Consumer Financial Protection Bureau v. Community Financial Services Assn. of America, Ltd., 601 U.S. ___ (2024)

Docket No. 22-448
Granted: February 27, 2023
Argued: October 3, 2023
Decided: May 16, 2024
Justia Summary

The case involves the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) and its funding mechanism. The CFPB, unlike most federal agencies, has a standing source of funding outside the ordinary annual appropriations process. Congress authorized the CFPB to draw from the Federal Reserve System an amount that its Director deems “reasonably necessary to carry out” the Bureau’s duties, subject only to an inflation-adjusted cap. Several trade associations representing payday lenders and credit-access businesses challenged this funding mechanism, arguing that it violates the Appropriations Clause of the Constitution.


Annotation
Primary Holding

Statutory authorization allowing the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau to draw money from the earnings of the Federal Reserve System to carry out the Bureau’s duties satisfied the Appropriations Clause.


Syllabus

NOTE: Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued. The syllabus constitutes no part of the opinion of the Court but has been prepared by the Reporter of Decisions for the convenience of the reader. See United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co., 200 U.S. 321, 337.

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

Syllabus

CONSUMER FINANCIAL PROTECTION BUREAU et al. v. COMMUNITY FINANCIAL SERVICES ASSOCIATION OF AMERICA, LTD., et al.

certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the fifth circuit

No. 22–448. Argued October 3, 2023—Decided May 16, 2024


Opinions
NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the United States Reports. Readers are requested to notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States, Washington, D. C. 20543, pio@supremecourt.gov, of any typographical or other formal errors.

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

_________________

No. 22–448

_________________

CONSUMER FINANCIAL PROTECTION BUREAU, et al., PETITIONERS v. COMMUNITY FINANCIAL SERVICES ASSOCIATION OF AMERICA, LIMITED, et al.

on writ of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the fifth circuit

[May 16, 2024]

Justice Thomas delivered the opinion of the Court.

Our Constitution gives Congress control over the public fisc, but it specifies that its control must be exercised in a specific manner. The Appropriations Clause commands that “[n]o Money shall be drawn from the Treasury, but in Consequence of Appropriations made by Law.” Art. I, §9, cl. 7. For most federal agencies, Congress provides funding on an annual basis. This annual process forces them to regularly implore Congress to fund their operations for the next year. The Consumer Financial Protection Bureau is different. The Bureau does not have to petition for funds each year. Instead, Congress authorized the Bureau to draw from the Federal Reserve System the amount its Director deems “reasonably necessary to carry out” the Bureau’s duties, subject only to an inflation-adjusted cap. 124Stat. 1975, 12 U. S. C. §§5497(a)(1), (2). In this case, we must decide the narrow question whether this funding mechanism complies with the Appropriations Clause. We hold that it does.

I

A

Congress enacted the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act in response to the 2008 financial crisis. 124Stat. 1376. The Act created an independent financial regulator within the Federal Reserve System known as the Bureau of Consumer Financial Protection. 12 U. S. C. §5491(a). Congress charged the Bureau with enforcing consumer financial protection laws to ensure “that all consumers have access to markets for consumer financial products and services and that markets for consumer financial products and services are fair, transparent, and competitive.” §5511(a). The Act consolidated in the Bureau the authority to administer 18 existing consumer protection statutes, among them the Fair Debt Collection Practices Act, the Fair Credit Reporting Act, and the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act of 1975. §§5512(a), 5481(12), (14). Additionally, the Act made it unlawful for those offering consumer financial products and services “to engage in any unfair, deceptive, or abusive act or practice.” §5536(a)(1)(B). Congress vested the Bureau with rulemaking, enforcement, and adjudicatory authority over the statutes that it administers. See §§5531(a)–(b), 5581(a)(1)(A), (b) (rulemaking authority); §§5562–5565 (enforcement and adjudicatory authority).

In addition to vesting the Bureau with sweeping authority, Congress shielded the Bureau from the influence of the political branches. To insulate the Bureau from the President’s control, Congress put a single Director with a 5-year term at the Bureau’s helm and made the Director removable only for inefficiency, neglect, or malfeasance. §§5491(b)–(c). This Court held in Seila Law LLC v. Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, 591 U.S. 197 (2020), that the combination of single-Director leadership and for-cause removal protection unconstitutionally circumscribed the President’s ability to oversee the Executive Branch. Id., at 208.

This case involves another one of the Bureau’s novel structural features, one that limits Congress’ control. Congress supplies most federal agencies with the funds necessary for their operations only on an annual basis, so those agencies must ask Congress for renewed funding each year. For the Bureau, however, Congress diminished this accountability by providing the Bureau a standing source of funding outside the ordinary annual appropriations process. Each year, the Bureau may requisition from the earnings of the Federal Reserve System “the amount determined by the [Bureau’s] Director to be reasonably necessary to carry out” its duties, subject only to a statutory cap. §5497(a)(1). The Bureau cannot request more than 12 percent of the Federal Reserve System’s total operating expenses as reported in fiscal year 2009 (adjusted for inflation). §§5497(a)(2)(A)–(B). In fiscal year 2022, that cap was about $734 million. See Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, Financial Report of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau 7 (Fiscal year 2022). The Bureau can also retain and invest unused funds from year to year, though the Director must take into account any surplus when requesting additional funds. §§5497(a)(1), (b)(3), (c).

B

In 2017, the Bureau promulgated a regulation focused on high-interest consumer loans. See Payday, Vehicle Title, and Certain High-Cost Installment Loans, 12 CFR pt. 1041 (2018) (Payday Lending Rule). Among other things, the regulation restricts lenders’ ability to obtain loan payments through preauthorized account access after two unsuccessful withdrawal attempts. Ibid. The Community Financial Services Association of America and Consumer Service Alliance of Texas, trade associations that represent payday lenders and credit-access businesses, challenged the Payday Lending Rule on statutory and constitutional grounds. In the operative complaint, the associations argued, among other things, that the Bureau “takes federal government money without an appropriations act” in violation of the Appropriations Clause. Amended Complaint in No. 1:18–cv–00295 (WD Tex.), ECF Doc. 76, p. 30.

The District Court granted summary judgment to the Bureau. As relevant, the court explained that “[t]he Appropriations Clause ‘means simply that no money can be paid out of the Treasury unless it has been appropriated by an act of Congress.’ ” 558 F. Supp. 3d 350, 364 (WD Tex. 2021) (quoting Office of Personnel Management v. Richmond, 496 U.S. 414, 424 (1990)). And, because “a statute authorizes” the disbursements from the Federal Reserve System’s combined earnings to the Bureau “up to a certain cap,” the District Court concluded, “there is no Appropriations Clause issue.” 558 F. Supp. 3d, at 364. On appeal, the associations renewed their argument that the “Bureau’s funding mechanism usurps Congress’s role in the appropriation of federal funds” by allowing it to take “federal money without an appropriations act.” Brief for Appellants in No. 21–50826 (CA5), p. 28.

The Court of Appeals agreed with this argument and reversed. 51 F. 4th 616 (CA5 2022). Drawing on the Constitution’s text and history, the court concluded that the Appropriations Clause “does more than reinforce Congress’s power over fiscal matters; it affirmatively obligates Congress to use that authority ‘to maintain the boundaries between the branches and preserve individual liberty from the encroachments of executive power.’ ” Id., at 637 (quoting Consumer Financial Protection Bureau v. All Am. Check Cashing, Inc., 33 F. 4th 218, 231 (CA5 2022) (en banc) (Jones, J., concurring)). By giving the Bureau a “self-actualizing, perpetual funding mechanism,” the court reasoned, Congress in effect abandoned this obligation. 51 F. 4th, at 638–639. It was not enough that Congress enacted the law authorizing the Bureau’s funding because a “law alone does not suffice—an appropriation is required.” Id., at 640. The court thus held that the Bureau’s funding mechanism violates the Appropriations Clause. Id., at 642.

We granted certiorari to address the narrow question whether the statute that provides funding to the Bureau violates the Appropriations Clause. 598 U. S. ___ (2023). We now reverse.

II

Under the Appropriations Clause, an appropriation is simply a law that authorizes expenditures from a specified source of public money for designated purposes. The statute that provides the Bureau’s funding meets these requirements. We therefore conclude that the Bureau’s funding mechanism does not violate the Appropriations Clause.

A

The Appropriations Clause provides that “[n]o Money shall be drawn from the Treasury, but in Consequence of Appropriations made by Law.” Art. I, §9, cl. 7. Textually, the command is unmistakable—“no money can be paid out of the Treasury unless it has been appropriated by an act of Congress.” Cincinnati Soap Co. v. United States, 301 U.S. 308, 321 (1937). Our decisions have long given the Appropriations Clause this straightforward reading. See, e.g., Office of Personnel Management, 496 U. S., at 424 (“Money may be paid out only through an appropriation made by law; in other words, the payment of money from the Treasury must be authorized by a statute”); Reeside v. Walker, 11 How. 272, 291 (1851) (“However much money may be in the Treasury at any one time, not a dollar of it can be used in the payment of any thing not . . . previously sanctioned” through an appropriation made by Congress).

As a threshold matter, the parties agree that the Bureau’s funding must comply with the Appropriations Clause. The Appropriations Clause applies to money “drawn from the Treasury.” Art. I, §9, cl. 7. The Bureau draws money from the Federal Reserve System. 12 U. S. C. §5497(a)(1). And, surplus funds in the Federal Reserve System would otherwise be deposited into the general fund of the Treasury. §289(a)(3)(B). Whatever the scope of the term “Treasury” in the Appropriations Clause, money otherwise destined for the general fund of the Treasury qualifies. The Bureau’s funding is therefore subject to the requirements of the Appropriations Clause.

The associations’ challenge turns solely on whether the Bureau’s funding mechanism constitutes an “Appropriatio[n] made by Law.” This question divided the courts below. The District Court concluded that a valid appropriation is nothing more than a statute that “authorizes an agency to receive funds up to a certain cap.” 558 F. Supp. 3d, at 364; see also Consumer Financial Protection Bureau v. Law Offices of Crystal Moroney, 63 F. 4th 174, 181 (CA2 2023). The Court of Appeals, on the other hand, suggested that appropriations must also “meet the Framers’ salutary aims of separating and checking powers and preserving accountability to the people.” 51 F. 4th, at 640. The associations defend this understanding and argue that the statute that provides the Bureau’s funding undermines these aims by allowing the agency to indefinitely choose its own level of annual funding, subject only to an illusory cap. That is, the associations contend that the Bureau’s funding mechanism is too open-ended in duration and amount to satisfy the requirement that there be an “Appropriatio[n] made by Law.”

Based on the Constitution’s text, the history against which that text was enacted, and congressional practice immediately following ratification, we conclude that appropriations need only identify a source of public funds and authorize the expenditure of those funds for designated purposes to satisfy the Appropriations Clause.

1

The Constitution’s text requires an “Appropriatio[n] made by Law.” Art. I, §9, cl. 7. Our concern is principally with the meaning of the word “appropriation.” The Constitution’s use of the term “appropriation” in the Appropriations Clause and in other Clauses provides important contextual clues about its meaning. To state the obvious, the Appropriations Clause itself makes clear that an appropriation must authorize withdrawals from a particular source—the public treasury. It provides that money may be “drawn from the Treasury” only “in Consequence of Appropriations made by Law.” Cl. 7. The section preceding the Appropriations Clause further suggests that appropriations assign funds for specific uses: Congress has the power to “raise and support Armies,” but subject to the limitation that “no Appropriation of Money to that Use shall be for a longer Term than two Years.” §8, cl. 12.

At the time the Constitution was ratified, “appropriation” meant “[t]he act of sequestering, or assigning to a particular use or person, in exclusion of all others.” 1 N. Webster, An American Dictionary of the English Language (1828); see also 1 J. Ash, The New and Complete Dictionary of the English Language (2d ed. 1795) (“[t]he application of something to a particular use”); 1 S. Johnson, A Dictionary of the English Language (6th ed. 1785) (“[t]he application of something to a particular purpose”); T. Dyche & W. Pardon, A New General English Dictionary (14th ed. 1771) (“the appointing a thing to a particular use”). In ordinary usage, then, an appropriation of public money would be a law authorizing the expenditure of particular funds for specified ends.

Taken as a whole, this evidence suggests that, at a minimum, appropriations were understood as a legislative means of authorizing expenditure from a source of public funds for designated purposes.

2

Pre-founding history supports the conclusion that an identified source and purpose are all that is required for a valid appropriation. The concept of legislative “appropriations” grew out of the broader struggle for popular control of the purse in England. Throughout the Middle Ages, the King enjoyed near total fiscal independence. At that time, the King’s revenues came largely from hereditary sources, sometimes called “ordinary” revenues. 1 W. Blackstone, Commentaries on the Laws of England 281 (1771) (Commentaries). These ordinary revenues flowed from many sources, including the “rents and profits of the demesne lands of the crown,” id., at 286, and the fines, forfeitures, and fees “arising from the king’s ordinary courts of justice,” id., at 289. Because this revenue inhered in the King himself, Parliament had little claim to direct how it was spent. See F. Maitland, The Constitutional History of England 430 (1908) (Maitland).

But, when these unencumbered ordinary revenues did not satisfy the demands of royal governance, most often during wartime, the King had to seek what Blackstone called “extraordinary revenue.” Commentaries 306. Extraordinary revenues were financed through various forms of taxation and therefore required parliamentary authorization. Id., at 169, 307; see Magna Charta, ch. 12 (1215), in A. Howard, Magna Carta: Text and Commentary 40 (rev. ed. 1998). In granting extraordinary revenues, Parliament began exercising an attendant power to specify how the Crown used these funds. Maitland 183–184; see also T. Taswell-Langmead, English Constitutional History: From the Teutonic Conquest to the Present Time 219, 229 (6th ed. 1905). That is, Parliament “claimed the power to appropriate the supplies granted to the king.” Maitland 183–184.

Conditions in the 17th century shifted the balance of power toward Parliament. A combination of rising prices and increasing demands made it so that the King’s ordinary revenues could not satisfy the costs of royal governance, even in times of peace. D. Keir, The Constitutional History of Modern Britain Since 1485, pp. 180–181 (6th ed. 1960); P. Einzig, The Control of the Purse 57 (1959). The King’s financial weakness, and Parliament’s increasing assertiveness in appropriating extraordinary revenues, led to intragovernmental strife. The ensuing power struggle culminated in the Glorious Revolution, in which Parliament stripped away the remnants of the King’s hereditary revenues and thereby secured supremacy in fiscal matters. Commentaries 306, 333; Maitland 434.

Following the Glorious Revolution, Parliament’s usual practice was to appropriate government revenue “to particular purposes more or less narrowly defined.” Id., at 433. Additionally, Parliament began limiting the duration of its revenue grants. For example, the duties on tonnage and poundage were no longer granted to the King for life, but only for a term of years. See 2 Wm. & Mary, c. 4, §1 (1690); 6 Wm. & Mary, c. 1, §1 (1694); see also D. Gill, The Treasury, 1660–1714, 46 Eng. Hist. Rev. 600, 610 (1931). Limiting the duration of these and other revenue grants ensured that the King could not rule without Parliament. As one historian described it, Parliament made sure “the Crown should be altogether unable to pay its way without an annual meeting of Parliament. . . . Every year he and his Ministers had to come, cap in hand, to the House of Commons, and more often than not the Commons drove a bargain and exacted a quid pro quo in return for supply.” G. Trevelyan, The English Revolution 1688–1689, pp. 180–181 (1939).

Even with this newfound fiscal supremacy, Parliament did not micromanage every aspect of the King’s finances. Not all post-Glorious Revolution grants of supplies were time limited. A notable exception involved what came to be known as the civil list. Despite its established power to limit the duration of revenue grants, Parliament deemed it proper to cover the expenses of the King’s household and the civil government by appropriating revenue to that purpose for life. Maitland 435–436; see also E. Reitan, The Civil List in Eighteenth-Century British Politics, 9 Hist. J. 318, 319 (1966) (Reitan) (explaining that the “Crown was to meet the costs of the civil government” out of the civil list, including “the fees and salaries of the ministers and many other public officers, the salaries of many of the small fry in various government departments, the salaries and pensions of judges, the salaries and allowances of ambassadors and consuls, and the maintenance of buildings for Parliament and the public offices”). And, parliamentary grants of supplies ordinarily gave the Crown broad discretion regarding how much to spend within an appropriated sum. Statutes granting money often stated that the Crown could spend “any Sum not exceeding” a particular amount. See, e.g., 13 Anne, c. 18, §69 (1713); 1 Anne, c. 6, §130 (1702). These grants were permissive. As Maitland explained, “Money is granted to the queen; it is placed at the disposal of her and her ministers. But she and they are not bound by law to spend it, at least not bound by the Appropriation Act.” Maitland 445. Other parliamentary appropriations acts, however, required that money be spent for particular purposes. See, e.g., 2 Wm. & Mary, c. 1, §§35–36 (1690); 3 Wm. & Mary, c. 5, §§42–43 (1691); see also M. Rappaport, The Selective Nondelegation Doctrine and the Line Item Veto, 76 Tulane L. Rev. 265, 327, n. 211 (2001) (Rappaport).

The appropriations practice in the Colonies and early state legislatures was much the same. “When called upon to grant supplies,” the lower houses in the colonial assemblies “insisted upon appropriating them in detail.” J. Greene, The Quest for Power: The Lower Houses of Assembly in the Southern Royal Colonies 1689–1776, p. 88 (1963). Many early state constitutions vested the legislative body with power over appropriations. Rappaport 332–333. And, in exercising that authority, state legislative bodies often opted for open-ended, discretionary appropriations. See, e.g., Act of Mar. 31, 1788, 1787 Mass. Acts and Laws ch. 63, p. 657 (“[T]he amount of all duties collected by virtue of this Act shall be, and is hereby appropriated to & for the support of the civil government of this Commonwealth”); Act of Nov. 17, 1786, 1786 Mass. Acts and Laws ch. 47, p. 117 (appropriating one-third of revenue “for the exigencies of Government”); An act to amend and reduce the several acts for appropriating the public revenue, into one act, 1784 Va. Acts ch. 46, §1, reprinted in 11 W. Hening’s Statutes at Large 434 (1823) (“The money arising [from certain taxes] shall form a general fund, ten thousand pounds of which per annum shall be at the disposal of the executive, to defray the contingent charges of government”); An act to amend the act for appropriating the public revenue, 1783 Va. Acts ch. 11, §4, reprinted in id., at 248 (Half of “all the revenue arising from the tax on free male tithables . . . shall be applied . . . to the support of civil government”); An act for the defence of the bay, and to impose certain duties on imported articles, 1783 Md. Acts ch. 26, §5, reprinted in 1 W. Kilty, The Laws of Maryland (1799) (“[A]ll the duties imposed by this act on the trade of this state shall be appropriated for the defence of the bay and the protection of trade”).

By the time of the Constitutional Convention, the principle of legislative supremacy over fiscal matters engendered little debate and created no disagreement. It was uncontroversial that the powers to raise and disburse public money would reside in the Legislative Branch. The only disagreement was about whether the right to originate taxation and appropriations bills should rest in a legislative body with proportionate representation. Having reached a tentative agreement on that difference, the Committee of Detail reported a draft constitution giving the House of Representatives the power to originate all revenue and appropriations laws. This proposed draft contained the prototype of what later became the Appropriations Clause. It provided that “[a]ll bills for raising or appropriating money . . . shall originate in the House of Representatives, and shall not be altered or amended by the Senate. No money shall be drawn from the public Treasury, but in pursuance of appropriations that shall originate in the House of Representatives.” 2 Records of the Federal Convention of 1787, p. 178 (M. Farrand ed. 1911). Ultimately, the Convention agreed to grant the House an exclusive power to originate revenue laws but not for appropriations laws. Compare Art. I, §7, cl. 1, with §9, cl. 7.

In short, the origins of the Appropriations Clause confirm that appropriations needed to designate particular revenues for identified purposes. Beyond that, however, early legislative bodies exercised a wide range of discretion. Some appropriations required expenditure of a particular amount, while others allowed the recipient of the appropriated money to spend up to a cap. Some appropriations were time limited, others were not. And, the specificity with which appropriations designated the objects of the expenditures varied greatly.

3

The practice of the First Congress also illustrates the source-and-purpose understanding of appropriations. This practice “provides contemporaneous and weighty evidence of the Constitution’s meaning.” Bowsher v. Synar, 478 U.S. 714, 723 (1986) (internal quotation marks omitted).

Many early appropriations laws made annual lump-sum grants for the Government’s expenses. Congress’ first annual appropriations law, for instance, divided Government expenditures into four broad categories and authorized disbursements up to certain amounts for those purposes. For example, the law appropriated a “sum not exceeding two hundred and sixteen thousand dollars for defraying the expenses of the civil list,” which covered most nonmilitary executive officers’ salaries and expenses. Act of Sept. 29, 1789, ch. 23, 1Stat. 95; see 5 Papers of Alexander Hamilton 381–388 (H. Syrett & J. Cooke eds. 1962) (reporting detailed line-item estimates for civil-list expenditures). And, it appropriated “a sum not exceeding one hundred and thirty-seven thousand dollars for defraying the expenses of the department of war.” 1Stat. 95. The law specified that the disbursements would “be paid out of the monies which arise, either from the requisitions heretofore made upon the several states, or from the duties on impost and tonnage.” Ibid. Subsequent annual appropriations laws followed a similar pattern. See Act of Mar. 26, 1790, ch. 4, 1Stat. 104; Act of Feb. 11, 1791, ch. 6, 1Stat. 190; Act of Dec. 23, 1791, ch. 3, 1Stat. 226.

The appropriation of “sums not exceeding” a specified amount did not by itself mandate that the Executive spend that amount; as was the case in England, such appropriations instead provided the Executive discretion over how much to spend up to a cap. In 1803, for instance, Congress appropriated “a sum not exceeding fifty thousand dollars” to build up to “fifteen gun boats.” Act of Feb. 28, 1803, ch. 11, 2Stat. 206. President Jefferson subsequently reported, however, that “[t]he sum of fifty thousand dollars appropriated by Congress for providing gun boats remains unexpended. The favorable and peaceable turn of affairs on the Mississippi rendered an immediate execution of that law unnecessary.” 13 Annals of Cong. 14 (1803).

Congress took even more flexible approaches to appropriations for several early executive agencies and allowed the agencies to indefinitely fund themselves directly from revenue collected. Soon after convening, Congress enacted laws that imposed a detailed schedule of duties on imported goods and tonnage. See Act of July 4, 1789, ch. 2, 1Stat. 24–27 (imposing duties on imported goods, wares, and merchandises); Act of July 20, 1789, ch. 3, 1Stat. 27–28 (imposing duties on tonnage). It then divided the Nation into customs districts and established a vast federal bureaucracy to oversee the collection of those duties. Act of July 31, 1789, ch. 5, 1Stat. 29–49. Rather than fund those customs officials through annual appropriations, Congress opted for a fee-based model. Customs collectors were compensated through tonnage- and transaction-based fees specified by law, and through a commission on the amount of duties raised within their districts. For example, customs collectors were entitled to collect from merchants two-and-a-half dollars “for every entrance of any ship or vessel of one hundred tons burthen or upwards” and 20 cents “for every permit to land goods.” Id., at 44. And, collectors in the largest ports were paid “half a per centum on the amount of all monies by them respectively received and paid into the treasury of the United States.” Id., at 45. Other customs functionaries were also compensated on a fee basis. For instance, customs collectors paid weighers 18 cents “out of the revenue” collected “for the measurement of every one hundred bushels of salt or grain.” Ibid.

Congress adopted a similarly open-ended funding scheme for the Post Office. Instead of appropriating funds on an annual basis, Congress authorized the Postmaster General to “defray the expense” of carrying the mail of the United States with the revenues generated through postage assessments. Act of Feb. 20, 1792, §3, 1Stat. 234. The postal statute also provided the Postmaster General a $2,000 annual salary “to be paid . . . out of the revenues of the post-office.” §8, id., at 235. And, it authorized the Postmaster General to pay deputy postmasters “such commission on the monies arising from the postage of letters and packets, as he shall think adequate to their respective services,” subject to an upper limit. §23, id., at 238. These fee-based funding schemes continued year after year without Congress passing an annual appropriation for these agencies.

These fee- and commission-based funding schemes were not an American innovation; they emulated the colonial precursors to the Customs Service and Post Office. Colonial customs officers, for instance, “were paid a percentage of total receipts in their area, the proportion varying from colony to colony depending on the estimated potential yield.” T. Barrow, Trade and Empire: The British Customs Service in Colonial America 1660–1775, p. 14 (1967). Although the customs service in the Colonies later transitioned to a salary system, each customs “official was allowed certain fees for almost every transaction.” Id., at 78. And, as to the postal service, the Continental Congress allowed postmaster deputies 20 percent “on the sums they collect and pay into the General post office annually,” up to $1,000, and 10 percent on sums over that amount. 2 Journals of the Continental Congress, 1774–1789, p. 208 (W. Ford ed. 1905).

Postratification practice therefore confirms our interpretation of the Appropriations Clause. Early appropriations displayed significant variety in their structure. Each, however, adhered to the minimum requirements of an identifiable source of public funds and purpose.

B

The Bureau’s funding statute contains the requisite features of a congressional appropriation. The statute authorizes the Bureau to draw public funds from a particular source—“the combined earnings of the Federal Reserve System,” in an amount not exceeding an inflation-adjusted cap. 12 U. S. C. §§5497(a)(1), (2)(A)–(B). And, it specifies the objects for which the Bureau can use those funds—to “pay the expenses of the Bureau in carrying out its duties and responsibilities.” §5497(c)(1).

Further, the Bureau’s funding mechanism fits comfortably with the First Congress’ appropriations practice. In design, the Bureau’s authorization to draw an amount that the Director deems reasonably necessary to carry out the agency’s responsibilities, subject to a cap, is similar to the First Congress’ lump-sum appropriations. And, the commission- and fee-based appropriations that supplied the Customs Service and Post Office provided standing authorizations to expend public money in the same way that the Bureau’s funding mechanism does.

For these reasons, we conclude that the statute that authorizes the Bureau to draw funds from the combined earnings of the Federal Reserve System is an “Appropriatio[n] made by Law.” We therefore hold that the requirements of the Appropriations Clause are satisfied.

III

The associations make three principal arguments for why the Bureau’s funding mechanism violates the Appropriations Clause, each of which attempts to build additional requirements into the meaning of an “Appropriatio[n] made by Law.” None is persuasive.

A

At the outset, the associations argue that the Bureau’s funding is not “drawn . . . in Consequence of Appropriations made by Law” because the agency, rather than Congress, decides the amount of annual funding that it draws from the Federal Reserve System. This argument proceeds from a mistaken premise. Congress determined the amount of the Bureau’s annual funding by imposing a statutory cap. The Bureau’s funding statute provides that “the amount that shall be transferred to the Bureau in each fiscal year shall not exceed” 12 percent “of the total operating expenses of the Federal Reserve System” as reported in 2009 and adjusted for inflation. §5497(a)(2). The only sense in which the Bureau decides its own funding, then, is by exercising its discretion to draw less than the statutory cap. But, as we have explained, “sums not exceeding” appropriations, which provided the Executive with the same discretion, were commonplace immediately after the founding. Supra, at 12–13. Thus, we cannot conclude that Congress violated the Appropriations Clause by permitting the Bureau to decide how much funding to draw up to a cap.

B

Next, the associations suggest that the Bureau’s funding statute is not a valid appropriation because it is not time limited. On their reading, the Appropriations Clause requires both Chambers of Congress to periodically agree on an agency’s funding, which ensures that each Chamber reserves the power to unilaterally block those funding measures through inaction. The Bureau’s funding mechanism, the associations insist, inverts this baseline by allowing it to draw funds—forever—unless both Chambers of Congress step in and affirmatively prevent the agency from doing so.

But, the Constitution’s text suggests that, at least in some circumstances, Congress can make standing appropriations. The Constitution expressly provides that “no Appropriation of Money” to support an army “shall be for a longer Term than two Years.” Art. I, §8, cl. 12. Hamilton explained that this restriction ensures that, for the army, Congress cannot “vest in the Executive department . . . permanent funds” and must instead “once at least in every two years . . . deliberate upon the propriety of keeping a military force on foot,” “come to a new resolution on the point,” and “declare their sense of the matter, by a formal vote in the face of their constituents.” The Federalist No. 26, p. 143 (E. Scott ed. 1898). The Framers were thus aware of the dynamic that the associations highlight, but they did not explicitly limit the duration of appropriations for other purposes.

The First Congress’ practice confirms this understanding. Recall that the appropriations that supplied funding to the Customs Service and the Post Office were not time limited. Supra, at 13–14. The associations resist the analogy to the Post Office and other fee-based agencies, arguing that such agencies do not enjoy the same level of fiscal independence as the Bureau. Fee-based agencies, the associations reason, “could not demand funds from the federal fisc, but rather needed to persuade the people they served to pay them, and the public could refuse to purchase to influence their conduct.” Brief for Respondents 35. The associations, however, make no attempt to explain why the possibility that the public’s choices could restrain fee-based agencies’ revenue is relevant to the question whether a law complies with the constitutional imperative that there be an appropriation.

C

Finally, the associations contend that the Bureau’s funding mechanism provides a blueprint for destroying the separation of powers, and that it invites tyranny by allowing the Executive to operate free of any meaningful fiscal check. If the Bureau’s funding mechanism is consistent with the Appropriations Clause, the associations reason, then Congress could do the same for any—or every—civilian executive agency. And that, they conclude, would be the very unification of the sword and purse that the Appropriations Clause forbids.

The associations err by reducing the power of the purse to only the principle expressed in the Appropriations Clause. To be sure, the Appropriations Clause presupposes Congress’ powers over the purse. But, its phrasing and location in the Constitution make clear that it is not itself the source of those powers. The Appropriations Clause is phrased as a limitation: “No Money shall be drawn from the Treasury, but in Consequence of Appropriations made by Law.” Art. I, §9. And, it is placed within a section of other such limitations. Compare ibid. (“No Bill of Attainder or ex post facto Law shall be passed”) and ibid. (“No Tax or Duty shall be laid on Articles exported from any State”), with §8 (“The Congress shall have Power To . . . ”). The associations offer no defensible argument that the Appropriations Clause requires more than a law that authorizes the disbursement of specified funds for identified purposes. Without such a theory, the associations’ Appropriations Clause challenge must fail. See Haaland v. Brackeen, 599 U.S. 255, 277–278 (2023).

IV

The dissent’s theory fares no better. The dissent accepts that the question in this case is ultimately about the meaning of “Appropriations.” Post, at 6. It faults us for consulting dictionaries to ascertain the original public meaning of that word, insisting instead that “Appropriations” is a “term of art whose meaning has been fleshed out by centuries of history.” Ibid. But, as we have explained at length, both preratification and postratification appropriations practice support our source-and-purpose understanding. Supra, at 8–14. What is more, the dissent never offers a competing understanding of what the word “Appropriations” means. After winding its way through English, Colonial, and early American history about the struggle for popular control of the purse, the dissent declares that “the Appropriations Clause demands legislative control over the source and disposition of the money used to finance Government operations and projects.” Post, at 17. The dissent never connects its summary of history back to the word “Appropriations.” And, even setting that problem aside, it is unclear why the dissent’s theory leads to a different outcome: Congress controls the “source and disposition of the money used to finance Government operations and projects” by enacting a law that identifies the source of public funds and authorizes the expenditure of those funds for designated purposes.

The dissent’s rendition of history largely ignores the historical evidence that bears most directly on the meaning of “Appropriations” at the founding—preratification appropriations laws. For example, the dissent spends pages recounting how Parliament secured fiscal supremacy and wielded that power to superintend the King. See post, at 7–11. Although that history is a helpful starting point, see supra, at 8–9, it at most explains why appropriations must be “made by Law”—not what it means for the legislature to make an “Appropriation.” The dissent does not meaningfully grapple with the many parliamentary appropriations laws that preserved a broad range of fiscal discretion for the King. See supra, at 9–10. It makes no attempt to explain “sums not exceeding” appropriations. See ibid. And, the dissent brushes aside the civil list, asserting that it “ ‘presented a constitutional problem in the conflict between the principle of the independence of the Crown and the principle of parliamentary control of finance.’ ” Post, at 12 (quoting Reitan 320). The problem was that the King claimed absolute power to use the sums granted in the civil list as he pleased and regularly spent in excess of the allotted amount. See id., at 320, 324–329. But, the dissent never explains why the reforms that Parliament adopted in response to these abuses bear on whether the law establishing the civil list was an “appropriation.”

The dissent’s treatment of early American history does not advance its point either. It highlights the undisputed point that colonial and state legislative bodies exercised the power of the purse, post, at 13, while sidestepping the discretionary and open-ended appropriations they enacted, supra, at 10–11. The dissent quibbles with the open-ended appropriations laws that we rely on, speculating that state constitutions somehow constrained the breadth of those laws. Post, at 16–17, n. 13. But, the dissent never explains how these constitutional provisions informed what it meant for state legislative bodies to make an “appropriation” and, in any event, its critique misses the point: It was commonplace for preratification appropriations laws to be open-ended in a way that is not consistent with the specificity that the dissent’s theory appears to require.

When the dissent turns to postratification history, it engages with several appropriations laws enacted by the First Congress. The dissent acknowledges, as it must, that the fee- and commission-based funding schemes for the Customs Service and Post Office show that Congress exercised broad discretion over how to appropriate money. Post, at 15–16. To square these funding schemes with its understanding of the Appropriations Clause, the dissent points out that Congress required “fees in excess of what was needed to defray the cost of providing services be turned over to the Treasury.” Post, at 16. This requirement, the dissent reasons, “ensured that Congress maintained control over the ways in which [the appropriated] money was spent.” Ibid. But, if what matters is that Congress controls how funds are spent, then we are all in agreement—appropriations must designate the purposes for which money can be spent.

Even under the dissent’s “legislative control” theory, its attempt to distinguish the Customs Service and the Post Office from the Bureau is not convincing. The dissent points out that Congress had control over the Customs Service, for instance, because Customs had a “carefully delineated mission” and “early tariff Acts spelled out in excruciating detail the various fees” customs officers could collect, as well as the salaries the officers could be paid from those receipts. Post, at 19–20. According to the dissent, the Bureau is different because “[i]ts powers are broad and vast,” “[i]t does not collect fees,” and “it is permitted to keep and invest surplus funds.” Post, at 20. But, it is unclear why these differences matter under the dissent’s theory. After all, to make a valid appropriation, Congress must designate the objects for which the appropriated funds may be used—as it did here. See 12 U. S. C. §5497(c)(1). Although there may be other constitutional checks on Congress’ authority to create and fund an administrative agency, specifying the source and purpose is all the control the Appropriations Clause requires.

V

The statute that authorizes the Bureau to draw money from the combined earnings of the Federal Reserve System to carry out its duties satisfies the Appropriations Clause. Accordingly, we reverse the judgment of the Court of Appeals and remand the case for further proceedings consistent with this opinion.

It is so ordered.

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

_________________

No. 22–448

_________________

CONSUMER FINANCIAL PROTECTION BUREAU, et al., PETITIONERS v. COMMUNITY FINANCIAL SERVICES ASSOCIATION OF AMERICA, LIMITED, et al.

on writ of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the fifth circuit

[May 16, 2024]

Justice Kagan, with whom Justice Sotomayor, Justice Kavanaugh, and Justice Barrett join, concurring.

I join in full the Court’s opinion holding that the funding mechanism for the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau complies with the Appropriations Clause. As the Court details, that conclusion emerges from the Clause’s “text, the history against which that text was enacted, and congressional practice immediately following ratification.” Ante, at 6. At its inception, the Clause required only that Congress “identify a source of public funds and authorize the expenditure of those funds for designated purposes.” Ibid. The Clause otherwise granted Congress “a wide range of discretion.” Ante, at 12. The result was “significant variety” in appropriations—most notably, as to their specificity, duration, and funding source. Ante, at 15; see ante, at 12–15. The CFPB’s funding scheme, if transplanted back to the late-18th century, would have fit right in.

I write separately to note that the same would have been true at any other time in our Nation’s history. “ ‘Long settled and established practice’ may have ‘great weight’ ” in interpreting constitutional provisions about the operation of government. Chiafalo v. Washington, 591 U.S. 578, 592–593 (2020) (quoting The Pocket Veto Case, 279 U.S. 655, 689 (1929)); see also The Federalist No. 37, p. 229 (C. Rossiter ed. 1961). And here just such a tradition supports everything the Court says about the Appropriations Clause’s meaning. The founding-era practice that the Court relates became the 19th-century practice, which became the 20th-century practice, which became today’s. For over 200 years now, Congress has exercised broad discretion in crafting appropriations. Sometimes it has authorized the expenditure of a sum certain for an itemized purpose on an annual basis. And sometimes it has departed from that model in one or more ways. All the flexibility and diversity evident in the founding period has thus continued unabated, making it ever more obvious that the CFPB’s funding accords with the Constitution.

For one thing, Congress has never thought it necessary to designate specific amounts for specific items. Over the years, many appropriations have instead given the Executive leeway to decide how to allocate funds, up to a ceiling, among a set of activities. As the Court shows, the First Congress made appropriations of “sums not exceeding” stated amounts for “broad categories” of purposes; the Executive then decided the level of funding it would use for all things within a category. Ante, at 12, 13. In instituting those “lump-sum grants,” the First Congress created a template for later ones to follow. Ante, at 12. Examples of such grants “abound in our history.” Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417, 467 (1998) (Scalia, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part). During the Civil War, Congress authorized the allocation of $76.5 million for various expenses “as the exigencies of the [Army] may require.” Act of Feb. 25, 1862, ch. 32, 12Stat. 344–345. In the Depression, Congress made $950 million available “for such projects and/or purposes” as the President “in his discretion may prescribe.” Act of Feb. 15, 1934, ch. 13, 48Stat. 351. More recent examples include an appropriation not to exceed $135 million for uses that the Secretaries of Defense and Energy determine are “necessary for Atomic Energy Defense Activities.” Act of Nov. 29, 1989, §1605(a), 103Stat. 1598. The constitutionality of such measures, Justice Scalia observed, “has never seriously been questioned”—in part because of their prevalence. Clinton, 524 U. S., at 467. Our government practice has been “replete with instances of general appropriations” to be “expended as directed by designated government agencies.” Cincinnati Soap Co. v. United States, 301 U.S. 308, 322 (1937). The CFPB’s authority to take and allocate moneys up to a statutory cap is just one more instance to add to the list.

Similarly, Congress has never thought appropriations must be annual, or even time-limited. (Appropriations that are time-limited themselves show variety: Most are annual, but some last for longer periods—say, two or five years.[1]*) “Standing” appropriations—those making funds “always available for specified purposes” without “requir[ing] repeated [legislative] action”—have a long history. GAO, Principles of Federal Appropriations Law, p. 2–10 (rev. 4th ed. 2016). As the Court notes, the First Congress, by setting up fee-based schemes, provided the Customs Service and Post Office with indefinite funding. See ante, at 13–14, 17. And in doing so, that Congress again inspired its successors. Standing appropriations proliferated during the 19th century; by 1880, 138 statutes making them were on the books. See S. Rep. No. 334, 46th Cong., 2d Sess., 4–7 (1880) (listing statutes). And the growth has not stopped: By Fiscal Year 2022, spending that does not require periodic appropriations (whether annual or longer) accounted for nearly two-thirds of the federal budget. See Congressional Budget Office, The Accuracy of CBO’s Budget Projections for Fiscal Year 2022, p. 3 (Jan. 2023). Frequently, too, standing appropriations do not designate specific sums of money, thus combining one type of flexibility with another. They instead may provide the sums “necessary for purposes of ” a program—such as to provide unemployment assistance or give scholarships to veterans’ dependents. 15 U. S. C. §9023(d)(3); see 20 U. S. C. §1070h(f ). So again, Congress’s non-time-limited grant to the CFPB for amounts (up to a cap) “reasonably necessary to carry out” its duties falls within an established tradition. 12 U. S. C. §5497(a).

And “flexible approaches to appropriations” have been particularly common in the sphere of financial regulation. Ante, at 13. There, Congress’s adoption of assessment-based funding mechanisms (similar to those the First Congress used for the Customs Service and Post Office, see supra, at 3) has meant that regulators do not have to seek yearly legislative funding. And they generally may devote the funds they collect to any of a range of activities. For example, the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency has authority to levy assessments on banks as “necessary or appropriate to carry out [its] responsibilities.” 12 U. S. C. §16; see also Act of Feb. 19, 1875, ch. 89, 18Stat. 329. Similarly, the Federal Reserve Board assesses Federal Reserve Banks for whatever amount is “sufficient to pay its estimated expenses.” 12 U. S. C. §243; see also Federal Reserve Act, 38Stat. 261 (1913). Indeed, not a single federal bank regulator is currently, or has been for a long while, funded by standard congressional appropriations. The CFPB received from those regulators most of the powers it wields today. So it is not surprising that the CFPB also inherited a bank-funded scheme enabling it to allocate moneys, at its own discretion, to carry out its responsibilities.

I would therefore add one more point to the Court’s opinion. As the Court describes, the Appropriations Clause’s text and founding-era history support the constitutionality of the CFPB’s funding. See ante, at 6. And so too does a continuing tradition. Throughout our history, Congress has created a variety of mechanisms to pay for government operations. Some schemes specified amounts to go to designated items; others left greater discretion to the Executive. Some were limited in duration; others were permanent. Some relied on general Treasury moneys; others designated alternative sources of funds. Whether or not the CFPB’s mechanism has an exact replica, its essentials are nothing new. And it was devised more than two centuries into an unbroken congressional practice, beginning at the beginning, of innovation and adaptation in appropriating funds. The way our Government has actually worked, over our entire experience, thus provides another reason to uphold Congress’s decision about how to fund the CFPB.

Notes
1 *See, e.g., Foreign Operations, Export Financing, and Related Programs Appropriations Act, 2001, §101(a), 114Stat. 1900 et seq. (2-year appropriations); Military Construction Appropriations Act of 1986, 99Stat. 1024 (5-year appropriations).
SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

_________________

No. 22–448

_________________

CONSUMER FINANCIAL PROTECTION BUREAU, et al., PETITIONERS v. COMMUNITY FINANCIAL SERVICES ASSOCIATION OF AMERICA, LIMITED, et al.

on writ of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the fifth circuit

[May 16, 2024]

Justice Jackson, concurring.

Today, the Court correctly concludes that, based on the plain meaning of the text of the Appropriations Clause, “an appropriation is simply a law that authorizes expenditures from a specified source of public money for designated purposes.” Ante, at 5. The statute that Congress passed to fund the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau easily meets the Appropriations Clause’s minimal requirements. See ante, at 15. It authorizes the Bureau to withdraw money from “the combined earnings of the Federal Reserve System,” 12 U. S. C. §5497(a)(1), in order “to pay the expenses of the Bureau in carrying out its duties and responsibilities,” §5497(c)(1). In my view, nothing more is needed to decide this case.

Indeed, there are good reasons to go no further. When the Constitution’s text does not provide a limit to a coordinate branch’s power, we should not lightly assume that Article III implicitly directs the Judiciary to find one. The Constitution was “intended to endure for ages to come, and, consequently, to be adapted to the various crises of human affairs.” McCulloch v. Maryland, 4 Wheat. 316, 415 (1819) (emphasis deleted). An essential aspect of the Constitution’s endurance is that it empowers the political branches to address new challenges by enacting new laws and policies—without undue interference by courts. To that end, we have made clear in cases too numerous to count that nothing in the Constitution gives federal courts “ ‘some amorphous general supervision of the operations of government.’ ” Raines v. Byrd, 521 U.S. 811, 829 (1997) (quoting United States v. Richardson, 418 U.S. 166, 192 (1974) (Powell, J., concurring)). Put another way, the principle of separation of powers manifested in the Constitution’s text applies with just as much force to the Judiciary as it does to Congress and the Executive. See Public Workers v. Mitchell, 330 U.S. 75, 90–91 (1947).

This case illustrates why. As the Court explains, in response to the devastation wrought by the 2008 financial crisis, Congress passed and the President signed the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act. See ante, at 2. In that statute, Congress chose to fund the Bureau outside of the annual appropriations process. See ante, at 3. Drawing on its extensive experience in financial regulation, Congress designed the funding scheme to protect the Bureau from the risk that powerful regulated entities might capture the annual appropriations process. See, e.g., S. Rep. No. 111–176, pp. 162–164 (2010); A. Levitin, The Politics of Financial Regulation and the Regulation of Financial Politics, 127 Harv. L. Rev. 1991, 2056–2058 (2014); R. Barkow, Insulating Agencies, 89 Texas L. Rev. 15, 42–45, 67, 77 (2010); see also ante, at 4 (Kagan, J., concurring) (describing long history of congressional flexibility in designing funding schemes for financial regulators).

Respondents, two associations of payday lenders, represent exactly the type of entity the Bureau’s progenitors sought to regulate and whose influence Congress may have feared. See O. Bar-Gill & E. Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 44–45, 55–59, 68–70 (2008). In urging us to find the Bureau’s funding scheme unconstitutional, then, respondents would not only have us find unstated limits in the Constitution’s text, they would have us undercut the considered judgments of a coordinate branch about how to respond to a pressing national concern.

Of course, to say that Congress had reasons for designing the Bureau’s funding scheme in the manner it did is not to endorse those policy choices. “With the wisdom of the policy adopted, with the adequacy or practicability of the law enacted to forward it, the courts are both incompetent and unauthorized to deal.” Nebbia v. New York, 291 U.S. 502, 537 (1934). Instead, the Constitution places primary responsibility for checking the political branches with the People. See King v. Burwell, 576 U.S. 473, 498 (2015) (“In a democracy, the power to make the law rests with those chosen by the people”). It is to them that the Court rightly returns any remaining policy questions posed by today’s case.

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

_________________

No. 22–448

_________________

CONSUMER FINANCIAL PROTECTION BUREAU, et al., PETITIONERS v. COMMUNITY FINANCIAL SERVICES ASSOCIATION OF AMERICA, LIMITED, et al.

on writ of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the fifth circuit

[May 16, 2024]

Justice Alito, with whom Justice Gorsuch joins, dissenting.

Since the earliest days of our Republic, Congress’s “power over the purse” has been its “most complete and effectual weapon” to ensure that the other branches do not exceed or abuse their authority. The Federalist No. 58, p. 359 (C. Rossiter ed. 1961) (J. Madison). The Appropriations Clause protects this power by providing that “[n]o Money shall be drawn from the Treasury, but in Consequence of Appropriations made by Law.” Art. I, §9, cl. 7. This provision has a rich history extending back centuries before the founding of our country. Its aim is to ensure that the people’s elected representatives monitor and control the expenditure of public funds and the projects they finance, and it imposes on Congress an important duty that it cannot sign away. “Any other course” would give the Executive “a most dangerous discretion.” Reeside v. Walker, 11 How. 272, 291 (1851).

Unfortunately, today’s decision turns the Appropriations Clause into a minor vestige. The Court upholds a novel statutory scheme under which the powerful Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) may bankroll its own agenda without any congressional control or oversight. According to the Court, all that the Appropriations Clause demands is that Congress “identify a source of public funds and authorize the expenditure of those funds for designated purposes.” Ante, at 6. Under this interpretation, the Clause imposes no temporal limit that would prevent Congress from authorizing the Executive to spend public funds in perpetuity. Contra, Montesquieu, The Spirit of the Laws, bk. XI, ch. VI, p. 160 (O. Piest ed., T. Nugent transl. 1949) (warning that a legislature will lose its power of the purse if it passes an appropriation that lasts “forever”). Nor does the Court’s interpretation require Congress to set an upper limit on the amount of money that the Executive may take. Today’s decision does not even demand that an agency’s funds come from the Treasury. As the Solicitor General admitted at argument, under this interpretation, the Appropriations Clause would permit an agency to be funded entirely by private sources. Tr. of Oral Arg. 34–35. In short, there is apparently nothing wrong with a law that empowers the Executive to draw as much money as it wants from any identified source for any permissible purpose until the end of time.

That is not what the Appropriations Clause was understood to mean when it was adopted. In England, Parliament had won the power over the purse only after centuries of struggle with the Crown. Steeped in English constitutional history, the Framers placed the Appropriations Clause in the Constitution to protect this hard-won legislative power.

I

In the 2010 Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Congress created the CFPB, an independent regulatory agency with “vast rulemaking, enforcement, and adjudicatory authority over a significant portion of the U. S. economy.” Seila Law LLC v. Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, 591 U.S. 197, 203 (2020); see id., at 222, n. 8. And in designing the CFPB, “Congress deviated from the structure of nearly every other independent administrative agency in our history.” Id., at 203. At every turn, the statute attempted to insulate the CFPB from control by any official answerable to the people. First, “Congress provided that the CFPB would be led by a single Director, who serves for a longer term than the President,” and Congress attempted to protect the Director from removal by the President “except for inefficiency, neglect, or malfeasance.” Ibid. In Seila Law, we struck down this restriction because it placed “potent” power in the hands of an official who was “neither elected by the people nor meaningfully controlled . . . by someone who is.” Id., at 206, 224–225.

Elected in the atmosphere that followed the financial crisis of 2008, the Congress that created the CFPB also sought to free the CFPB from supervision by subsequent Congresses that might wish to superintend the Bureau’s exercise of its vast powers. To achieve that end, the CFPB was given an unprecedented way of obtaining funds that was expressly designed to make it totally “independent of the Congressional appropriations process.” S. Rep. No. 111–176, p. 163 (2010).

Under that scheme, the CFPB is not funded by appropriations enacted by Congress. Instead, each year, the CFPB Director tells the Federal Reserve Board of Governors how much money it thinks is “reasonably necessary” to carry out the CFPB’s operations. 12 U. S. C. §5497(a)(1). So long as this amount does not exceed 12% of the Federal Reserve System’s total operating expenses, the Board of Governors must comply with that demand and hand over the specified sum “from the combined earnings of the Federal Reserve System.” §§5497(a)(1), (2)(A). These earnings come from the Federal Reserve Banks, which are federally chartered corporations that are “not departments of the government.” Emergency Fleet Corp. v. Western Union Telegraph Co., 275 U.S. 415, 426 (1928); see §341.[1] The Federal Reserve Banks’ earnings represent interest on and gains derived from the purchase and sale of securities, as well as fees they receive for services provided to depository institutions, “such as check clearing, funds transfers, and automated clearinghouse operations.” United States Federal Reserve System, The Fed Explained: What the Central Bank Does 4 (11th ed. 2021); see also Brief for Petitioners 23. At present, the CFPB’s maximum annual draw is nearly $750 million.[2]

In addition, the CFPB, unlike most agencies, does not have to return any unspent funds to the Treasury. 12 U. S. C. §5497(b). Instead, the CFPB may invest or roll over any unspent money into a separate fund, which it may use in the future “to pay the expenses of the [CFPB] in carrying out its duties and responsibilities.” §§5497(b)–(c).[3] As of September 30, 2022, the CFPB had built up an endowment worth nearly $340 million. See 2022 Report, at 86.

In devising this novel scheme, Congress appears to have anticipated that it might be challenged under the Appropriations Clause, and Congress therefore attempted to shield its new creation by providing that “[f]unds obtained by or transferred to the [CFPB] shall not be construed to be Government funds or appropriated monies.”[4] §5497(c)(2). And to impede congressional oversight of the CFPB’s use of this money, the Act added that the Bureau’s funds are not “subject to review by the Committees on Appropriations.” §5497(a)(2)(C).

The Framers would be shocked, even horrified, by this scheme. Beginning with the First Congress, agencies[5] were generally funded by annual appropriations from the Treasury. K. Stith, Congress’ Power of the Purse, 97 Yale L. J. 1343, 1354, n. 53 (1988) (Stith). While there have been departures from this dominant model, nothing like the CFPB’s funding scheme has previously been seen. In the decision below, the Fifth Circuit held that the CFPB’s unparalleled financial independence violates the Appropriations Clause and “the constitutional separation of powers.” 51 F. 4th 616, 642 (2022). Because I agree that the CFPB’s funding structure is unconstitutional, I would affirm the Fifth Circuit’s judgment.

II

A

The Appropriations Clause is found in Article I, §9, clause 7, of the Constitution, which provides:

“No Money shall be drawn from the Treasury, but in Consequence of Appropriations made by Law; and a regular Statement and Account of the Receipts and Expenditures of all public Money shall be published from time to time.”

The first part of this provision is customarily called the Appropriations Clause, and the second is referred to as the Statement and Account Clause.

The Appropriations Clause contains two key terms—“Money . . . drawn from the Treasury” and “Appropriations”—both of which require a little explanation. As the Government acknowledges, “Money . . . drawn from the Treasury” is synonymous with the term “public Money,”[6] which appears in the Statement and Account Clause. And in this case, it is undisputed that the funds requisitioned by the CFPB constitute “public Money.”[7] Thus, the only remaining textual question is whether the CFPB gets its funding from “Appropriations” in the sense in which the Constitution uses that term.

The Court answers that question by consulting a few old dictionaries, which it says establish that “[i]n ordinary usage, . . . an appropriation of public money would be a law authorizing the expenditure of particular funds for specified ends.” Ante, at 7. It accordingly concludes that the Appropriations Clause requires no more than a law, a fund, and a purpose. Ante, at 6–7.

This analysis overlooks the fact that the term “Appropriations,” as used in the Constitution, is a term of art whose meaning has been fleshed out by centuries of history. To be sure, in interpreting the Constitution, we start with the presumption that “ ‘its words and phrases’ ” carry their “ ‘normal and ordinary’ ” meaning. District of Columbia v. Heller, 554 U.S. 570, 576 (2008) (quoting United States v. Sprague, 282 U.S. 716, 731 (1931)). But our analysis cannot end there. Some provisions use terms with specialized and well-established meanings that we cannot use dictionaries to brush aside. “ ‘[I]f a word is obviously transplanted from another legal source, whether the common law or other legislation, it brings the old soil with it.’ ” Sekhar v. United States, 570 U.S. 729, 733 (2013); see also A. Scalia & B. Garner, Reading Law: The Interpretation of Legal Texts 73–77 (2012). Applied here, this rule means that the term “Appropriatio[n]” should be interpreted in light of “legal tradition and . . . centuries of practice.” Morissette v. United States, 342 U.S. 246, 263 (1952). I therefore turn to that history.

B

1

The delegates to the Constitutional Convention did not invent the appropriations requirement. Rather, that important safeguard arose from centuries of “British experience.” Consumer Financial Protection Bureau v. All Am. Check Cashing, Inc., 33 F. 4th 218, 224 (CA5 2022) (en banc) (Jones, J., concurring). The Framers were aware of the requirement’s deep roots and the critical role it had played in “the history of the British Constitution.” The Federalist No. 58, at 359. By steadily asserting the power to condition appropriations, the House of Commons, originally “an infant and humble representation of the people[,] gradually enlarg[ed] the sphere of its activity and importance, and finally reduc[ed], as far as it seems to have wished, all the overgrown prerogatives of the other branches of the government.” Ibid.

A short summary of this process illustrates the important role of the appropriations requirement. During the Middle Ages, kings relied almost entirely on what was called “ordinary” revenue. F. Maitland, The Constitutional History of England 433 (1908) (reprint 1993) (Maitland). This included income from lands owned by the Crown, customs duties, and feudal dues. See 1 W. Blackstone, Commentaries on the Laws of England 281–306 (2d ed. 1766). Consequently, there was little meaningful difference “between the national revenue and the king’s private pocket-money.” Maitland 433.

The Crown’s financial independence gave it the ability to govern with little parliamentary interference. As Maitland puts it, “throughout the Middle Ages the king’s revenue had been in a very true sense the king’s revenue, and parliament had but seldom attempted to give him orders as to what he should do with it.” Id., at 309. “Under the Tudors, parliament hardly dared to meddle with such matters.” Ibid.

In the 17th century, however, this pattern began to change. Id., at 309–310. By that time, “the king’s ordinary revenues were no longer even remotely sufficient to cover the normal costs of royal governance,” and the heavy expenditures of James I and Charles I exacerbated the problem. J. Chafetz, Congress’s Constitution 47 (2017) (Chafetz). Rather than seeking appropriations from Parliament, the early Stuart kings engaged in controversial efforts to obtain additional ordinary income through the use of various royal “prerogative[s].” G. Smith, A Constitutional and Legal History of England 315 (1955) (Smith). Among other things, they unilaterally imposed duties on imports, stepped up the collection of feudal dues, sold monopolies, and forced individuals to loan money on pain of imprisonment. See id., at 315, 318.

These measures aroused opposition and, in any event, did not yield sufficient funds. As a result, James I and Charles I periodically found it necessary to ask Parliament to impose new taxes in order to obtain the funds they wanted. When they did so, the Commons began to flex the power of the purse and to demand a measure of royal accountability. Disputes between the Commons and the Stuart kings about the power of the purse played a pivotal role in the transition from royal to parliamentary financial supremacy.

A few incidents illustrate this dynamic. In 1621, the power of the purse played a central role in disputes between the Crown and Parliament over religious, geopolitical, and judicial authority. For some months, Parliament ignored requests from James I for more tax revenue. T. Taswell-Langmead, English Constitutional History From the Teutonic Conquest to the Present Time 532 (3d ed. 1886) (Taswell-Langmead). Though Parliament finally expressed “willing[ness] to grant a moderate subsidy,” it insisted “first” on redress for “grievances.” Id., at 533; see also Smith 315–316. Parliament’s petition infuriated James I, who ultimately dissolved Parliament and sent several of its leaders—including Sir Matthew Hale—to the Tower of London. Taswell-Langmead 534, 536.

Under Charles I, the situation worsened. At the beginning of his reign, the Commons refused to grant him the life-time power to impose tonnage and poundage duties, i.e., duties on imports and exports, as had been the custom, but instead granted the power for only one year. Id., at 539. The members of Commons “had no intention of refusing a further supply, but were resolved to avail themselves of their Constitutional right to make it dependent upon redress of grievances.” Ibid. Indignant about this temerity, the King hastily dissolved Parliament before the Lords passed the bill. Id., at 540; Smith 318. But as a consequence, the King once again then found himself without sufficient funds. So he took matters into his own hands by resorting to the monarchy’s “old illegal methods of raising money.” Taswell-Langmead 543.

This reignited a power struggle between the two branches. As a result, when Charles I again turned to Parliament in 1628, the Commons refused to grant funds until he agreed to the Petition of Right, which demanded that he cease efforts to obtain more “ordinary income” by objectionable means, such as compulsory loans and the payment of “any tax, tallage,[8] aid, or other like charge not set by common consent, in parliament.” 3 Car. I., c. 1. (1628). The King, of course, did not like this. So when the Commons continued to challenge royal prerogatives, Charles I prorogued Parliament. And during the long period that ensued in which Parliament did not meet (1629–1640), the King sought new sources of “ordinary income,” including the imposition of “Ship-money,” that is, fees imposed on both maritime and inland counties to pay for the construction of ships. Taswell-Langmead 566–569. These practices “further enraged an already alienated Parliament, reinforcing a vicious cycle that led to the Civil War and, ultimately, to Charles’s beheading.” Chafetz 47.

This constitutional crisis restored the English Government’s financial separation of powers for a season. During the Commonwealth, the Commons exercised “complete authority . . . over the whole receipts and expenditure of the national treasury.” Taswell-Langmead 626. But shortly after the Restoration, the war for the supremacy of the purse reignited. Starting in 1665, “Parliament was largely unwilling to grant [the King] additional money without specifying in some measure how it was to be used.” Chafetz 50. “This precedent was followed in some, but not all . . . cases under Charles II.” Maitland 310. Charles II, “fed up with parliamentary interference, ruled without Parliament, and therefore without any parliamentary taxation, for the rest of his reign.” Chafetz 50.

After the Revolution of 1688, Parliament took strong measures to curb the Crown’s financial independence. The 1689 Bill of Rights declared “[t]hat levying Money for or to the Use of the Crowne by pretence of Prerogative, without Grant of Parlyament for longer time or in other manner than the same is or shall be granted is Illegall.” 1 Wm. 3 & Mary 2, c. 2 (1688). In other words, to ensure “that it was supreme in directing the use of [all] public funds,” Parliament “asserted that any use of funds by the monarch that lacked Parliament’s authorization was unlawful.” Congressional Research Service, S. Stiff, Congress’s Power Over Appropriations: Constitutional and Statutory Provisions 8 (2020).

These steps, however, did not cement Parliament’s power of the purse. Royal officers continued to collect revenue and to evade the appropriations requirement by exaggerating collection costs, giving very little in “net receipts” to Parliament, and keeping the rest for the use of the Crown. P. Einzig, The Control of the Purse 164, 188 (1959) (Einzig). So Parliament took steps to crack down on this practice. Id., at 188. In 1711, for example, Parliament passed a resolution declaring that “ ‘applying any sum of un- appropriated money, or surplusages of funds to usages not voted, or addressed for by parliament, hath been a misapplication of the public money.’ ” 6 Cobbett’s Parliamentary History of England 1025 (1810).

Parliament also appointed a commission to prevent the Crown from defying the appropriations requirement. In that commission’s very first report, it recommended that “[r]evenue should come from the Pocket of the Subject directly into the Exchequer.” Report Relative to the Balances in the Hands of the Receivers General of the Land Tax, Nov. 27, 1780 (First Report), reprinted in 1 Reports of the Commissioners Appointed To Examine, Take, and State the Public Accounts of the Kingdom 14 (W. Molleson ed. 1783). Permitting revenue departments to retain or divert any public funds, the Commissioners concluded, would create a “private Interest . . . in direct Opposition to that of the Public.” Ibid. Finally, Parliament took an increasingly “firmer line . . . against virement, that is, the transfer of funds appropriated for one department for the use of another department.” Einzig 144.

2

The Court’s treatment of this history begins by conceding most of what I have recounted. The Court notes that after the Revolution of 1688, “Parliament’s usual practice was to appropriate government revenue ‘to particular purposes more or less narrowly defined,’ ” and “Parliament began limiting the duration of its revenue grants.” Ante, at 9 (quoting Maitland 433). “ ‘Every year,’ ” the Court continues, the King and his ministers “ ‘had to come, cap in hand, to the House of Commons, and more often than not the Commons drove a bargain and exacted a quid pro quo in return for supply.’ ” Ante, at 9 (quoting G. Trevelyan, The English Revolution of 1688–1689, pp. 180–181 (1939)).

In an effort to find a trace of helpful precedent in pre-founding British constitutional history, the Court turns to laws appropriating funds for the “civil list,” which it touts as a particularly “notable exception” to the centuries-long understanding of appropriations. Ante, at 9, 12, 19. In truth, however, Parliament’s treatment of the civil list actually undermines the Court’s position. The civil list, although renamed in 2012, remains to this day, and it consists of the money needed to cover the expenses of the royal family.[9] By the end of the 17th century, “the Civil List was a relatively small share of the total public expenditure,” but the independence it afforded the Crown “presented a constitutional problem in the conflict between the principle of the independence of the Crown and the principle of parliamentary control of finance.” E. Reitan, The Civil List in Eighteenth-Century British Politics: Parliamentary Supremacy Versus the Independence of the Crown, 9 Hist. J. 318, 320, 322 (1966) (Reitan).

To prevent the Crown from using the civil list to erode Parliament’s hard-fought supremacy over the purse, eminent statesmen like Edmund Burke and Charles James Fox began pushing for substantial reforms. Id., at 328–337. Beginning in 1760, Parliament enacted a series of laws that altered the appropriation of civil list funds. Id., at 324; see, e.g., 1 H. Cavendish, Debates of the House of Commons 267–307 (1841). And by 1782, Parliament finally secured its “right . . . to interfere at its discretion in the affairs of the Civil List.” Reitan 336–337. “The eighteenth-century tension between the conflicting principles of parliamentary supremacy and an independent financial provision for the Crown had been resolved—as it had to be—in favour of parliamentary supremacy.” Id., at 336.

C

1

“The conflicts between Parliament and the Crown over the power of the purse . . . were replayed in the American colonies in struggles between the royal governors and provincial assemblies.” R. Rosen, Funding “Non-Traditional” Military Operations: The Alluring Myth of a Presidential Power of the Purse, 155 Mil. L. Rev. 1, 44 (1998); see also P. Wolfson, Is a Presidential Item Veto Constitutional? 96 Yale L. J. 838, 841–842 (1987). But learning from Parliament’s experiences with the monarchy, some of the American Colonies assumed appropriations authority “greater even than that of the British House of Commons,” exercising significant auditing powers and legislative oversight. J. Greene, The Quest for Power: The Lower Houses of Assembly in the Southern Royal Colonies 106 (1963). Indeed, by 1787, all but one of the 11 State Constitutions provided their respective legislatures with some control over appropriations; and no State allowed the executive to draw money from the state treasury without legislative approval. Chafetz 55, and nn. 119–120 (citing provisions); see also The Federalist No. 48, at 310 (J. Madison) (noting that, under many state constitutions, “the legislative department alone has access to the pockets of the people”).

The Framers built on this legacy at the Constitutional Convention when they adopted the Appropriations Clause, which they “well understood” would “complet[e] the power vested in Congress over money.” 7 Annals of Cong. 1124 (1798) (statement of Rep. Albert Gallatin). The Clause not only “gives to the Legislature an exclusive authority of raising and granting money,” but it also obligates Congress to keep that authority from “the hands of the Executive” at all times thereafter. Ibid. It makes the President “depen[d] on the will of [Congress] for supplies of money” in the first instance and puts him continually “in a state of subordinate dependence” to the people’s elected representatives. 3 Debates on the Constitution 17 (J. Elliot ed. 1836) (statement of Wilson Nicholas). The Appropriations Clause enables Congress, “without the concurrence of the other branches, to check, by refusing money, any mischief in the operations carrying on in any department of the Government.” 5 Annals of Cong. 509 (1796) (statement of Rep. William Branch Giles) (emphasis added).

Early budgets illustrate how the appropriations power was understood. Although the Constitution does not require that appropriations be limited to a single year, that was the dominant practice in the years immediately following the adoption of the Constitution. See ante, at 12. And while the first few appropriations laws were brief and lacked details about how the money was to be spent, the amounts approved closely tracked the estimates submitted by Secretary of the Treasury Alexander Hamilton. See Chafetz 58–59. Indeed, the second appropriations act expressly incorporated the estimates of specific expenses contained in Hamilton’s report to Congress. Compare Appropriations Act, §1, 1Stat. 104, with 5 American State Papers: Finance 33 (1832). As a result, Congress clearly contemplated that the money would be devoted toward particular purposes.

In the mid-1790s, appropriations laws became even more specific. Chafetz 59. And when Thomas Jefferson became President, he urged Congress “to multiply barriers against” the “dissipation” of public funds by “appropriating specific sums to every specific purpose susceptible of definition,” and “by disallowing applications of money varying from the appropriation in object, or transcending it in amount.” First Annual Message (Dec. 8, 1801), reprinted in 9 The Works of Thomas Jefferson 336 (P. Ford ed. 1905); see also Letter from Albert Gallatin to Thomas Jefferson (Nov. 1801), reprinted in 1 The Writings of Albert Gallatin 68 (H. Adams ed. 1879) (“Congress should adopt such measures as will effectually guard against misapplication of public moneys”).

To be sure, not all early funding laws followed the dominant model of specified short-term appropriations. Agencies that provided services to a particular segment of the public were funded by fees that were paid by the recipients of those services. See, e.g., Act of Feb. 20, 1792, §§2–3, 1Stat. 233–234 (funding the Post Office through collection of postage rates); Act of Apr. 2, 1792, ch. 16, §§1, 14, 1Stat. 246, 249 (funding the National Mint in part through collection of fees); Act of July 31, 1789, §29, 1Stat. 44–45 (funding customs collection through tonnage fees). If these fees exceeded the costs of providing the services, however, these agencies were required to send the surplus to the Treasury, which oversaw the collection and use of such fees.[10]

As the Government notes, Brief for Petitioners 21–22, this practice had deep historical roots, see N. Parrillo, Against the Profit Motive 65 (2013) (Parrillo),[11] and was presumably based on the idea that the cost of providing certain services should be borne by the recipients of those services rather than the general public. At the same time, the requirement that fees in excess of what was needed to defray the cost of providing services be turned over to the Treasury ensured that Congress maintained control over the ways in which this money was spent. Under these arrangements, therefore, Congress exercised close control over both the amount of money that the agencies in question obtained and the way in which that money was used. The agencies received and were allowed to use the amount of money necessary to provide their narrowly prescribed services. All the rest was sent to the Treasury and could then be used only as authorized by a congressional appropriation.

2

In discussing this early American history, the Court begins by essentially conceding the principal lesson outlined above. As the Court candidly puts it, “ ‘[w]hen called upon to grant supplies,’ the lower houses in the colonial assemblies ‘insisted upon appropriating them in detail.’ ” Ante, at 10.[12] The best the Court can muster to support its assertion that “state legislative bodies often opted for open-ended, discretionary appropriations” are a few minor state laws that, when understood in relation to the Constitutions of the States in question, provide no support for the Court’s argument. Ibid.[13]

*  *  *

In sum, centuries of historical practice show that the Appropriations Clause demands legislative control over the source and disposition of the money used to finance Government operations and projects.[14]

III

A

As the previous discussion shows, today’s case turns on a simple question: Is the CFPB financially accountable to Congress in the way the Appropriations Clause demands? History tells us it is not. As we said in Seila Law, “ ‘[p]erhaps the most telling indication of [a] severe constitutional problem’ with an executive entity ‘is [a] lack of historical precedent’ to support it.” 591 U. S., at 220 (quoting Free Enterprise Fund v. Public Company Accounting Oversight Bd., 561 U.S. 477, 505 (2010)). And the Government agrees with this principle. In its briefing and at argument, the Government admitted that an utterly unprecedented funding scheme would raise a serious constitutional problem. Reply Brief 18; Tr. of Oral Arg. 11, 26. The Government therefore attempts to show that there is ample precedent for the CFPB scheme, but that effort fails.

The CFPB’s funding scheme contains the following features: (1) it applies in perpetuity; (2) the CFPB has discretion to select the amount of funding that it receives, up to a statutory cap; (3) the funds taken by the CFPB come from other entities; (4) those entities are self-funded corporations that obtain their funding from fees on private parties, “not departments of the Government,” Emergency Fleet Corp., 275 U. S., at 426; (5) the CFPB is not required to return unspent funds or transfer them to the Treasury; and (6) those funds may be placed in a separate fund that earns interest and may be used to pay the CFPB’s expenses in the future. At argument, the Government was unable to cite any other agency with a funding scheme like this, see Tr. of Oral Arg. 31–33, 39–41, and thus no other agency—old or new—has enjoyed so many layers of insulation from accountability to Congress.

The Government points to the Post Office and the Customs Service as founding-era precedents for the CFPB, but the analogy is flawed. As noted, funding Government agencies with fees charged to the beneficiaries of their services has long been viewed as consistent with the appropriations requirement. And both the Post Office and the Customs Service fell comfortably into that category.

A quick look at the laws that set up the Post Office and the Customs Service shows that they were nothing like the CFPB. In the Act establishing the Post Office, Congress gave that agency a narrow and specific mission: to “provide for carrying the mail of the United States.” See, e.g., Act of Feb. 20, 1792, §3, 1Stat. 234. The Postmaster’s discretionary authority was modest. (He could, for example, decide whether mail should be carried on particular routes “by stage carriages or horses.” Ibid.) The Act specified in minute detail the fees that could be collected from those who used the Post Office’s services. §9, id., at 235. And it required the Postmaster “to render to the secretary of the treasury, a quarterly account of all the receipts and expenditures” and to “pay quarterly, into the treasury . . . , the balance in his hands.” §4, id., at 234. Under this arrangement, Congress controlled the amount that the Post Office took in (i.e., the sum total of the fees specified by law) and how those fees were to be spent (i.e., to provide for carrying the mail).

Much the same is true with respect to the Customs Service, which the Government claims “best” resembles the CFPB. Tr. of Oral Arg. 31. Like the Post Office, the Customs Service had a carefully delineated mission—basically, to control imports and exports, and to collect duties and other payments from those engaged in those activities. To maintain accountability, the early tariff Acts spelled out in excruciating detail the various fees, fines, and forfeitures that officers were to collect, as well as the salaries and commissions that were to be paid out of those receipts. Act of July 31, 1789, ch. 5, 1Stat. 29–49; L. Schmeckebier, The Customs Service: Its History, Activities and Organization 3–6 (1924). Surplus funds had to be sent to the Treasury, Act of July 31, 1789, §§9, 38, 1Stat. 38, 48, and for many years, these funds were the lifeblood of the Federal Government. From 1789 to 1862, “[n]early all of federal revenue was derived from customs duties.” A. Reamer, Before the U. S. Tariff Commission: Congressional Efforts To Obtain Statistics and Analysis for Tariff-setting, 1789–1916, in A Centennial History of the United States International Trade Commission 35 (2017).[15]

The CFPB, by contrast, is an entirely different creature. Its powers are broad and vast. It enjoys substantial discretionary authority. It does not collect fees from persons and entities to which it provides services or persons and entities that are subject to its authority. And it is permitted to keep and invest surplus funds. In short, the Government’s “best” argument fails.

The Government’s next-best analogs fare no better. Moving to modern agencies, the Government claims that the CFPB’s funding scheme is not materially different from the funding schemes of a list of other currently existing agencies. See Brief for Petitioners 22–23, 29–36 (comparing the CFPB to the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), the National Credit Union Administration (NCUA), the Farm Credit Administration (FCA), the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA), and others).

But unlike the CFPB, the agencies cited by the Government are funded in whole or in part by fees charged those who make use of their services or are subject to their regulation. This is true for the OCC, see 12 U. S. C. §16; the FDIC, see §1815; the NCUA, see §1755; the FCA, §2250; and the FHFA, see §4516.[16]

For these reasons, it is undeniable that the combination of features in the CFPB funding scheme is unprecedented. And it is likewise clear that this assemblage was no accident. Rather, it was carefully designed to give the Bureau maximum unaccountability. Our decision in Seila Law addressed part of the problem posed by this arrangement. It made the CFPB accountable to the President, but that decision did nothing to protect Congress’s power of the purse. Indeed, standing alone, Seila Law worsens the appropriations problem. The appropriations requirement developed to ensure that the Executive (in England, the monarch) would be accountable to the people’s elected representatives. Seila Law, however, increased the power of the Executive over appropriations. By brandishing or wielding the threat of removal, a President may push the CFPB director to requisition the amount of money that the President thinks is appropriate and to spend that money as the President wishes. I joined the decision in Seila Law and continue to believe that it was correctly decided, but it solved only half the accountability problem that inheres in the CFPB’s structure.

B

Left with no analog in history, the Government employs a divide-and-conquer strategy to defend the CFPB’s funding scheme. It argues that even if no prior agency had a funding scheme with all the features of the CFPB’s, the funding schemes of other presumptively constitutional agencies contain one or more of the features found in the CFPB’s scheme. It then reasons that the combination of these features in the CFPB’s scheme must be constitutional as well.

This argument founders for two reasons. First, the CFPB’s scheme includes an important feature never before seen. As explained, the CFPB’s money does not come from Congress, from private recipients of its services, or from private entities that it regulates. It does not even originate with another Government agency. Instead, the CFPB gets its money via a three-step process: The Federal Reserve Banks earn money from the purchase and sale of securities, as well as from the fees they charge for providing services to depository institutions. The Federal Reserve Banks then deliver these earnings to the Federal Reserve System. Finally, the CFPB requests an amount from the Federal Reserve Board. That feature of the CFPB scheme is entirely new.

Second, the Government’s argument fails “to engage with the Dodd-Frank Act as a whole.” Seila Law, 591 U. S., at 230. By addressing the individual elements of the CFPB’s setup one-by-one, the Government seeks to divert attention from the combined layers that insulate the CFPB from accountability to Congress. Elements that are safe or tolerable in isolation may be unsafe when combined. In the case of the CFPB, the combination is deadly. The whole point of the appropriations requirement is to protect “the right of the people,” through their elected representatives in Congress, to “be actually consulted” about the expenditure of public money. St. George Tucker, View of the Constitution of the United States 297 (1803) (C. Wilson ed. 1999). The CFPB’s design strips the people of this power.

The Federal Reserve’s earnings represent “specific charges for specific services to specific individuals or companies.” FPC v. New England Power Co., 415 U.S. 345, 349 (1974). It would be “a sharp break with our traditions” to allow the CFPB to use these earnings to fund a broader array of governmental activities that have little-to-no relationship with those specific charges, services, and regulated entities. National Cable Television Assn., Inc. v. United States, 415 U.S. 336, 341 (1974). By allowing the CFPB to use the Federal Reserve’s earnings to enforce and implement broader consumer protection laws, Congress impermissibly removed the CFPB “from its customary orbit” as an agency, authorizing the Bureau to appropriate funds obtained from private sources “in the manner of an Appropriations Committee.” Ibid. In other words, Congress abdicated its appropriations authority, an exclusively legislative prerogative. Knote v. United States, 95 U.S. 149, 156 (1877). But Congress lacks the authority to “transfer to another branch powers which are strictly and exclusively legislative.” Gundy v. United States, 588 U.S. 128, 135 (2019) (plurality opinion) (internal quotation marks omitted).

In sum, the CFPB’s unprecedented combination of funding features affords it the very kind of financial independence that the Appropriations Clause was designed to prevent. It is not an exaggeration to say that the CFPB enjoys a degree of financial autonomy that a Stuart king would envy.

C

This autonomy has real-world consequences. The CFPB is a powerful agency with the authority to impose “substantive rules [on] a wide swath of industries” and “lev[y] knee-buckling penalties against private citizens.” Seila Law, 591 U. S., at 222, n. 8. In the last several months alone, the Bureau has announced plans to effectuate not one, but three major changes in consumer protection law. The CFPB has issued guidance cautioning financial institutions from “denying credit to individuals based on their [illegal] immigration status, regardless of their personal circumstances and demonstrated ability to repay.”[17] It has also begun “a rulemaking process to remove medical bills from Americans’ credit reports”[18] and to cap overdraft fees “at an established benchmark—as low as $3.”[19] These may or may not be wise policies, but Congress did not specifically authorize any of them, and if the CFPB’s financing scheme is sustained, Congress cannot control or monitor the CFPB’s use of funds to implement such changes. That is precisely what the Appropriations Clause was meant to prevent.

*  *  *

The Court holds that the Appropriations Clause is satisfied by any law that authorizes the Executive to take any amount of money from any source for any period of time for any lawful purpose. That holding has the virtue of clarity, but such clarity comes at too high a price. There are times when it is our duty to say simply that a law that blatantly attempts to circumvent the Constitution goes too far. This is such a case. Today’s decision is not faithful to the original understanding of the Appropriations Clause and the centuries of history that gave birth to the appropriations requirement,[20] and I therefore respectfully dissent.

Notes
1  Each Federal Reserve Bank has a Board of nine Directors—six are elected by private member banks, and three are appointed by the Federal Reserve System’s Board of Governors. 12 U. S. C. §§302, 304.
2  In the most recent fiscal year, the Bureau requested $641.5 million of its then-applicable $734 million limit. Financial Report of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau: Fiscal Year 2022, pp. 44–45 (Nov. 15, 2022) (2022 Report) (online source archived at https://www.supremecourt.gov).
3  The CFPB invests these funds in 3-month Treasury bills, from which it receives an annualized return of 5%. See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 3-Month Treasury Bill Secondary Market Rate, Discount Basis, Economic Research: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (Mar. 13, 2024), https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/DTB3.
4  Congress obviously cannot evade the Appropriations Clause simply by placing a different label on an authorization to obtain and spend money that falls within the meaning of an “Appropriatio[n]” under that provision. And here, the Government argues that the statutory provision cited in the text was not meant to have that effect, but was adopted for other purposes. See Tr. of Oral Arg. 20.
5  For want of a better term, I use the term “agency” to refer to anycomponent of the Executive Branch.
6  See, e.g., Tr. of Oral Arg. 34; Stith 1357.
7  See, e.g., Tr. of Oral Arg. 19, 34.
8  A tallage is “[a]n arbitrary tax levied by the monarch on towns and lands belonging to the crown.” Black’s Law Dictionary 1756 (11th ed. 2009).
9  See Royal Finances, https://www.royal.uk/royal-finances (Apr. 22, 2024).
10  At the founding, it was well understood that “the unexpended balance of any appropriation after a given period passes to the surplus fund.” 16 Annals of Cong. 393 (1807) (statement of Rep. David Thomas). See, e.g., Act of Feb. 11, 1791, ch. 6, 1Stat. 190 (recognizing default rule that surplus funds return to the Treasury); see also Act of Feb. 20, 1792, §§3–4, 1Stat. 234 (requiring the Postmaster General to “pay, quarterly, into the treasury of the United States, the balance” of any receipts after using them to “defray the expense” of services provided); Act of July 31, 1789, §38, 1Stat. 48 (providing that an unexpended portion of all customs and fines shall be “paid into the treasury” thereof ); Act of Sept. 2, 1789, ch. 12, §2, 1Stat. 65 ( “[I]t shall be the duty of the Secretary of the Treasury to . . . superintend the collection of the revenue”).
11  Parliament and “nearly all the American colonial legislatures” used such fees “to cover many and sometimes all of the offices within their respective bounds.” Parrillo 65.
12  Many sources document this general approach. See, e.g., P. Figley & J. Tidmarsh, The Appropriations Power and Sovereign Immunity, 107 Mich. L. Rev. 1207, 1244 (2009).
13  Citing two Massachusetts laws directing that certain revenue be used for broadly defined purposes, the Court infers that the executive enjoyed wide discretion to decide how this money would be spent, see ante, at 11, but this inference is unwarranted. One of the two Massachusetts laws cited by the Court, Act of Nov. 17, 1786, 1786 Mass. Acts and Laws ch. 47, p. 117, clearly illustrates this point. That law stated expressly that the revenue in question was to be paid “into the Treasury of this Commonwealth, for the exigencies of Government.” Ibid. Under the State Constitution, this money could be not be taken from the treasury without the approval of the legislature. See Mass. Const. of 1780, ch. 2, §1, Art. XI. And to fortify legislative control, the state treasurer was elected annually by the legislature. Id., ch. 2, §4. As another supposed example of a state law giving the executive wide discretion to decide how funds could be spent, the Court cites a Maryland law specifying that certain revenue was to be used for the general purpose of defending the Chesapeake Bay and protecting trade. 1783 Md. Acts ch. 26, §5, reprinted in 1 W. Kilty, The Laws of Maryland (1799). The Court overlooks the fact that under the State’s Constitution, the two state treasurers were appointed by and served at the pleasure of the legislature, Maryland Constitution of 1776, Art. XIII, and the legislature was specifically authorized to “examine and pass all accounts of the State, relating either to the collection or expenditure of the revenue, or appoint auditors, to state and adjust the same,” Art. X. Finally, the Court points to a Virginia law, ante, at 11, but again the Court overlooks the structure of the Virginia government. Under the Virginia Constitution of 1776, the treasurer was elected annually by the legislature, and this obviously gave the legislature extensive power over expenditures. Virginia Constitution of 1776, ¶17; see Chafetz 55 (referring to the Virginia Legislature’s authority over the state treasurer as an “explicit mechanism of legislative control over appropriations”).
14  Not content to rest on the Court’s argument, which relies on the Court’s understanding of the original meaning of the Appropriations Clause, four Justices advance an entirely different rationale, namely, that congressional practice in the ensuing centuries supports the constitutionality of the CFPB’s scheme. Ante, at 1 (Kagan, J., concurring). This argument is doubly flawed. First, the concurrence cannot point to any other law that created a funding scheme like the CFPB’s. Second, as explained by Justice Scalia, the separation of powers mandated by the Constitution cannot be altered by a course of practice at odds with our national charter. See NLRB v. Noel Canning, 573 U.S. 513, 571–572 (2014) (opinion concurring in judgment). “[P]olicing the ‘enduring structure’ of constitutional government when the political branches fail to do so is ‘one of the most vital functions of this Court.’ ” Id., at 572 (quoting Public Citizen v. Department of Justice, 491 U.S. 440, 468 (1989) (Kennedy, J., concurring in judgment)).
15  “In 1792, for example, customs duties . . . accounted for $3.4 million of the $3.7 million of total government receipts.” Founding Choices: American Economic Policy in the 1790s, p. 101 (D. Irwin & R. Sylla eds. 2010).
16  The Government also suggested that the Federal Reserve Board is a close historical analog for the CFPB. Brief for Petitioners 23; Tr. of Oral Arg. 41. But that setup should not be seen as a model for other Government bodies. The Board, which is funded by the earnings of the Federal Reserve Banks, 12 U. S. C. §§243, 244, is a unique institution with a unique historical background. It includes the creation and demise of the First and Second Banks of the United States, as well as the string of financial panics (in 1873, 1893, and 1907) that were widely attributed to the country’s lack of a national bank. See generally O. Sprague, History of Crises Under the National Banking System, S. Doc. No. 538, 61st Cong., 2d Sess. (1910). The structure adopted in the Federal Reserve Act of 1913 represented an intensely-bargained compromise between two insistent and influential camps: those who wanted a largely private system, and those who favored a Government-controlled national bank. See, e.g., R. Lowenstein, America’s Bank 5–8, 113–116, 265 (2015). For Appropriations Clause purposes, the funding of the Federal Reserve Board should be regarded as a special arrangement sanctioned by history.
17  Press Release, Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, CFPB and Justice Department Issue Joint Statement Cautioning That Financial Institutions May Not Use Immigration Status To Illegally Discriminate Against Credit Applicants (Oct. 12, 2023).
18  Press Release, Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, CFPB Kicks Off Rulemaking To Remove Medical Bills From Credit Reports (Sept. 21, 2023).
19  Press Release, Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, CFPB Proposes Rule To Close Bank Overdraft Loophole That Costs Americans Billions Each Year in Junk Fees (Jan. 17, 2024).
20  At the end of its opinion, the Court suggests that broad separationof powers principles may provide more protection for Congress’s power of the purse than does the Appropriations Clause. Ante, at 18–19. But we do not generally resort to broad principles when a provision of the Constitution specifically addresses the question at hand. See County of Sacramento v. Lewis, 523 U.S. 833, 843 (1998). At any rate, since the decision below relied on both the Appropriations Clause and broad separation of powers principles, 51 F. 4th 616, 635 (CA5 2022), it is not clear why the Court does not proceed to apply those principles.

Materials
Oct 3, 2023 Argued. For petitioners: Elizabeth B. Prelogar, Solicitor General, Department of Justice, Washington, D. C. For respondents: Noel J. Francisco, Washington, D. C.
Aug 21, 2023 Motion of West Virginia and 26 Other States for leave to participate in oral argument as amici curiae and for divided argument DENIED.
Aug 2, 2023 Reply of petitioners Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, et al. filed. (Distributed)
Jul 27, 2023 CIRCULATED
Jul 24, 2023 Record from W.D. Tex. electronically received and available with the Clerk.
Jul 24, 2023 Record received from the United States Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit. The record is electronic and available on PACER.
Jul 17, 2023 Record requested from the United States Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit.
Jul 14, 2023 SET FOR ARGUMENT on Tuesday, October 3, 2023.
Jul 12, 2023 Response in opposition to motion from respondents Community Financial Services Association of America, Limited, et al. filed.
Jul 12, 2023 Response of Community Financial Services Association of America, Limited, et al. to motion submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of New Civil Liberties Alliance, et al. submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of Former Members of Congress submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of Landmark Legal Foundation submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of America's Future, U.S. Constitutional Rights Legal Defense Fund, and Conservative Legal Defense and Education Fund submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of ACA International submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of Credit Union National Association, Inc., National Association of Federally-Insured Credit Unions, and American Association of Credit Union Leagues submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America, et al. submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of John Michael “Mick” Mulvaney submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of Third Party Payment Processors Association submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of Washington Legal Foundation submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Motion of State of West Virginia and 26 Other States for leave to participate in oral argument and for divided argument submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of The Foundation for Government Accountability submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of New England Legal Foundation submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Amicus brief of 132 Members of Congress submitted.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amici curiae of New Civil Liberties Alliance, et al. filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America, et al. filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amici curiae of 132 Members of Congress filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amicus curiae of John Michael “Mick” Mulvaney filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amicus curiae of The Foundation for Government Accountability filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Motion of State of West Virginia and 26 Other States for leave to participate in oral argument as amici curiae and for divided argument filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amici curiae of America's Future, U.S. Constitutional Rights Legal Defense Fund, and Conservative Legal Defense and Education Fund filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amicus curiae of Third Party Payment Processors Association filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amicus curiae of New England Legal Foundation filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Credit Union National Association, Inc., National Association of Federally-Insured Credit Unions, and American Association of Credit Union Leagues filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amicus curiae of Landmark Legal Foundation filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Former Members of Congress filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amici curiae of ACA International filed.
Jul 10, 2023 Brief amicus curiae of Washington Legal Foundation filed.
Jul 7, 2023 Amicus brief of Americans for Prosperity Foundation submitted.
Jul 7, 2023 Brief amici curiae of State of West Virginia and 26 Other States filed.
Jul 7, 2023 Brief amicus curiae of Americans for Prosperity Foundation filed.
Jul 7, 2023 Amicus brief of State of West Virginia and 26 Other States submitted.
Jul 6, 2023 Amicus brief of Atlantic Legal Foundation submitted.
Jul 6, 2023 Brief amicus curiae of Atlantic Legal Foundation filed.
Jul 3, 2023 Brief of Community Financial Services Association of America, Limited, et al. submitted.
Jul 3, 2023 Brief of respondents Community Financial Services Association of America, Limited, et al. filed.
Jun 30, 2023 Amicus brief of Center for Constitutional Jurisprudence submitted.
Jun 30, 2023 Brief amicus curiae of Center for Constitutional Jurisprudence filed.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of 90 State and Local Nonprofit Organizations submitted.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of Public Citizen. Americans for Financial Reform Education Fund, Consumer Action, Consumer Federation of America, Consumer Reports, Electronic Privacy Information Center, National Association of Consumer Advocates, National Consumer Law Center, Student Borrower Protection Center, U.S. Public Interest Research Group submitted.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of Community Development Credit Unions and Financial Institutions Including Self-Help Credit Union, The Center For Responsible Lending, And National Association of Latino Community Asset Builders submitted.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of States of New York, California, Colorado, Connecticut, Delaware, Hawaiʻi, Illinois, Maine, Maryland, Massachusetts, Michigan, Minnesota, Nevada, New Jersey, New Mexico, North Carolina, Oregon, Pennsylvania, Rhode Island, Washington, and Wisconsin, and the District of Columbia submitted.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of Financial Regulation Scholars submitted.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of AARP and AARP Foundation submitted.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of Lawyers’ Committee for Civil Rights Under Law, Housing Clinic of Jerome N. Frank Legal Services Organization at Yale Law School, Leadership Conference on Civil and Human Rights, National Fair Housing Alliance, Unidosus, et al. submitted.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of Members of Congress submitted.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of National Treasury Employees Union submitted.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of States of New York, et al.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of Military and Veterans Organizations submitted.
May 15, 2023 Motion to dispense with printing the joint appendix filed by petitioners GRANTED.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of The Mortgage Bankers Association, The National Association of Home Builders and The National Association of Realtors submitted.
May 15, 2023 Amicus brief of Professors of History and Constitutional Law submitted.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Financial Regulation Scholars filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Community Development Credit Unions and Financial Institutions Including Self-Help Credit Union, et al. filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Lawyers’ Committee for Civil Rights Under Law, et al. filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Community Development Credit Unions and Financial Institutions Including Self-Help Credit Union, The Center For Responsible Lending, And National Association of Latino Community Asset Builders filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of 90 State and Local Nonprofit Organizations filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Ten Consumer Advocacy Organizations filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of AARP and AARP Foundation filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of The Mortgage Bankers Association, et al. in support of neither party.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Professors of History and Constitutional Law filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of The Mortgage Bankers Association, The National Association of Home Builders and The National Association of Realtors in Support of Neither Party filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Lawyers’ Committee for Civil Rights Under Law, Housing Clinic of Jerome N. Frank Legal Services Organization at Yale Law School, Leadership Conference on Civil and Human Rights, National Fair Housing Alliance, Unidosus, et al. filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Military and Veterans Organizations filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Current and Former Members of Congress filed.
May 15, 2023 Brief amicus curiae of National Treasury Employees Union filed.
May 12, 2023 Amicus brief of Farm Action, HEAL Food Alliance, Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy, Rural Coalition, Partners for Rural Transformation submitted.
May 12, 2023 Brief amici curiae of Farm Action, et al. filed.
May 8, 2023 Brief of Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, et al. submitted.
May 8, 2023 Brief of petitioners Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, et al. filed.
Apr 26, 2023 Motion of Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, et al. to dispense with joint appendix submitted.
Apr 26, 2023 Motion to dispense with printing the joint appendix filed by petitioners Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, et al.
Apr 26, 2023 Motion of Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, et al. to dispense with joint appendix submitted.
Mar 14, 2023 Motion to extend the time to file the briefs on the merits granted. The time to file the joint appendix and petitioners' brief on the merits is extended to and including May 8, 2023. The time to file respondents' brief on the merits is extended to and including July 3, 2023.
Mar 10, 2023 Letter of Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, et al. submitted.
Mar 10, 2023 Motion for an extension of time filed.
Feb 27, 2023 Petition GRANTED.
Feb 21, 2023 DISTRIBUTED for Conference of 2/24/2023.
Feb 1, 2023 DISTRIBUTED for Conference of 2/17/2023.
Feb 1, 2023 Reply of petitioner Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, et al. filed. (Distributed)
Jan 13, 2023 Brief of respondents Community Financial Services Association of America, Limited, et al. in opposition filed.
Dec 14, 2022 Brief amici curiae of New York, et al. filed.
Dec 14, 2022 Brief amici curiae of West Virginia, et al. filed.
Nov 22, 2022 Motion to extend the time to file a response is granted and the time is extended to and including January 13, 2023.
Nov 21, 2022 Motion to extend the time to file a response from December 14, 2022 to January 13, 2023, submitted to The Clerk.
Nov 21, 2022 Response to motion to extend the time to file a response filed.
Nov 14, 2022 Petition for a writ of certiorari filed. (Response due December 14, 2022)