
arm's-length bargaining
or from restraint of free and
independent competition; . . . "
(Italics supplied.)
[
Footnote 14]
See S.Rep. No. 621, 74th Cong., 1st Sess., 29; Report
of National Power Policy Committee, H.R.Doc. No. 137, 74th Cong.,
1st Sess., 10 (Appendix to S.Rep. No. 621, 74th Cong., 1st
Sess.).
Congress was well aware of the anticompetitive potential of
corporate structures through which control of gas and electric
utility companies rests under the umbrella of a single holding
company. That a holding company so situated might retard expansion
of the gas utility company in favor of the electric utility company
was expressly discussed in the Senate Hearings on an earlier
version of the Act.
See Hearings before the Senate
Committee on Interstate Commerce on S. 1725, 74th Cong., 1st Sess.,
783.
Congress made specific provision in § 8 of the Act to prohibit a
registered holding company from acquiring an interest in both an
electric and a gas utility serving the same territory, in a State
which prohibits common control, without first obtaining permission
from the appropriate state regulatory agency. While § 8 reflects
the concern of Congress with this aspect of competition
(
see S.Rep. No. 621,
supra at 29-30; Report of
National Power Policy Committee,
supra, at 10), there is
no warrant for concluding that § 8 was the exclusive legislative
effort relating to the problem. The history of the Act reflects the
presence of a sophisticated statutory scheme. To some extent, local
policy was expected to govern, with § 8 serving to prevent
circumvention of that policy by use of the "extra-State device of a
holding company." S.Rep. No. 621,
supra, at 29-30. At the
same time, § 11 was expected to assist in imposing restrictions
with regard to the combination of gas and electricity in one
system. Discussing the interplay between § 8 and § 11, the Senate
Committee noted that § 8 only applied to future acquisitions:
"The committee felt that, while the
policy upon which this
section was based was essential in the formulation of any Federal
legislation on utility holding companies, it did not think
that the section should make it unlawful to retain (
up to the
time that section 11 may require divestment) interests in
businesses in which the companies were lawfully engaged on the date
of the enactment of the title."
Id. at 7. (Italics supplied.)
[
Footnote 15]
By fostering competition between gas and electric utility
companies, the Act promotes what has been described as "variegated
competition." Hearings before the Subcommittee on Antitrust and
Monopoly of the Senate Committee on the Judiciary, 89th Cong., 1st
Sess., pt. 2, 840 (1965) (statement of Dr. Samuel M. Loescher).
"But since the distribution of electricity, following
geographical divorcements, was to remain a natural monopoly in
every region, the only kind of competition to be enhanced was that
of 'variegated competition.'"
Ibid.
[
Footnote 16]
See, e.g., Hearings before House Committee on
Interstate and Foreign Commerce on H.R. 5423, 74th Cong., 1st
Sess., 1249, 1402-1403, 1530-1531, 2257-2277; Hearings before
Senate Committee on Interstate Commerce on S. 1725, 74th Cong., 1st
Sess., 65. It was only the loss of "substantial economies" that
Congress thought would justify an exception from the separation
rule of § 11.
MR. JUSTICE HARLAN, whom MR. JUSTICE STEWART joins,
dissenting.
The question before the Court is the meaning of the phrase "loss
of substantial economies" as it appears in § 11(b)(1) of the Public
Utility Holding Company Act of 1935. [
Footnote 2/1] The Court of Appeals ruled that the
phrase
Page 384 U. S. 186
"called for a business judgment of what would be a significant
loss," 346 F.2d at 406, and I agree with this rendering, which is
both sensible and, in my view, obvious. This Court's opinion, on
the other hand, seems to hold that the phrase demands a loss great
enough to imperil "sound" corporate operations. [
Footnote 2/2] That holding, as I shall indicate, is
at odds with the Act's wording, has little basis in legitimate
statutory history or the aims of the Act, and cannot be sustained
by agency or judicial precedent.
Inquiry naturally begins with the language of the Act, and with
our reiterated principle that "the words of statutes . . . should
be interpreted where possible in their ordinary, everyday senses."
Crane v. Commissioner, 331 U. S. 1,
331 U. S. 6;
Malat v. Riddell, 383 U. S. 569,
383 U. S. 571.
In this instance, plainly the normal meaning of "substantial
economies" is a significant amount of money, and not that amount,
whatever its size, which guarantees corporate survival. The first
reading would be given by lawyers and laymen alike automatically,
while the second could hardly be imagined without the prompting of
persuasive legislative evidence. If Congress had intended the
Court's test to govern, it could easily have said so in
Page 384 U. S. 187
shorter space and with far greater precision. [
Footnote 2/3] In addition, the Court's decision
will apparently result in "substantial economies" being read its
way in § 11(b)(1) but in a quite different, more normal fashion
where the same phrase appears in § 2(a)(29)(B), defining an
integrated gas utility system (
see ante, n 4, of the Court's opinion). None of this is
to say that the many subtle choices to be made in deciding what is
a substantial sum in the present context are dictated by the terse
language of the Act.
See infra, 384
U.S. 176fn2/11|>n. 11. The choice here, however, is between
two broad approaches, and the Act's language invites the first and
repels the second.
If the natural reading produced some strange or arbitrary
result, there might be reason to hesitate; but, in this case, the
literal reading makes excellent sense in serving the very rational
and desirable end of financial economy. The Congress that passed
the Act had been importantly concerned with the "intensification of
economic power beyond the point of proved economies. . . ."
H.R.Doc. No. 137, 74th Cong., 1st Sess., 4;
see §§
1(b)(4), (5) of the Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 79a(b)(4), (5) (1964 ed.)
(policy statement), and the Act itself bristles with provisions
aimed largely at attaining efficient management and operations.
See §§ 7(d)(3), 10(c)(2), 12(d), (f), (g), 13, 15 U.S.C.
§§ 79g(d)(3), 79j(c)(2), 79l(d), (f), (g), 79m (1964 ed.). With
this background, nothing could be more plausible than to curtail
divestiture at the point where the prospect of substantial losses
removed a prime reason for having divestiture at all. There are to
be sure other dangers in proliferated growth besides
diseconomy,
Page 384 U. S. 188
dangers which played their part in the passage of the Act, but
there are also other clauses of § 11(b)(1) whose conditions must be
met before the exception is allowed (
see supra, 384
U.S. 176fn2/1|>n. 1). In sum, it seems clear enough that the
burden of persuasion rests upon those who would displace the Court
of Appeals' interpretation. [
Footnote
2/4]
Legislative history and purpose, heavily relied on by the Court,
furnish no reason for departing from the natural reading of the
Act. There was very little direct explanation of the "substantial
economies" provision in Congress; the majority opinion sets out in
full the two important statements, one by the House Conference
Committee (
ante, p.
384 U. S.
180-181) and the other by Senator Wheeler
(
ante, p.
384 U. S.
181). [
Footnote 2/5] The
Committee Report, highly authoritative but unilluminating, says
merely that there must be "a real economic need" to justify
retention of an additional system. Indisputably, substantial
savings can be labeled a real economic need, the more so since
Congress was sharply concerned with the lack of economic
justification for many utility combinations. That the Committee's
language is also compatible with the SEC's reading of "substantial
economies" does no more than make that language a useless
guidepost.
Senator Wheeler's statement, by contrast, does support, if
indeed it is not the source of, the SEC interpretation, and
normally the view of a principal sponsor of
Page 384 U. S. 189
an Act carries heavy weight. Here, however, Senator Wheeler made
his remarks after the bill had finally passed both Houses, and,
quite arguably,
"[t]he views of individual members of the legislature as to the
meaning of a statute which were not officially communicated to the
legislature prior to its enactment are not competent to be
considered in determining the meaning which ought to be attributed
to the statute."
Hart & Sacks, The Legal Process 1285 (tent. ed. 1958,
Harvard Univ.). Moreover, in this instance, Senator Wheeler had
been a fierce opponent of allowing any exception at all to the
one-system principle,
see 346 F.2d at 403, and had
excellent reason to minimize severely the scope of the present
provision when to do so could no longer cost the Act votes. The SEC
itself, in its early days, before the elevation of the Wheeler
statement to its present exaggerated importance, took a far more
guarded view of its worth. [
Footnote
2/6]
To support its construction of the "substantial economies"
provision, the Court also relies on two general policies attributed
to the Act as a whole. It is initially emphasized that the Act's
overriding aim was to confine holding companies to a single
integrated system while control of additional systems was to be
"decidedly the exception" (
ante, p.
384 U. S.
180). The mild but misleading inference is that the
"exception" is some minor, little noticed addendum, to be strictly
construed. In truth, the original, more stringent version of § 11,
popularly known as
Page 384 U. S. 190
the "death sentence" provision, was bitterly opposed, and the
"ABC" clauses exception with Clause A of which we now deal
(
supra, 384
U.S. 176fn2/1|>n. 1) was adopted as a considered compromise
between quite different House and Senate versions.
See
Ritchie, Integration of Public Utility Holding Companies 16-19, 151
(1954). The ABC clauses represent part of the price openly paid for
enactment, and there is no basis in these events for a grudging
interpretation. [
Footnote 2/7]
Far more weight is given by the Court's opinion to the Act's
supposed hostility toward common control of gas and electric
utility systems, with its danger of stifled competition. First of
all, this hostility appears to be an illusion. The House and Senate
Committees in identical language expressly stated that common
ownership of competing forms of energy was "a field which is
essentially a question of State policy"; the present § 8, 15 U.S.C.
§ 79h (1964 ed.), was enacted to support this approach by using
federal power to limit common ownership only where it is contrary
to state law.
See S.Rep.No. 621, 74th Cong., 1st Sess.,
29-30; H.R.Rep.No. 1318, 74th Cong., 1st Sess., 14-15. [
Footnote 2/8] In its decision in this
Page 384 U. S. 191
very case, the SEC stated: "We do not take the view that the Act
expresses a federal policy against combined gas and electric
operations as such." Holding Company Act Release No. 15035, p. 15.
This was apparently so clear at the time the Act passed that, in an
early and now-repudiated decision, the SEC went so far as to hold
that gas and electric companies could be combined in the same
single integrated public utility system.
American Water Works
& Elec. Co., 2 S.E.C. 972 (1937).
Furthermore, a constricted reading of the "substantial
economies" provision is a quite unsuitable way of responding to the
dangers in common ownership of competing types of utilities. The
provision is equally intended to govern common control of two or
more gas systems or two or more electric systems, and at least in
the abstract, the Court's reading will hinder those arrangements as
well, though its rationale is irrelevant to them. If the SEC is
prepared to show that freeing a gas system from control by an
electric system will improve earnings by some amount, then this may
be a legitimate offset to the losses that can be shown, and there
is leeway for rough calculations and for estimates based on
studying past separations.
See Ritchie, Integration of
Public Utility Holding Companies 143-147 (1954). But to dispense
with proof and disregard the basic test of "substantial economies"
is to undo Congress' own careful compromise of the various
conflicting policy interests. [
Footnote
2/9]
Page 384 U. S. 192
There remains to be answered only the Court's claim that its
reading of the statute is "supported by consistent administrative
practice" (
ante, p.
384 U. S. 182,
n. 12). Analysis of the SEC decisions shows that the Court is
mistaken. The first important construction of "substantial
economies" came in
North American Co., 11 S.E.C. 194,
decided in 1942 only seven years after the Act took effect.
Rejecting the assertion that any saving beyond a wholly nominal one
would do, the SEC stated:
"The normal and usual meaning of the word 'substantial' is a
meaning connoting 'important.' And we think that this normal and
usual meaning is compelled here."
Id. at 209. At least four subsequent decisions cite
North American and adopt its "importance" test, a natural
reading of the Act, rather the unusual and specialized one adopted
today.
Cities Serv. Power & Light Co., 14 S.E.C. 28,
37 (1943);
Middle West Corp., 15 S.E.C. 309, 319 (1944);
Cities Serv. Co., 15 S.E.C. 962, 984 (1944);
American
Gas & Elec. Co., 21 S.E.C. 575, 597 (1945). Also during
this first decade of the Act's enforcement, two decisions,
including one just cited, said that inability to operate
independently was "one of the guides which (among others) Congress
intended to be used. . . ."
Cities Serv. Power & Light
Co., 14 S.E.C. 28, 62 (1943);
Commonwealth & Southern
Corp., 26 S.E.C. 464, 489 (1947). In one other case, the SEC
stated the loss must be one which would "seriously impair . . .
effective operations."
Engineers Pub. Serv. Co., 12 S.E.C.
41, 61 (1942).
Page 384 U. S. 193
The majority opinion says that the respondent "concedes" that
the Commission has, since 1948, articulated its present test, and
three SEC decisions are then cited (
ante, p.
384 U. S. 182,
n 12). But, with the
Engineers case just cited as a possible addition, these
are the only three decisions until the present one to state the
Court's test out of the 15 or more decisions applying § 11(b)(1),
taking the ones already mentioned with those that established no
test. Furthermore, the respondent asserts that the three SEC
decisions stating its present test involved a very small percentage
of the assets it has ordered divested, and, even in those three
cases, it is not clear that the test was determinative. Brief, pp.
47-48. In sum, whether or not the SEC's early decisions may be said
actually to refute the test now urged, certainly there is no
consistent administrative practice lending it any real weight.
Before leaving precedent, it should also be noted that the First
and Fifth Circuits have squarely rejected the SEC's present
interpretation, and that the Second Circuit has approved its
"importance" gloss, while only the District of Columbia Circuit has
upheld the present reading. [
Footnote
2/10]
To conclude, I think it should be noted that the Court's
departure from the statute is not just an abstract legal error, but
does immediate, tangible harm in a most practical sense. The annual
losses which respondent has forecast for its gas system because of
separation exceed
Page 384 U. S. 194
$1,000,000, a figure the SEC has questioned in part, but not yet
properly considered. The respondent's analysis also shows annual
losses of $800,000 for the electrical system, although the SEC
deems irrelevant losses to the primary system, and the Court of
Appeals did not reach this issue. The heavy losses in this case
will presumably be borne by investors and consumers if the figures
are accurate and separation occurs; it is noteworthy that the
Massachusetts Department of Public Utilities appeared at the
hearings in this case to oppose divestiture. The SEC has wide
latitude in deciding how to gauge and compute "substantial
economies" and it has used that freedom in the past. [
Footnote 2/11] What the Commission has no
right to do, however, is to substitute to the detriment of business
interests and the public alike a quite different standard for the
one enacted by Congress. Neither does this Court have that right. I
would affirm the Court of Appeals' well considered decision.
[
Footnote 2/1]
49 Stat. 820, 15 U.S.C. § 79k(b)(1). This subsection provides
that a holding company shall be limited to "a single integrated
public utility system,"
"provided that the Commission shall permit control of additional
systems if:"
"(A) Each of such additional systems cannot be operated as an
independent system without the loss of substantial economies which
can be secured by the retention of control by such holding company
of such system;"
"(B) All of such additional systems are located in one State, or
in adjoining States, or in a contiguous foreign country; and"
"(C) The continued combination of such systems under the control
of such holding company is not so large (considering the state of
the art and the area or region affected) as to impair the
advantages of localized management, efficient operation, or the
effectiveness of regulation."
[
Footnote 2/2]
I say "seems" to hold both because two statements in the opinion
(
ante, pp. 1
384 U. S. 79,
384 U. S.
184-185) emphasize a supposed offsetting economic saving
to be found in divestiture, and because the SEC has stated the test
in this case in varying terms.
[
Footnote 2/3]
This could in fact have been accomplished simply by chopping off
the last half of the present, controlling clause (
supra,
384
U.S. 176fn2/1|>n. 1), leaving the condition to read "[e]ach
of such additional systems cannot be operated as an independent
system" and omitting wholly the qualifying language which begins
"without the loss of substantial economies."
[
Footnote 2/4]
"It . . . [is] wrong to deny the natural meaning of language its
proper primacy; like Cardozo's 'Method of Philosophy,' it 'is the
heir presumptive. A pretender to the title will have to fight his
way.'"
Friendly, Mr. Justice Frankfurter and the Reading of Statutes,
in Felix Frankfurter: The Judge 40 (1964).
[
Footnote 2/5]
One other legislative comment on the provision favors the
Commission, 79 Cong.Rec. 14165-16166 (remarks of Mr. Cooper), but
the Court of Appeals properly disregarded it as an opponent's
attempt to blacken the Act,
cf. Labor Board v. Fruit
Packers, 377 U. S. 58,
377 U. S. 66,
and the SEC no longer relies upon it in its brief.
[
Footnote 2/6]
The statement was quoted as cumulative, minor evidence on
another matter in 1941, the SEC admitting that it "may not strictly
be considered part of the legislative history," but saying it
deserved "some consideration."
Engineers Pub. Serv. Co., 9
S.E.C. 764, 782-783. In 1942, it was quoted as bearing on the
present question, but its test was not adopted.
North American
Co., 11 S.E.C. 194, 209. The following year, the statement was
thought to reveal "one" of the various criteria to be used along
with others.
Cities Serv. Power & Light Co., 14 S.E.C.
28, 62.
[
Footnote 2/7]
For its "decidedly the exception" characterization, the Court
cites (
ante, p.
384 U. S. 180,
n 9)
North American Co. v.
SEC, 327 U. S. 686.
That decision imparted no such gloss to the ABC clauses, but gave a
most cursory summary in passing on the constitutionality of §
11(b)(1).
[
Footnote 2/8]
The Court's opinion (
ante, p.
384 U. S. 184,
n. 14) quotes from p. 7 of the above-cited Senate report, borrowing
from its language that suggests § 11 was forwarding the same policy
as § 8. What the Court overlooks is that this discussion was
directed to an earlier and very different version of § 8, in which
it also embodied other restrictions on holding company ownership
having nothing to do with common control of gas and electricity,
but closely related to § 11's policy of federally imposed
simplification. A reading of the Court's quotation in context along
with the relevant version of S. 2796, 74th Cong., 1st Sess., §§ 8,
11 (as reported on May 13, 1935), will quickly show that its
reliance is misplaced. The majority's other citations in the same
footnote are also infirm. The first two citations are statements on
behalf of the rule that is now § 8, which allows the States to
decide the issue. The remaining citation to the Senate Hearings
does indeed reveal one Senator's general concern with common
ownership's impact on competition; the respondent states it is "the
only such reference in the entire Senate hearing." Brief, p. 37, n.
45.
[
Footnote 2/9]
It should again be remembered also that the present provision is
not the only legislative safeguard. Even to obtain ownership over
two systems, a holding company must, along with proving
"substantial economies," show that there is geographical unity, and
that the combination is not so large as to impair "the advantages
of localized management, efficient operation, or the effectiveness
of regulation" (
supra, 384
U.S. 176fn2/1|>n. 1). Section 8 (
supra, p.
384 U. S. 190)
acts as a further restraint in some cases. Other sections of the
Act regulate transactions between utility companies and require
disclosure of reports and maintenance of accounting data and other
records. §§ 12(f) 13(a), 14, 15, 15 U.S.C. §§ 79l(f), 79m(a), 79n,
79
o (1964 ed.).
[
Footnote 2/10]
The Fifth Circuit case is
Louisiana Pub. Serv. Comm'n v.
SEC, 235 F.2d 167. It was reversed here on jurisdictional
grounds,
353 U. S. 368,
which does not, of course, impair statement on the merits. The
Second Circuit decision is
North American Co. v. SEC, 133
F.2d 148,
aff'd on constitutional questions,
327 U.
S. 686. The District of Columbia decision is
Philadelphia Co. v. SEC, 85 U.S.App.D.C. 327, 177 F.2d
720; that court thought it was following its earlier two-to-one
decision in
Engineers Pub. Serv. Co. v. SEC, 78
U.S.App.D.C. 199, 138 F.2d 936,
cert. granted, 322 U.S.
723,
vacated as moot, 332 U.S. 788, but
Engineers
is ambiguous.
[
Footnote 2/11]
Among examples -- and I do not mean to approve or disapprove the
ones I cite -- are SEC rulings that, as noted, it will not consider
losses to the principal system,
General Pub. Utils. Corp.,
32 S.E.C. 807, 838-839 (1951); that it will not consider tax losses
as a very significant factor,
Cities Serv. Co., 15 S.E.C.
962, 985 (1944); that it will give only limited weight to capital
costs of divestiture,
Eastern Utils. Associates, 31 S.E.C.
329, 349 (1950); and that it will offset predicted gains resulting
from separation against the losses,
North American Co., 18
S.E.C. 611 (1945).