1. Construed by the plain import of their terms and the manifest
intent of the legislature, the statutes of 1862 and 1863 which make
United States notes a legal tender in payment of debts, public and
private, apply to debts contracted before as well as to debts
contracted after enactment.
2. The cases of
Lane County v. Oregon, Bronson v.
Rodes, and
Butler v. Horuitz, 7 Wall.
74
U. S. 71,
74 U. S. 229,
and
74 U. S. 258, in
which it was held that, upon a sound construction of those
statutes, neither taxes imposed by state legislation nor dues upon
contracts for the payment or delivery of coin or bullion are
included, by legislative intent, under the description of "debts,
public and private," are approved and reaffirmed.
3. When a case arises for judicial determination and the
decision depends on the alleged inconsistency of a legislative
provision with the Constitution, it is the plain duty of the
Supreme Court to compare the act with the fundamental law, and if
the former cannot, upon a fair construction, be reconciled with the
latter, to give effect to the Constitution, rather than the
statute.
4. There is in the Constitution no express grant of legislative
power to make any description of credit currency a legal tender in
payment of debts.
5. The words "all laws necessary and proper for carrying into
execution" powers expressly granted of vested have, in the
Constitution, a sense
Page 75 U. S. 604
equivalent to that of the words laws, not absolutely necessary,
indeed, but appropriate, plainly adapted to constitutional and
legitimate ends, which are not prohibited, but consistent with the
letter and spirit of the Constitution; laws really calculated to
effect objects entrusted to the government.
6. Among means appropriate, plainly adapted, not inconsistent
with the spirit of the Constitution, nor prohibited by its terms,
the legislature has unrestricted choice; but no power can be
derived by implication from any express power to enact laws as
means for carrying it into execution unless such laws come within
this description.
7. The making of notes or bills of credit a legal tender in
payment of preexisting debts is not a means appropriate, plainly
adapted, or really calculated to carry into effect any express
power vested in Congress, is inconsistent with the spirit of the
Constitution, and is prohibited by the Constitution.
8. The clause in the acts of 1862 and 1863 which makes United
States notes a legal tender in payment of all debts, public and
private, is, so far as it applies to debts contracted before the
passage of those acts, unwarranted by the Constitution.
9. Prior to the 25th of February, 1862, all contracts for the
payment of money, not expressly stipulating otherwise were, in
legal effect and universal understanding, contracts for the payment
of coin, and under the Constitution, the parties to such contracts
are respectively entitled to demand and bound to pay the sums due,
according to their terms, in coin, notwithstanding the clause in
that act and the subsequent acts of like tenor, which make United
States notes a legal tender in, payment of such debts.
On the 20th of June, 1860, a certain Mrs. Hepburn made a
promissory note, by which she promised to pay to Henry Griswold on
the 20th of February, 1862, eleven thousand two hundred and fifty
"dollars."
At the time when the note was made, as also at the time when it
fell due, there was confessedly no lawful money of the United
States, or money which could lawfully be tendered in payment of
private debts, but gold and silver coin.
Five days after the day when the note by its terms fell due --
that is to say on the 25th of February, 1862 -- in an exigent
crisis of the nation in which the government was engaged in putting
down an armed rebellion of vast magnitude, Congress passed an act
authorizing the issue of $150,000,000
Page 75 U. S. 605
of its own notes, [
Footnote
1] and enacted in regard to them, by one clause in the first
section of the act, as follows:
"And
such notes, herein authorized,
shall be
receivable in payment of all taxes, internal duties, excises,
debts, and demands of every kind due to the United States
except duties on imports, and of all claims and demands against the
United States of every kind whatsoever, except for interest upon
bonds and notes, which shall be paid in coin,
and shall also be
lawful money and a legal tender in payment of all debts, public and
private, within the United States except duties on imports and
interest as aforesaid."
The note given by Mrs. Hepburn not being paid at maturity,
interest accrued on it. And in March, 1864, suit having been
brought on the note in the Louisville Chancery Court, she tendered
in United States notes issued under the act mentioned, $12,720, the
amount of principal of the note with the interest accrued to the
date of tender, and some costs, in satisfaction of the plaintiff's
claim. The tender was refused. The notes were then tendered and
paid into court, and the chancellor, "resolving all doubts in favor
of the Congress," declared the tender good and adjudged the debt,
interest and costs to be satisfied accordingly.
The case was then taken by Griswold to the Court of Errors of
Kentucky, which reversed the chancellor's judgment, and remanded
the case with instructions to enter a contrary judgment.
From the judgment of the Court of Errors of Kentucky, the case
was brought by Mrs. Hepburn here.
Page 75 U. S. 606
THE CHIEF JUSTICE delivered the opinion of the Court.
The question presented for our determination by the record in
this case is whether or not the payee or assignee of a note, made
before the 25th of February, 1862, is obliged by law to accept in
payment United States notes, equal in nominal amount to the sum due
according to its terms, when tendered by the maker or other party
bound to pay it? And this requires, in the first place, a
construction of that clause of the first section of the act of
Congress passed on that day, which declares the United States
notes, the issue of which was authorized by the statute, to be a
legal tender in payment of debts. The clause has already received
much consideration here, and this Court has held that, upon a sound
construction,
Page 75 U. S. 607
neither taxes imposed by state legislation [
Footnote 2] nor demands upon contracts which
stipulate in terms for the payment or delivery of coin or bullion
[
Footnote 3] are included by
legislative intention under the description of debts public and
private. We are now to determine whether this description embraces
debts contracted before as well as after the date of the act.
It is an established rule for the construction of statutes that
the terms employed by the legislature are not to receive an
interpretation which conflicts with acknowledged principles of
justice and equity if another sense consonant with those principles
can be given to them. But this rule cannot prevail where the intent
is clear. Except in the scarcely supposable case where a statute
sets at nought the plainest precepts of morality and social
obligation, courts must give effect to the clearly ascertained
legislative intent if not repugnant to the fundamental law ordained
in the Constitution.
Applying the rule just stated to the act under consideration,
there appears to be strong reason for construing the word "debts"
as having reference only to debts contracted subsequent to the
enactment of the law. For no one will question that the United
States notes which the act makes a legal tender in payment are
essentially unlike in nature, and, being irredeemable in coin, are
necessarily unlike in value, to the lawful money intended by
parties to contracts for the payment of money made before its
passage. The lawful money then in use and made a legal tender in
payment consisted of gold and silver coin. The currency in use
under the act and declared by its terms to be lawful money and a
legal tender consists of notes or promises to pay impressed upon
paper, prepared in convenient form for circulation and protected
against counterfeiting by suitable devices and penalties. The
former possess intrinsic value determined by the weight and
fineness of the metal; the latter have no intrinsic value, but a
purchasing value, determined by the
Page 75 U. S. 608
quantity in circulation, by general consent to its currency in
payments, and by opinion as to the probability of redemption in
coin. Both derive, in different degrees, a certain additional value
from their adaptation to circulation by the form and impress given
to them under national authority, and from the acts making them
respectively a legal tender.
Contracts for the payment of money, made before the act of 1862,
had reference to coined money, and could not be discharged, unless
by consent, otherwise than by tender of the sum due in coin. Every
such contract, therefore, was in legal import a contract for the
payment of coin.
There is a well known law of currency that notes or promises to
pay, unless made conveniently and promptly convertible into coin at
the will of the holder, can never, except under unusual and
abnormal conditions, be at par in circulation with coin. It is an
equally well known law that depreciation of notes must increase
with the increase of the quantity put in circulation and the
diminution of confidence in the ability or disposition to redeem.
Their appreciation follows the reversal of these conditions. No act
making them a legal tender can change materially the operation of
these laws. Their force has been strikingly exemplified in the
history of the United States notes. Beginning with a very slight
depreciation when first issued, in March, 1862, they sank in July,
1864, to the rate of two dollars and eighty-five cents for a dollar
in gold, and then rose until recently a dollar and twenty cents in
paper became equal to a gold dollar.
Admitting, then, that prior contracts are within the intention
of the act, and assuming that the act is warranted by the
Constitution, it follows that the holder of a promissory note, made
before the act, for a thousand dollars, payable, as we have just
seen, according to the law and according to the intent of the
parties, in coin, was required, when depreciation reached its
lowest point, to accept in payment a thousand note dollars,
although with the thousand coin dollars, due under the contract, he
could have purchased on that day two thousand eight hundred and
fifty such dollars.
Page 75 U. S. 609
Every payment, since the passage of the act, of a note of
earlier date, has presented similar, though less striking
features.
Now it certainly needs no argument to prove that an act
compelling acceptance in satisfaction of any other than stipulated
payment alters arbitrarily the terms of the contract and impairs
its obligation, and that the extent of impairment is in the
proportion of the inequality of the payment accepted under the
constraint of the law to the payment due under the contract. Nor
does it need argument to prove that the practical operation of such
an act is contrary to justice and equity. It follows that no
construction which attributes such practical operation to an act of
Congress is to be favored, or indeed to be admitted, if any other
can be reconciled with the manifest intent of the legislature.
What, then, is that manifest intent? Are we at liberty, upon a
fair and reasonable construction of the act, to say that Congress
meant that the word "debts" used in the act should not include
debts contracted prior to its passage?
In the case of
Bronson v. Rodes, we thought ourselves
warranted in holding that this word, as used in the statute, does
not include obligations created by express contracts for the
payment of gold and silver, whether coined or in bullion. This
conclusion rested, however, mainly on the terms of the act, which
not only allow, but require payments in coin by or to the
government, and may be fairly considered, independently of
considerations belonging to the law of contracts for the delivery
of specified articles, as sanctioning special private contracts for
like payments, without which, indeed, the provisions relating to
government payments could hardly have practical effect. This
consideration, however, does not apply to the matter now before us.
There is nothing in the terms of the act which looks to any
difference in its operation on different descriptions of debts
payable generally in money -- that is to say, in dollars and parts
of a dollar. These terms, on the contrary, in their obvious import,
include equally all debts not specially expressed to be payable in
gold or silver, whether arising under past
Page 75 U. S. 610
contracts and already due, or arising under such contracts and
to become due at a future day, or arising and becoming due under
subsequent contracts. A strict and literal construction indeed
would, as suggested by Mr. Justice Story [
Footnote 4] in respect to the same word used in the
Constitution, limit the word "debts" to
debts existing,
and if this construction cannot be accepted because the limitation
sanctioned by it cannot be reconciled with the obvious scope and
purpose of the act, it is certainly conclusive against any
interpretation which will exclude existing debts from its
operation. The same conclusion results from the exception of
interest on loans and duties on imports from the effect of the
legal tender clause. This exception affords an irresistible
implication that no description of debts, whenever contracted, can
be withdrawn from the effect of the act if not included within the
terms or the reasonable intent of the exception. And it is worthy
of observation in this connection that in all the debates to which
the act gave occasion in Congress, no suggestion was ever made that
the legal tender clause did not apply as fully to contracts made
before as to contracts made after its passage.
These considerations seem to us conclusive. We do not think
ourselves at liberty, therefore, to say that Congress did not
intend to make the notes authorized by it a legal tender in payment
of debts contracted before the passage of the act.
We are thus brought to the question whether Congress has power
to make notes issued under its authority a legal tender in payment
of debts which, when contracted, were payable by law in gold and
silver coin.
The delicacy and importance of this question has not been
overstated in the argument. This Court always approaches the
consideration of questions of this nature reluctantly, and its
constant rule of decision has been and is that acts of Congress
must be regarded as constitutional unless clearly shown to be
otherwise.
Page 75 U. S. 611
But the Constitution is the fundamental law of the United
States. By it the people have created a government, defined its
powers, prescribed their limits, distributed them among the
different departments, and directed in general the manner of their
exercise. No department of the government has any other powers than
those thus delegated to it by the people. All the legislative power
granted by the Constitution belongs to Congress, but it has no
legislative power which is not thus granted. And the same
observation is equally true in its application to the executive and
judicial powers granted respectively to the President and the
courts. All these powers differ in kind, but not in source or in
limitation. They all arise from the Constitution, and are limited
by its terms.
It is the function of the judiciary to interpret and apply the
law to cases between parties as they arise for judgment. It can
only declare what the law is and enforce, by proper process, the
law thus declared. But in ascertaining the respective rights of
parties, it frequently becomes necessary to consult the
Constitution. For there can be no law inconsistent with the
fundamental law. No enactment not in pursuance of the authority
conferred by it can create obligations or confer rights. For such
is the express declaration of the Constitution itself in these
words:
"The Constitution, and the laws of the United States which shall
be
made in pursuance thereof, and all treaties made, or
which shall be made under the authority of the United States, shall
be the supreme law of the land, and the judges of every state shall
be bound thereby, anything in the constitution or laws of any state
to the contrary notwithstanding."
Not every act of Congress, then, is to be regarded as the
supreme law of the land; nor is it by every act of Congress that
the judges are bound. This character and this force belong only to
such acts as are "made in pursuance of the Constitution."
When, therefore, a case arises for judicial determination, and
the decision depends on the alleged inconsistency of a
Page 75 U. S. 612
legislative provision with the fundamental law, it is the plain
duty of the court to compare the act with Constitution, and if the
former cannot, upon a fair construction, be reconciled with the
latter, to give effect to the Constitution rather than the statute.
This seems so plain that it is impossible to make it plainer by
argument. If it be otherwise, the Constitution is not the supreme
law; it is neither necessary or useful, in any case, to inquire
whether or not any act of Congress was passed in pursuance of it,
and the oath which every member of this Court is required to take
that he
"will administer justice without respect to persons, and do
equal right to the poor and the rich, and faithfully perform the
duties incumbent upon him to the best of his ability and
understanding, agreeably to the Constitution and laws of the United
States,"
becomes an idle and unmeaning form.
The case before us is one of private right. The plaintiff in the
court below sought to recover of the defendants a certain sum
expressed on the face of a promissory note. The defendants insisted
on the right, under the Act of February 25, 1862, to acquit
themselves of their obligation by tendering in payment a sum
nominally equal in United States notes. But the note had been
executed before the passage of the act, and the plaintiff insisted
on his right under the Constitution to be paid the amount due in
gold and silver. And it has not been and cannot be denied that the
plaintiff was entitled to judgment according to his claim unless
bound by a constitutional law to accept the notes as coin.
Thus two questions were directly presented: were the defendants
relieved by the act from the obligation assumed in the contract?
Could the plaintiff be compelled, by a judgment of the court, to
receive in payment a currency of different nature and value from
that which was in the contemplation of the parties when the
contract was made?
The Court of Appeals resolved both questions in the negative,
and the defendants, in the original suit, seek the reversal of that
judgment by writ of error.
Page 75 U. S. 613
It becomes our duty, therefore, to determine whether the Act of
February 25, 1862, so far as it makes United States notes a legal
tender in payment of debts contracted prior to its passage, is
constitutional and valid or otherwise. Under a deep sense of our
obligation to perform this duty to the best of our ability and
understanding, we shall proceed to dispose of the case presented by
the record.
We have already said, and it is generally, if not universally,
conceded, that the government of the United States is one of
limited powers, and that no department possesses any authority not
granted by the Constitution.
It is not necessary, however, in order to prove the existence of
a particular authority to show a particular and express grant. The
design of the Constitution was to establish a government competent
to the direction and administration of the affairs of a great
nation, and at the same time to mark by sufficiently definite lines
the sphere of its operations. To this end it was needful only to
make express grants of general powers, coupled with a further grant
of such incidental and auxiliary powers as might be required for
the exercise of the powers expressly granted. These powers are
necessarily extensive. It has been found, indeed, in the practical
administration of the government, that a very large part, if not
the largest part, of its functions have been performed in the
exercise of powers thus implied.
But the extension of power by implication was regarded with some
apprehension by the wise men who framed, and by the intelligent
citizens who adopted, the Constitution. This apprehension is
manifest in the terms by which the grant of incidental and
auxiliary powers is made. All powers of this nature are included
under the description of
"power to make all laws necessary and proper for carrying into
execution the powers expressly granted to Congress or vested by the
Constitution in the government or in any of its departments or
officers."
The same apprehension is equally apparent in the tenth article
of the amendments, which declares that
"The powers not delegated to the United States by the
Constitution, nor
Page 75 U. S. 614
prohibited by it to the states, are reserved to the states or
the people."
We do not mean to say that either of these constitutional
provisions is to be taken as restricting any exercise of power
fairly warranted by legitimate derivation from one of the
enumerated or express powers. The first was undoubtedly introduced
to exclude all doubt in respect to the existence of implied powers,
while the words "necessary and proper" were intended to have a
"sense," to use the words of Mr. Justice Story "at once admonitory
and directory" and to require that the means used in the execution
of an express power "should be
bona fide, appropriate to
the end." [
Footnote 5] The
second provision was intended to have a like admonitory and
directory sense and to restrain the limited government established
under the Constitution from the exercise of powers not clearly
delegated or derived by just inference from powers so
delegated.
It has not been maintained in argument, nor indeed would anyone,
however slightly conversant with constitutional law, think of
maintaining that there is in the Constitution any express grant of
legislative power to make any description of credit currency a
legal tender in payment of debts.
We must inquire then whether this can be done in the exercise of
an implied power.
The rule for determining whether a legislative enactment can be
supported as an exercise of an implied power was stated by Chief
Justice Marshall, speaking for the whole Court, in the case of
McCullough v. State of Maryland, [
Footnote 6] and the statement then made has ever since
been accepted as a correct exposition of the Constitution. His
words were these:
"Let the end be legitimate, let it be within the scope of the
Constitution, and all means which are appropriate, which are
plainly adapted to that end, which are not prohibited, but
consistent with the letter and spirit of the Constitution, are
constitutional."
And in another part of the
Page 75 U. S. 615
same opinion, the practical application of this rule was thus
illustrated:
"Should Congress, in the execution of its powers, adopt measures
which are prohibited by the Constitution, or should Congress, under
the pretext of executing its powers, pass laws for the
accomplishment of objects not entrusted to the government, it would
be the painful duty of this tribunal, should a case requiring such
a decision come before it, to say that such an act was not the law
of the land. But where the law is not prohibited, and is really
calculated to effect any of the objects entrusted to the
government, to undertake here to inquire into the degree of its
necessity would be to pass the line which circumscribes the
judicial department, and tread on legislative ground. [
Footnote 7]"
It must be taken then as finally settled, so far as judicial
decisions can settle anything, that the words "all laws necessary
and proper for carrying into execution" powers expressly granted or
vested, have, in the Constitution, a sense equivalent to that of
the words, laws, not absolutely necessary indeed, but appropriate,
plainly adapted to constitutional and legitimate ends; laws not
prohibited, but consistent with the letter and spirit of the
Constitution; laws really calculated to effect objects entrusted to
the government.
The question before us, then, resolves itself into this: "Is the
clause which makes United States notes a legal tender for debts
contracted prior to its enactment a law of the description stated
in the rule?"
It is not doubted that the power to establish a standard of
value by which all other values may be measured -- or in other
words, to determine what shall be lawful money and a legal tender
-- is in its nature, and of necessity, a governmental power. It is
in all countries exercised by the government. In the United States,
so far as it relates to the precious metals, it is vested in
Congress by the grant of the power to coin money. But can a power
to impart these qualities to notes, or promises to pay money, when
offered in discharge of preexisting
Page 75 U. S. 616
debts, be derived from the coinage power, or from any other
power expressly given?
It is certainly not the same power as the power to coin money.
Nor is it in any reasonable or satisfactory sense an appropriate or
plainly adapted means to the exercise of that power. Nor is there
more reason for saying that it is implied in, or incidental to, the
power to regulate the value of coined money of the United States,
or of foreign coins. This power of regulation is a power to
determine the weight, purity, form, impression, and denomination of
the several coins and their relation to each other, and the
relations of foreign coins to the monetary unit of the United
States.
Nor is the power to make notes a legal tender the same as the
power to issue notes to be used as currency. The old Congress,
under the Articles of Confederation, was clothed by express grant
with the power to emit bills of credit, which are in fact notes for
circulation as currency; and yet that Congress was not clothed with
the power to make these bills a legal tender in payment. And this
Court has recently held that the Congress, under the Constitution,
possesses, as incidental to other powers, the same power as the old
Congress to emit bills or notes; but it was expressly declared at
the same time that this decision concluded nothing on the question
of legal tender. Indeed, we are not aware that it has ever been
claimed that the power to issue bills or notes has any identity
with the power to make them a legal tender. On the contrary, the
whole history of the country refutes that notion. The states have
always been held to possess the power to authorize and regulate the
issue of bills for circulation by banks or individuals, subject, as
has been lately determined, to the control of Congress, for the
purpose of establishing and securing a national currency; and yet
the states are expressly prohibited by the Constitution from making
anything but gold and silver coin a legal tender. This seems
decisive on the point that the power to issue notes and the power
to make them a legal tender are not the same power, and that they
have no necessary connection with each other.
But it has been maintained in argument that the power to
Page 75 U. S. 617
make United States notes a legal tender in payment of all debts
is a means appropriate and plainly adapted to the execution of the
power to carry on war, of the power to regulate commerce, and of
the power to borrow money. If it is, and is not prohibited, nor
inconsistent with the letter or spirit of the Constitution, then
the act which makes them such legal tender must be held to be
constitutional.
Let us, then, first inquire whether it is an appropriate and
plainly adapted means for carrying on war? The affirmative argument
may be thus stated: Congress has power to declare and provide for
carrying on war; Congress has also power to emit bills of credit,
or circulating notes receivable for government dues and payable, so
far at least as parties are willing to receive them, in discharge
of government obligations; it will facilitate the use of such notes
in disbursements to make them a legal tender in payment of existing
debts; therefore Congress may make such notes a legal tender.
It is difficult to say to what express power the authority to
make notes a legal tender in payment of preexisting debts may not
be upheld as incidental, upon the principles of this argument. Is
there any power which does not involve the use of money? And is
there any doubt that Congress may issue and use bills of credit as
money in the execution of any power? The power to establish post
offices and post roads, for example, involves the collection and
disbursement of a great revenue. Is not the power to make notes a
legal tender as clearly incidental to this power as to the war
power?
The answer to this question does not appear to us doubtful. The
argument therefore seems to prove too much. It carries the doctrine
of implied powers very far beyond any extent hitherto given to it.
It asserts that whether in any degree promotes an end within the
scope of a general power, whether, in the correct sense of the
word, appropriate or not, may be done in the exercise of an implied
power.
Can this proposition by maintained?
It is said that this is not a question for the court deciding a
cause, but for Congress exercising the power. But the decisive
answer to this is that the admission of a legislative
Page 75 U. S. 618
power to determine finally what powers have the described
relation as means to the execution of other powers plainly granted,
and then to exercise absolutely and without liability to question,
in cases involving private rights, the powers thus determined to
have that relation, would completely change the nature of American
government. It would convert the government, which the people
ordained as a government of limited powers, into a government of
unlimited powers. It would confuse the boundaries which separate
the executive and judicial from the legislative authority. It would
obliterate every criterion which this Court, speaking through the
venerated Chief Justice in the case already cited, established for
the determination of the question whether legislative acts are
constitutional or unconstitutional.
Undoubtedly among means appropriate, plainly adapted, really
calculated, the legislature has unrestricted choice. But there can
be no implied power to use means not within the description.
Now then let it be considered what has actually been done in the
provision of a national currency. In July and August, 1861, and
February, 1862, the issue of sixty millions of dollars in United
States notes, payable on demand, was authorized. [
Footnote 8] They were made receivable in
payments, but were not declared a legal tender until March, 1862,
[
Footnote 9] when the amount in
circulation had been greatly reduced by receipt and cancellation.
In 1862 and 1863, [
Footnote
10] the issue of four hundred and fifty millions in United
States notes, payable not on demand, but in effect at the
convenience of the government, was authorized, subject to certain
restrictions as to fifty millions. These notes were made receivable
for the bonds of the national loans, for all debts due to or from
the United States, except duties on imports and interest on the
public debt, and were also declared a legal tender. In March, 1863,
[
Footnote 11] the issue of
notes for parts of a dollar was authorized to an amount not
exceeding fifty millions of dollars. These notes were not declared
a legal tender, but were
Page 75 U. S. 619
made redeemable under regulations to be prescribed by the
Secretary of the Treasury. In February, 1863, [
Footnote 12] the issue of three hundred millions
of dollars in notes of the national banking associations was
authorized. These notes were made receivable to the same extent as
United States notes, and provision was made to secure their
redemption, but they were not made a legal tender.
The several descriptions of notes have since constituted, under
the various acts of Congress, the common currency of the United
States. The notes which were not declared a legal tender have
circulated with those which were so declared without unfavorable
discrimination.
It may be added as a part of the history that other issues,
bearing interest at various rates, were authorized and made a legal
tender, except in redemption of bank notes, for face amount
exclusive of interest. Such were the one and two years five percent
notes and three years compound interest notes. [
Footnote 13] These notes never entered
largely or permanently into the circulation, and there is no reason
to think that their utility was increased or diminished by the act
which declared them a legal tender for face amount. They need not
be further considered here. They serve only to illustrate the
tendency remarked by all who have investigated the subject of paper
money, to increase the volume of irredeemable issues, and to extend
indefinitely the application of the quality of legal tender. That
it was carried no farther during the recent civil war, and has been
carried no farther since, is due to circumstances, the
consideration of which does not belong to this discussion.
We recur, then, to the question under consideration. No one
questions the general constitutionality, and not very many,
perhaps, the general expediency of the legislation by which a note
currency has been authorized in recent years. The doubt is as to
the power to declare a particular class of these notes to be a
legal tender in payment of preexisting debts.
Page 75 U. S. 620
The only ground upon which this power is asserted is not that
the issue of notes was an appropriate and plainly adapted means for
carrying on the war, for that is admitted, but that the making of
them a legal tender to the extent mentioned was such a means.
Now we have seen that of all the notes issued those not declared
a legal tender at all constituted a very large proportion, and that
they circulated freely and without discount.
It may be said that their equality in circulation and credit was
due to the provision made by law for the redemption of this paper
in legal tender notes. But this provision, if at all useful in this
respect, was of trifling importance compared with that which made
them receivable for government dues. All modern history testifies
that in time of war especially, when taxes are augmented, large
loans negotiated, and heavy disbursements made, notes issued by the
authority of the government and made receivable for dues of the
government always obtain at first a ready circulation, and even
when not redeemable in coin on demand are as little and usually
less subject to depreciation than any other description of notes
for the redemption of which no better provision is made. And the
history of the legislation under consideration is that it was upon
this quality of receivability, and not upon the quality of legal
tender, that reliance for circulation was originally placed, for
the receivability clause appears to have been in the original draft
of the bill, while the legal tender clause seems to have been
introduced at a later stage of its progress.
These facts certainly are not without weight as evidence that
all the useful purposes of the notes would have been fully answered
without making them a legal tender for preexisting debts. It is
denied, indeed, by eminent writers, that the quality of legal
tender adds anything at all to the credit or usefulness of
government notes. They insist, on the contrary, that it impairs
both. However this may be, it must be remembered that it is as a
means to an end to be attained by the action of the government that
the implied
Page 75 U. S. 621
power of making notes a legal tender in all payments is claimed
under the Constitution. Now how far is the government helped by
this means? Certainly it cannot obtain new supplies or services at
a cheaper rate, for no one will take the notes for more than they
are worth at the time of the new contract. The price will rise in
the ratio of the depreciation, and this is all that could happen if
the notes were not made a legal tender. But it may be said that the
depreciation will be less to him who takes them from the government
if the government will pledge to him its power to compel his
creditors to receive them at par in payments. This is, as we have
seen, by no means certain. If the quantity issued be excessive and
redemption uncertain and remote, great depreciation will take
place; if, on the other hand, the quantity is only adequate to the
demands of business and confidence in early redemption is strong,
the notes will circulate freely whether made a legal tender or
not.
But if it be admitted that some increase of availability is
derived from making the notes a legal tender under new contracts,
it by no means follows that any appreciable advantage is gained by
compelling creditors to receive them in satisfaction of preexisting
debts. And there is abundant evidence that whatever benefit is
possible from that compulsion to some individuals or to the
government is far more than outweighed by the losses of property,
the derangement of business, the fluctuations of currency and
values, and the increase of prices to the people and the
government, and the long train of evils which flow from the use of
irredeemable paper money. It is true that these evils are not to be
attributed altogether to making it a legal tender. But this
increases these evils. It certainly widens their extent and
protracts their continuance.
We are unable to persuade ourselves that an expedient of this
sort is an appropriate and plainly adapted means for the execution
of the power to declare and carry on war. If it adds nothing to the
utility of the notes, it cannot be upheld as a means to the end in
furtherance of which the notes are issued. Nor can it, in our
judgment, be upheld as such if,
Page 75 U. S. 622
while facilitating in some degree the circulation of the notes,
it debases and injures the currency in its proper use to a much
greater degree. And these considerations seem to us equally
applicable to the powers to regulate commerce and to borrow money.
Both powers necessarily involve the use of money by the people and
by the government, but neither, as we think, carries with it as an
appropriate and plainly adapted means to its exercise, the power of
making circulating notes a legal tender in payment of preexisting
debts.
But there is another view, which seems to us decisive, to
whatever express power the supposed implied power in question may
be referred. In the rule stated by Chief Justice Marshall, the
words appropriate, plainly adapted, really calculated, are
qualified by the limitation that the means must be not prohibited,
but consistent with the letter and spirit of the Constitution.
Nothing so prohibited or inconsistent can be regarded as
appropriate, or plainly adapted, or really calculated means to any
end.
Let us inquire, then, first whether making bills of credit a
legal tender, to the extent indicated, is consistent with the
spirit of the Constitution.
Among the great cardinal principles of that instrument, no one
is more conspicuous or more venerable than the establishment of
justice. And what was intended by the establishment of justice in
the minds of the people who ordained it is, happily, not a matter
of disputation. It is not left to inference or conjecture,
especially in its relations to contracts.
When the Constitution was undergoing discussion in the
Convention, the Congress of the Confederation was engaged in the
consideration of the ordinance for the government of the territory
northwest of the Ohio, the only territory subject at that time to
its regulation and control. By this ordinance certain fundamental
articles of compact were established between the original states
and the people and states of the territory, for the purpose, to use
its own language, "of extending the fundamental principles of civil
and religious liberty, whereon these republics" (the states united
under the Confederation), "their laws, and constitutions are
erected."
Page 75 U. S. 623
Among these fundamental principles was this:
"And in the just preservation of rights and property it is
understood and declared that no law ought ever to be made or have
force in the said territory that shall in any manner whatever
interfere with or affect private contracts or engagements
bona
fide and without fraud previously formed."
The same principle found more condensed expression in that most
valuable provision of the Constitution of the United States, ever
recognized as an efficient safeguard against injustice, that "no
state shall pass any law impairing the obligation of
contracts."
It is true that this prohibition is not applied in terms to the
government of the United States. Congress has express power to
enact bankrupt laws, and we do not say that a law made in the
execution of any other express power, which, incidentally only,
impairs the obligation of a contract can be held to be
unconstitutional for that reason.
But we think it clear that those who framed and those who
adopted the Constitution intended that the spirit of this
prohibition should pervade the entire body of legislation, and that
the justice which the Constitution was ordained to establish was
not thought by them to be compatible with legislation of an
opposite tendency. In other words, we cannot doubt that a law not
made in pursuance of an express power, which necessarily and in its
direct operation impairs the obligation of contracts, is
inconsistent with the spirit of the Constitution.
Another provision, found in the Fifth Amendment, must be
considered in this connection. We refer to that which ordains that
private property shall not be taken for public use without
compensation. This provision is kindred in spirit to that which
forbids legislation impairing the obligation of contracts, but
unlike that, it is addressed directly and solely to the national
government. It does not, in terms, prohibit legislation which
appropriates the private property of one class of citizens to the
use of another class; but if such property cannot be taken for the
benefit of all without compensation, it is difficult to understand
how it can be so
Page 75 U. S. 624
taken for the benefit of a part without violating the spirit of
the prohibition.
But there is another provision in the same amendment which, in
our judgment, cannot have its full and intended effect unless
construed as a direct prohibition of the legislation which we have
been considering. It is that which declares that "no person shall
be deprived of life, liberty, or property, without due process of
law."
It is not doubted that all the provisions of this amendment
operate directly in limitation and restraint of the legislative
powers conferred by the Constitution. The only question is whether
an act which compels all those who hold contracts for the payment
of gold and silver money to accept in payment a currency of
inferior value deprives such persons of property without due
process of law.
It is quite clear that whatever may be the operation of such an
act, due process of law makes no part of it. Does it deprive any
person of property? A very large proportion of the property of
civilized men exists in the form of contracts. These contracts
almost invariably stipulate for the payment of money. And we have
already seen that contracts in the United States, prior to the act
under consideration, for the payment of money were contracts to pay
the sums specified in gold and silver coin. And it is beyond doubt
that the holders of these contracts were and are as fully entitled
to the protection of this constitutional provision as the holders
of any other description of property.
But it may be said that the holders of no description of
property are protected by it from legislation which incidentally
only impairs its value. And it may be urged in illustration that
the holders of stock in a turnpike, a bridge, or a manufacturing
corporation, or an insurance company, or a bank, cannot invoke its
protection against legislation which, by authorizing similar works
or corporations, reduces its price in the market. But all this does
not appear to meet the real difficulty. In the cases mentioned, the
injury is purely contingent and incidental. In the case we are
considering, it is direct and inevitable.
Page 75 U. S. 625
If in the cases mentioned, the holders of the stock were
required by law to convey it on demand to anyone who should think
fit to offer half its value for it, the analogy would be more
obvious. No one probably could be found to contend that an act
enforcing the acceptance of fifty or seventy-five acres of land in
satisfaction of a contract to convey a hundred would not come
within the prohibition against arbitrary privation of property.
We confess ourselves unable to perceive any solid distinction
between such an act and an act compelling all citizens to accept,
in satisfaction of all contracts for money, half or three-quarters
or any other proportion less than the whole of the value actually
due, according to their terms. It is difficult to conceive what act
would take private property without process of law if such an act
would not.
We are obliged to conclude that an act making mere promises to
pay dollars a legal tender in payment of debts previously
contracted, is not a means appropriate, plainly adapted, really
calculated to carry into effect any express power vested in
Congress, that such an act is inconsistent with the spirit of the
Constitution, and that it is prohibited by the Constitution.
It is not surprising that amid the tumult of the late civil war,
and under the influence of apprehensions for the safety of the
Republic almost universal, different views, never before
entertained by American statesmen or jurists, were adopted by many.
The time was not favorable to considerate reflection upon the
constitutional limits of legislative or executive authority. If
power was assumed from patriotic motives, the assumption found
ready justification in patriotic hearts. Many who doubted yielded
their doubts; many who did not doubt were silent. Some who were
strongly averse to making government notes a legal tender felt
themselves constrained to acquiesce in the views of the advocates
of the measure. Not a few who then insisted upon its necessity, or
acquiesced in that view, have, since the return of peace and under
the influence of the calmer time, reconsidered their
conclusions,
Page 75 U. S. 626
and now concur in those which we have just announced. These
conclusions seem to us to be fully sanctioned by the letter and
spirit of the Constitution.
We are obliged, therefore, to hold that the defendant in error
was not bound to receive from the plaintiffs the currency tendered
to him in payment of their note, made before the passage of the Act
of February 25, 1862. It follows that the judgment of the Court of
Appeals of Kentucky must be affirmed.
It is proper to say that MR. JUSTICE GRIER, who was a member of
the Court when this cause was decided in conference, [
Footnote 14] and when this opinion
was directed to be read, [
Footnote 15] stated his judgment to be that the legal
tender clause, properly construed, has no application to debts
contracted prior to its enactment, but that upon the construction
given to the act by the other judges he concurred in the opinion
that the clause, so far as it makes United States notes a legal
tender for such debts, is not warranted by the Constitution.
Judgment affirmed.
[
Footnote 1]
For the general form of the notes,
see 7 Wall.
74 U. S. 26.
[
Footnote 2]
Lane County v.
Oregon, 7 Wall. 71.
[
Footnote 3]
Bronson v.
Rodes, 7 Wall. 229;
Butler v.
Horwitz, 7 Wall. 258.
[
Footnote 4]
1 Story on the Constitution § 921.
[
Footnote 5]
2 Story on the Constitution, p. 142, § 1253.
[
Footnote 6]
17 U. S. 4
Wheat. 421.
[
Footnote 7]
4 Wheat.
17 U. S.
423.
[
Footnote 8]
12 Stat. at Large 259, 313, and 338.
[
Footnote 9]
Ib., 370.
[
Footnote 10]
Ib., 345, 532, and 709
[
Footnote 11]
Ib., 711.
[
Footnote 12]
12 Stat. at Large 669.
[
Footnote 13]
13
id. 218, 425.
[
Footnote 14]
November 27, 1869.
[
Footnote 15]
January 29, 1870.
MR. JUSTICE MILLER (with whom concurred SWAYNE and DAVIS, JJ),
dissenting.
The provisions of the Constitution of the United States which
have direct reference to the function of legislation may be divided
into three primary classes:
1. Those which confer legislative powers on Congress.
2. Those which prohibit the exercise of legislative powers by
Congress.
3. Those which prohibit the states from exercising certain
legislative powers.
The powers conferred on Congress may be subdivided into the
positive and the auxiliary, or, as they are more commonly called,
the express and the implied powers.
As instances of the former class may be mentioned the power to
borrow money, to raise and support armies, and to coin money and
regulate the value thereof.
Page 75 U. S. 627
The implied or auxiliary powers of legislation are founded
largely on that general provision which closes the enumeration of
powers granted in express terms by the declaration that Congress
shall also
"have power to make all laws which shall be necessary and proper
for carrying into execution the foregoing powers, and all other
powers vested by this Constitution in the government of the United
States, or in any department or officer thereof."
The question which this Court is called upon to consider is
whether the authority to make the notes of the United States a
lawful tender in payment of debts is to be found in Congress under
either of these classes of legislative powers.
As one of the elements of this question, and in order to
negative any idea that the exercise of such a power would be an
invasion of the rights reserved to the states, it may be as well to
say at the outset that this is among the subjects of legislation
forbidden to the states by the Constitution. Among the unequivocal
utterances of that instrument on this subject of legal tender is
that which declares that "no state shall coin money, emit bills of
credit, or make anything but gold and silver coin a tender in
payment of debts," thus removing the whole matter from the domain
of state legislation.
No such prohibition is placed upon the power of Congress on this
subject, though there are, as I have already said, matters
expressly forbidden to Congress; but neither this of legal tender,
nor of the power to emit bills of credit, or to impair the
obligation of contracts, is among them. On the contrary, Congress
is expressly authorized to coin money and to regulate the value
thereof, and of foreign coins, and to punish the counterfeiting of
such coin and of the securities of the United States. It has been
strongly argued by many able jurists that these latter clauses,
fairly construed, confer the power to make the securities of the
United States a lawful tender in payment of debts.
While I am not able to see in them, standing alone, a sufficient
warrant for the exercise of this power, they are not without
decided weight when we come to consider the question
Page 75 U. S. 628
of the existence of this power as one necessary and proper for
carrying into execution other admitted powers of the government.
For they show that so far as the framers of the Constitution did go
in granting express power over the lawful money of the country, it
was confided to Congress and forbidden to the states, and it is no
unreasonable inference that if it should be found necessary in
carrying into effect some of the powers of the government essential
to its successful operation, to make its securities perform the
office of money in the payment of debts, such legislation would be
in harmony with the power over money granted in express terms.
It being conceded, then, that the power under consideration
would not, if exercised by Congress, be an invasion of any right
reserved to the states, but one which they are forbidden to employ,
and that it is not one in terms either granted or denied to
Congress, can it be sustained as a law necessary and proper, at the
time it was enacted, for carrying into execution any of these
powers that are expressly granted either to Congress, or to the
government, or to any department thereof?
From the organization of the government under the present
Constitution, there have been from time to time attempts to limit
the powers granted by that instrument by a narrow and literal rule
of construction, and these have been specially directed to the
general clause which we have cited as the foundation of the
auxiliary powers of the government. It has been said that this
clause, so far from authorizing the use of any means which could
not have been used without it, is a restriction upon the powers
necessarily implied by an instrument go general in its
language.
The doctrine is that when an act of Congress is brought to the
test of this clause of the Constitution, its necessity must be
absolute and its adaptation to the conceded purpose
unquestionable.
Nowhere has this principle been met with more emphatic denial
and more satisfactory refutation than in this Court. That eminent
jurist and statesman, whose official career of
Page 75 U. S. 629
over thirty years as Chief Justice commenced very soon after the
Constitution was adopted, and whose opinions have done as much to
fix its meaning as those of any man living or dead, has given this
particular clause the benefit of his fullest consideration.
In the case of
United States v. Fisher, [
Footnote 2/1] decided in 1804, the point in
issue was the priority claimed for the United States as a creditor
of a bankrupt over all other creditors. It was argued mainly on the
construction of the statutes, but the power of Congress to pass
such a law was also denied. Chief Justice Marshall said:
"It is claimed under the authority to make all laws which shall
be necessary and proper to carry into execution the powers vested
by the Constitution in the government, or in any department
thereof. In construing this clause, it would be incorrect, and
would produce endless difficulties, if the opinion should be
maintained that no law was authorized which was not indispensably
necessary to give effect to a specified power. Where various
systems might be adopted for that purpose, it might be said with
respect to each that it was not necessary, because the end might be
attained by other means. Congress must possess the choice of means,
and must be empowered to use any means which are in fact conducive
to the exercise of the power granted by the Constitution."
It was accordingly held that under the authority to pay the
debts of the Union, it could pass a law giving priority for its own
debts in cases of bankruptcy.
But in the memorable case of
McCulloch v. Maryland,
[
Footnote 2/2] the most exhaustive
discussion of this clause is found in the opinion of the Court by
the same eminent expounder of the Constitution. That case involved,
it is well known, the right of Congress to establish the Bank of
the United States and to authorize it to issue notes for
circulation. It was conceded that the right to incorporate or
create such a bank had no specific grant in any clause of the
Constitution, still less the right to authorize it to issue notes
for
Page 75 U. S. 630
circulation as money. But it was argued that as a means
necessary to enable the government to collect, transfer, and pay
out its revenues, the organization of a bank with this function was
within the power of Congress. In speaking of the true meaning of
the word "necessary" in this clause of the Constitution, he
says:
"Does it always import an absolute physical necessity so strong
that one thing to which another may be termed necessary cannot
exist without it? We think it does not. If reference be had to its
use in the common affairs of the world or in approved authors, we
find that if frequently imports no more than that one thing is
convenient or useful or essential to another. To employ means
necessary to an end is generally understood as employing any means
calculated to produce the end, and not as being confined to those
single means without which the end would be entirely
unattainable."
The word necessary admits, he says, of all degrees of
comparison.
"A thing may be necessary, very necessary, absolutely or
indispensably necessary. . . . This word, then, like others, is
used in various senses, and in its construction the subject, the
context, the intention of the person using them are all to the
taken into view. Let this be done in the case under consideration.
The subject is the execution of those great powers on which the
welfare of a nation essentially depends. It must have been the
intention of those who gave these powers to insure, as far as human
prudence could insure, their beneficial execution. This could not
be done by confining the choice of means to such narrow limits as
not to leave it in the power of Congress to adopt any which might
be appropriate, and which were conducive to the end. This provision
is made in a Constitution intended to endure for ages to come, and
consequently to be adapted to various crises of human affairs. To
have prescribed the means by which the government should in all
future time execute its powers would have been to change entirely
the character of the instrument and give it the properties of a
legal code. It would have been an unwise attempt to provide by
immutable rules for exigencies which, if foreseen at
Page 75 U. S. 631
all, must have been but dimly, and which can best be provided
for as they occur. To have declared that the best means shall not
be used, but those alone without which the power given would be
nugatory, would have been to deprive the legislature of the
capacity to avail itself of experience, to exercise its reason, and
to accommodate its legislation to circumstances."
I have cited at unusual length these remarks of Chief Justice
Marshall because, though made half a century ago, their
applicability to the circumstances under which Congress called to
its aid the power of making the securities of the government a
legal tender, as a means of successfully prosecuting a war, which
without such aid seemed likely to terminate its existence, and to
borrow money which could in no other manner be borrowed, and to pay
the debt of millions due to its soldiers in the field, which could
by no other means be paid, seems to be almost prophetic. If he had
had clearly before his mind the future history of his country, he
could not have better characterized a principle which would in this
very case have rendered the power to carry on war nugatory, which
would have deprived Congress of the capacity to avail itself of
experience, to exercise its reason, and to accommodate its
legislation to circumstances, by the use of the most appropriate
means of supporting the government in the crisis of its fate.
But it is said that the clause under consideration is admonitory
as to the use of implied powers, and adds nothing to what would
have been authorized without it.
The idea is not new, and is probably intended for the same which
was urged in the case of
McCulloch v. Maryland, namely
that instead of enlarging the powers conferred on Congress or
providing for a more liberal use of them, it was designed as a
restriction upon the ancillary powers incidental to every express
grant of power in general terms. I have already cited so fully from
that case that I can only refer to it to say that this proposition
is there clearly stated and refuted.
Does there exist, then, any power in Congress or in the
Page 75 U. S. 632
government, by express grant, in the execution of which this
legal tender act was necessary and proper, in the sense here
defined, and under the circumstances of its passage?
The power to declare war, to suppress insurrection, to raise and
support armies, to provide and maintain a navy, to borrow money on
the credit of the United States, to pay the debts of the Union, and
to provide for the common defense and general welfare, are each and
all distinctly and specifically granted in separate clauses of the
Constitution.
We were in the midst of a war which called all these powers into
exercise and taxed them severely. A war which, if we take into
account the increased capacity for destruction introduced by modern
science and the corresponding increase of its cost, brought into
operation powers of belligerency more potent and more expensive
than any that the world has ever known.
All the ordinary means of rendering efficient the several powers
of Congress above-mentioned had been employed to their utmost
capacity, and with the spirit of the rebellion unbroken, with large
armies in the field unpaid, with a current expenditure of over a
million of dollars per day, the credit of the government nearly
exhausted, and the resources of taxation inadequate to pay even the
interest on the public debt, Congress was called on to devise some
new means of borrowing money on the credit of the nation, for the
result of the war was conceded by all thoughtful men to depend on
the capacity of the government to raise money in amounts previously
unknown. The banks had already loaned their means to the Treasury.
They had been compelled to suspend the payment of specie on their
own notes. The coin in the country, if it could all have been
placed within the control of the Secretary of the Treasury, would
not have made a circulation sufficient to answer army purchases and
army payments, to say nothing of the ordinary business of the
country. A general collapse of credit, of payment, and of business
seemed inevitable, in which faith in the ability of the government
would have been destroyed, the rebellion would have triumphed, the
states would have
Page 75 U. S. 633
been left divided, and the people impoverished. The national
government would have perished, and with it the Constitution which
we are now called upon to construe with such nice and critical
accuracy.
That the legal tender act prevented these disastrous results,
and that the tender clause was necessary to prevent them, I
entertain no doubt.
It furnished instantly a means of paying the soldiers in the
field, and filled the coffers of the commissary and quartermaster.
It furnished a medium for the payment of private debts, as well as
public, at a time when gold was being rapidly withdrawn from
circulation and the state bank currency was becoming worthless. It
furnished the means to the capitalist of buying the bonds of the
government. It stimulated trade, revived the drooping energies of
the country, and restored confidence to the public mind.
The results which followed the adoption of this measure are
beyond dispute. No other adequate cause has ever been assigned for
the revival of government credit, the renewed activity of trade,
and the facility with which the government borrowed, in two or
three years, at reasonable rates of interest, mainly from its own
citizens, double the amount of money there was in the county,
including coin, bank notes, and the notes issued under the legal
tender acts.
It is now said, however, in the calm retrospect of these events,
that Treasury notes suitable for circulation as money, bearing on
their face the pledge of the United States for their ultimate
payment in coin, would, if not equally efficient, have answered the
requirement of the occasion without being made a lawful tender for
debts.
But what was needed was something more than the credit of the
government. That had been stretched to its utmost tension, and was
clearly no longer sufficient in the simple form of borrowing money.
Is there any reason to believe that the mere change in the form of
the security given would have revived this sinking credit? On the
contrary, all experience shows that a currency not redeemable
promptly in coin, but dependent on the credit of a promissor whose
resources
Page 75 U. S. 634
are rapidly diminishing while his liabilities are in creasing,
soon sinks to the dead level of worthless paper. As no man would
have been compelled to take it in payment of debts, as it bore no
interest, as its period of redemption would have been remote and
uncertain, this must have been the inevitable fate of any extensive
issue of such notes.
But when by law they were made to discharge the function of
paying debts, they had a perpetual credit or value equal to the
amount of all the debts, public and private, in the country. If
they were never redeemed, as they never have been, they still paid
debts at their par value, and for this purpose were then, and
always have been, eagerly sought by the people. To say, then, that
this quality of legal tender was not necessary to their usefulness
seems to be unsupported by any sound view of the situation.
Nor can any just inference of that proposition arise from a
comparison of the legal tender notes with the bonds issued by the
government about the same time. These bonds had a fixed period for
their payment, and the Secretary of the Treasury declared that they
were payable in gold. They bore interest, which was payable
semiannually in gold, by express terms on their face, and the
customs duties, which by law could be paid in nothing but gold,
were sacredly pledged to the payment of this interest. They can
afford no means of determining what would have been the fate of
Treasury notes designed to circulate as money, but which bore no
interest and had no fixed time of redemption and by law could pay
no debts and had no fund pledged for their payment.
The legal tender clauses of the statutes under consideration
were placed emphatically by those who enacted them upon their
necessity to the further borrowing of money and maintaining the
army and navy. It was done reluctantly and with hesitation, and
only after the necessity had been demonstrated and had become
imperative. Our statesmen had been trained in a school which looked
upon such legislation with something more than distrust. The
debates of the two houses of Congress show that on this necessity
alone could
Page 75 U. S. 635
this clause of the bill have been carried, and they also prove,
as I think, very clearly the existence of that necessity. The
history of that gloomy time, not to be readily forgotten by the
lover of his country, will forever remain the full, clear, and
ample vindication of the exercise of this power by Congress, as its
results have demonstrated the sagacity of those who originated and
carried through this measure.
Certainly it seems to the best judgment that I can bring to bear
upon the subject that this law was a necessity in the most
stringent sense in which that word can be used. But if we adopt the
construction of Chief Justice Marshall and the full Court over
which he presided, a construction which has never to this day been
overruled or questioned in this Court, how can we avoid this
conclusion? Can it be said that this provision did not conduce
towards the purpose of borrowing money, of paying debts, of raising
armies, of suppressing insurrection? or that it was not calculated
to effect these objects? or that it was not useful and essential to
that end? Can it be said that this was not among the choice of
means, if not the only means, which were left to Congress to carry
on this war for national existence?
Let us compare the present with other cases decided in this
Court.
If we can say judicially that to declare, as in the case of
United States v. Fisher, that the debt which a bankrupt
owes the government shall have priority of payment over all other
debts is a necessary and proper law to enable the government to pay
its own debts, how can we say that the legal tender clause was not
necessary and proper to enable the government to borrow money to
carry on the war?
The creation of the United States Bank, and especially the power
granted to it to issue notes for circulation as money, was
strenuously resisted as without constitutional authority; but this
Court held that a bank of issue was necessary, in the sense of that
word as used in the Constitution, to enable the government to
collect, to transfer, and to pay out its revenues.
It was never claimed that the government could find no
Page 75 U. S. 636
other means to do this. It could not then be denied, nor has it
ever been, that other means more clearly within the competency of
Congress existed, nor that a bank of deposit might possibly have
answered without a circulation. But because that was the most
fitting, useful, and efficient mode of doing what Congress was
authorized to do, it was held to be necessary by this Court. The
necessity in that case is much less apparent to me than in the
adoption of the legal tender clause.
In
Veazie Bank v. Fenno, decided at the present term,
[
Footnote 2/3] this Court held
after full consideration that it was the privilege of Congress to
furnish to the country the currency to be used by it in the
transaction of business, whether this was done by means of coin, of
the notes of the United States, or of banks created by Congress.
And that as a means of making this power of Congress efficient,
that body could make this currency exclusive by taxing out of
existence any currency authorized by the states. It was said
"that having, in the exercise of undoubted constitutional power,
undertaken to provide a currency for the whole country, it cannot
be questioned that Congress may constitutionally secure the benefit
of it to the people by appropriate means."
Which is the more appropriate and effectual means of making the
currency established by Congress useful, acceptable, perfect -- the
taxing of all other currency out of existence or giving to that
furnished by the government the quality of lawful tender for debts?
The latter is a means directly conducive to the end to be attained,
a means which attains the end more promptly and more perfectly than
any other means can do. The former is a remote and uncertain means
in its effect, and is liable to the serious objection that it
interferes with state legislation. If Congress can, however, under
its implied power, protect and foster this currency by such means
as destructive taxation on state bank circulation, it seems strange
indeed if it cannot adopt the more appropriate and the more
effectual means of declaring these notes
Page 75 U. S. 637
of its own issue, for the redemption of which its faith is
pledged, a lawful tender in payment of debts.
But it is said that the law is in conflict with the spirit, if
not the letter, of several provisions of the Constitution.
Undoubtedly it is a law impairing the obligation of contracts made
before its passage. But while the Constitution forbids the states
to pass such laws, it does not forbid Congress. On the contrary,
Congress is expressly authorized to establish a uniform system of
bankruptcy, the essence of which is to discharge debtors from the
obligation of their contracts; and in pursuance of this power
Congress has three times passed such a law, which in every instance
operated on contracts made before it was passed. Such a law is now
in force, yet its constitutionality has never been questioned. How
it can be in accordance with the spirit of the Constitution to
destroy directly the creditor's contract for the sake of the
individual debtor, but contrary to its spirit to affect remotely
its value for the safety of the nation, it is difficult to
perceive.
So it is said that the provisions that private property shall
not be taken for public use without due compensation and that no
person shall be deprived of life, liberty, or property without due
course of law are opposed to the acts under consideration.
The argument is too vague for my perception by which the
indirect effect of a great public measure in depreciating the value
of lands, stocks, bonds, and other contracts renders such a law
invalid as taking private property for public use or as depriving
the owner of it without due course of law.
A declaration of war with a maritime power would thus be
unconstitutional because the value of every ship abroad is lessened
twenty-five or thirty percent, and those at home almost as much.
The abolition of the tariff on iron or sugar would in like manner
destroy the furnaces and sink the capital employed in the
manufacture of these articles. Yet no statesman, however warm an
advocate of high tariff, has claimed that to abolish such duties
would be unconstitutional as taking private property.
If the principle be sound, every successive issue of
government
Page 75 U. S. 638
bonds during the war was void because, by increasing the public
debt, it made those already in private hands less valuable.
This whole argument of the injustice of the law, an injustice
which if it ever existed will be repeated by now holding it wholly
void, and of its opposition to the spirit of the Constitution is
too abstract and intangible for application to courts of justice,
and is, above all, dangerous as a ground on which to declare the
legislation of Congress void by the decision of a court. It would
authorize this Court to enforce theoretical views of the genius of
the government or vague notions of the spirit of the Constitution
and of abstract justice, by declaring void laws which did not
square with those views. It substitutes our ideas of policy for
judicial construction, an undefined code of ethics for the
Constitution, and a court of justice for the national
legislature.
Upon the enactment of these legal tender laws, they were
received with almost universal acquiescence as valid. Payments were
made in the legal tender notes for debts in existence when the law
was passed, to the amount of thousands of millions of dollars,
though gold was the only lawful tender when the debts were
contracted. A great if not larger amount is now due under contracts
made since their passage, under the belief that these legal tenders
would be valid payment.
The two houses of Congress, the President who signed the bill,
and fifteen state courts, being all but one that has passed upon
the question, have expressed their belief in the constitutionality
of these laws.
With all this great weight of authority, this strong concurrence
of opinion among those who have passed upon the question, before we
have been called to decide it, whose duty it was as much as it is
ours to pass upon it in the light of the Constitution, are we to
reverse their action, to disturb contracts, to declare the law
void, because the necessity for its enactment does not appear so
strong to us as it did to Congress or so clear as it was to other
courts?
Such is not my idea of the relative functions of the
legislative
Page 75 U. S. 639
and judicial departments of the government. Where there is a
choice of means, the selection is with Congress, not the court. If
the act to be considered is in any sense essential to the execution
of an acknowledged power, the degree of that necessity is for the
legislature, and not for the court, to determine. In the case in
Wheaton from which I have already quoted so fully, the Court says
that
"Where the law is not prohibited and is really calculated to
effect any of the objects entrusted to the government, to undertake
here to inquire into the degree of its necessity would be to pass
the line which circumscribes the judicial department and to tread
on legislative ground. This Court disclaims all pretenses to such a
power."
This sound exposition of the duties of the Court in this class
of cases relieves me from any embarrassment or hesitation in the
case before me. If I had entertained doubts of the
constitutionality of the law, I must have held the law valid until
those doubts became convictions. But as I have a very decided
opinion that Congress acted within the scope of its authority, I
must hold the law to be constitutional, and dissent from the
opinion of the Court.
[
Footnote 2/1]
6 U. S. 2 Cranch
358.
[
Footnote 2/2]
17 U. S. 4 Wheat.
316.
[
Footnote 2/3]
Supra, <|75 U.S. 533|>533.