1. Under contracts entered into by an oil company with
independent dealers in petroleum products and automobile
accessories, the dealer agreed to purchase exclusively from the
company all of his requirements of one or more of the products
marketed by the company. In 1947, the contracts affected a gross
business of $58,000,000, comprising 6.7% of the total in a
seven-state area in which the company sold its products.
Held: the contracts were violative of § 3 of the
Clayton Act and the company was properly enjoined from enforcing or
entering into them. Pp.
337 U. S.
294-314.
2. The requirement of § 3 of the Clayton Act of a showing that
the effect of the contracts "may be to substantially lessen
competition" is here satisfied by proof that competition has been
foreclosed in a substantial share of the line of commerce affected.
Pp.
337 U. S.
299-314.
(a) In view of the widespread adoption of such contracts by the
company's competitors and the availability of alternative ways of
obtaining an assured market, evidence that competitive activity has
not actually declined is inconclusive. P.
337 U. S.
314.
(b) The company's use of the contracts creates just such a
potential clog on competition as it was the purpose of § 3 to
remove wherever, were it to become actual, it would impede a
substantial amount of competitive activity. P.
337 U. S.
314.
3. The fact that nearly all the products sold by the company to
California dealers are produced in that State does not exempt the
company's requirements contracts with California dealers as not
substantially affecting interstate commerce, since the effect of
those contracts is to prevent the California dealers from dealing
with out-of-State as well as local suppliers, and thus to lessen
competition in both interstate and intrastate commerce.
Addyston Pipe & Steel Co. v. United States,
175 U. S. 211,
distinguished. Pp.
337 U. S.
314-315.
78 F.
Supp. 850 affirmed.
Page 337 U. S. 294
In a suit brought by the United States under the antitrust laws,
the District Court enjoined an oil company and its wholly owned
subsidiary from enforcing or entering into exclusive supply
contracts with independent dealers in petroleum products and
automobile accessories.
78 F.
Supp. 850. The companies appealed directly to this Court.
Affirmed, p.
337 U. S.
315.
MR. JUSTICE FRANKFURTER delivered the opinion of the Court.
This is an appeal to review a decree enjoining the Standard Oil
Company of California and its wholly owned subsidiary, Standard
Stations, Inc., [
Footnote 1]
from enforcing or entering exclusive supply contracts with any
independent dealer in petroleum products and automobile
accessories. The use of such contracts was successfully assailed by
the United States as violative of § 1 of the Sherman Act [
Footnote 2] and § 3 of the Clayton Act.
[
Footnote 3]
Page 337 U. S. 295
The Standard Oil Company of California, a Delaware corporation,
owns petroleum-producing resources and refining plants in
California and sells petroleum products in what has been termed in
these proceedings the "Western area" -- Arizona, California, Idaho,
Nevada, Oregon, Utah and Washington. It sells through its own
service stations, to the operators of independent service stations,
and to industrial users. It is the largest seller of gasoline in
the area. In 1946, its combined sales amounted to 23% of the total
taxable gallonage sold there in that year: sales by company-owned
service stations constituted 6.8% of the total, sales under
exclusive dealing contracts with independent service stations, 6.7%
of the total; the remainder were sales to industrial users. Retail
service station sales by Standard's six leading competitors
absorbed 42.5% of the total taxable gallonage; the remaining retail
sales were divided between more than seventy small companies. It is
undisputed that Standard's major competitors employ similar
exclusive dealing arrangements. In 1948, only 1.6% of retail
outlets were what is known as "split-pump" stations, that is, sold
the gasoline of more than one supplier.
Exclusive supply contracts with Standard had been entered, as of
March 12, 1947, by the operators of 5,937 independent stations, or
16% of the retail gasoline outlets in the Western area, which
purchased from Standard in 1947 $57,646,233 worth of gasoline
and
Page 337 U. S. 296
$8,200,089.21 worth of other products. Some outlets are covered
by more than one contract, so that, in all, about 8,000 exclusive
supply contracts are here in issue. These are of several types, but
a feature common to each is the dealer's undertaking to purchase
from Standard all his requirements of one or more products. Two
types, covering 2,777 outlets, bind the dealer to purchase of
Standard all his requirements of gasoline and other petroleum
product as well as tires, tubes, and batteries. The remaining
written agreements, 4,368 in number, bind the dealer to purchase of
Standard all his requirements of petroleum products only. It was
also found that independent dealers had entered 742 oral contracts
by which they agreed to sell only Standard's gasoline. In some
instances, dealers who contracted to purchase from Standard all
their requirements of tires, tubes, and batteries, had also orally
agreed to purchase of Standard their requirements of other
automobile accessories. Of the written agreements, 2,712 were for
varying specified terms; the rest were effective from year to year,
but terminable "at the end of the first 6 months of any contract
year, or at the end of any such year, by giving to the other at
least 30 days prior thereto written notice. . . ." Before 1934,
Standard's sales of petroleum products through independent service
stations were made pursuant to agency agreements, but, in that
year, Standard adopted the first of its several requirements
purchase contract forms, and, by 1938, requirements contracts had
wholly superseded the agency method of distribution.
Between 1936 and 1946, Standard's sales of gasoline through
independent dealers remained at a practically constant proportion
of the area's total sales; its sales of lubricating oil declined
slightly during that period from 6.2% to 5% of the total. Its
proportionate sales of tires and batteries for 1946 were slightly
higher than they were in 1936, though somewhat lower than for
some
Page 337 U. S. 297
intervening years; they have never, as to either of these
products, exceeded 2% of the total sales in the Western area.
Since § 3 of the Clayton Act was directed to prohibiting
specific practices even though not covered by the broad terms of
the Sherman Act, [
Footnote 4]
it is appropriate to consider first whether the enjoined contracts
fall within the prohibition of the narrower Act. The relevant
provisions of § 3 are:
"It shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce, in the
course of such commerce, to lease or make a sale or contract for
sale of goods, wares, merchandise, machinery, supplies, or other
commodities, whether patented or unpatented, for use, consumption,
or resale within the United States . . . on the condition,
agreement, or understanding that the lessee or purchaser thereof
shall not use or deal in the goods . . . of a competitor or
competitors of the . . . seller, where the effect of such lease,
sale, or contract for sale or such condition, agreement, or
understanding may be to substantially lessen competition or tend to
create a monopoly in any line of commerce."
Obviously the contracts here at issue would be proscribed if § 3
stopped short of the qualifying clause beginning, "where the effect
of such lease, sale, or contract
Page 337 U. S. 298
for sale. . . ." If effect is to be given that clause, however,
it is by no means obvious, in view of Standard's minority share of
the "line of commerce" involved, of the fact that that share has
not recently increased, and of the claims of these contracts to
economic utility, that the effect of the contracts may be to lessen
competition or tend to create a monopoly. It is the qualifying
clause therefore which must be construed.
The District Court held that the requirement of showing an
actual or potential lessening of competition or a tendency to
establish monopoly was adequately met by proof that the contracts
covered "a substantial number of outlets and a substantial amount
of products, whether considered comparatively or not." Given such
quantitative substantiality, the substantial lessening of
competition -- so the court reasoned -- is an automatic result, for
the very existence of such contracts denies dealers opportunity to
deal in the products of competing suppliers and excludes suppliers
from access to the outlets controlled by those dealers. Having
adopted this standard of proof, the court excluded as immaterial
testimony bearing on
"the commercial merits or demerits of the present system as
contrasted with a system which prevailed prior to its establishment
and which would prevail if the court declared the present
arrangement [invalid]."
The court likewise deemed it unnecessary to make findings, on
the basis of evidence that was admitted, whether the number of
Standard's competitors had increased or decreased since the
inauguration of the requirements contract system, whether the
number of their dealers had increased or decreased, and as to other
matters which would have shed light on the comparative status of
Standard and its competitors before and after the adoption of that
system. The court concluded:
"Grant that, on a comparative basis, and in relation to the
entire trade in these products in the area,
Page 337 U. S. 299
the restraint is not integral. Admit also that control of
distribution results in lessening of costs and that its abandonment
might increase costs. . . . Concede further that the arrangement
was entered into in good faith, with the honest belief that control
of distribution and consequent concentration of representation were
economically beneficial to the industry and to the public, that
they have continued for over fifteen years openly, notoriously, and
unmolested by the Government, and have been practised by other
major oil companies competing with Standard, that the number of
Standard outlets so controlled may have decreased, and the quantity
of products supplied to them may have declined, on a comparative
basis. Nevertheless, as I read the latest cases of the Supreme
Court, I am compelled to find the practices here involved to be
violative of both statutes. For they affect injuriously a sizeable
part of interstate commerce, or -- to use the current phrase -- 'an
appreciable segment' of interstate commerce."
The issue before us, therefore, is whether the requirement of
showing that the effect of the agreements "may be to substantially
lessen competition" may be met simply by proof that a substantial
portion of commerce is affected, or whether it must also be
demonstrated that competitive activity has actually diminished or
probably will diminish. [
Footnote
5]
Page 337 U. S. 300
Since the Clayton Act became effective, this Court has passed on
the applicability of § 3 in eight cases, in five of which it upheld
determinations that the challenged agreement was violative of that
Section. Three of these --
United Shoe Machinery Corp. v.
United States, 258 U. S. 451;
International Business Machines Corp. v. United States,
298 U. S. 131;
International Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.
S. 392 -- involved contracts tying to the use of a
patented article all purchases of an unpatented product used in
connection with the patented article. The other two cases --
Standard Fashion Co. v. Magrane-Houston Co., 258 U.
S. 346;
Fashion Originators' Guild v. Federal Trade
Comm'n, 312 U. S. 457 --
involved requirements contracts not unlike those here in issue.
The
Standard Fashion case, the first of the five
holding that the Act had been violated, settled one question of
interpretation of § 3. The Court said:
"Section 3 condemns sales or agreements where the effect of such
sale or contract of sale 'may' be to substantially lessen
competition or tend to create monopoly. . . . But we do not think
that the purpose in using the word 'may' was to prohibit the mere
possibility of the consequences described. It was intended to
prevent such agreements as would, under the circumstances
disclosed, probably lessen competition, or create an actual
tendency to monopoly."
258 U.S. at
258 U. S.
356-357.
See also Federal Trade Comm'n v. Morton
Salt Co., 334 U. S. 37,
334 U. S. 46, n.
14.
Page 337 U. S. 301
The Court went on to add that the fact that the Section "was not
intended to reach every remote lessening of competition is shown in
the requirement that such lessening must be substantial," but,
because it deemed the finding of two lower courts that the
contracts in question did substantially lessen competition and tend
to create monopoly amply supported by evidence that the defendant
controlled two-fifths of the nation's pattern agencies, it did not
pause to indicate where the line between a "remote" and a
"substantial" lessening should be drawn.
All but one of the later cases also regarded domination of the
market as sufficient, in itself, to support the inference that
competition had been or probably would be lessened. In the
United Shoe Machinery case, referring,
inter
alia, to the clause incorporated in all United's leases of
patented machinery requiring the use by the lessee of materials
supplied by United, the Court observed:
"That such restrictive and tying agreements must necessarily
lessen competition and tend to monopoly is, we believe, . . .
apparent. When it is considered that the United Company occupies a
dominating position in supplying shoe machinery of the classes
involved, these covenants, signed by the lessee and binding upon
him, effectually prevent him from acquiring the machinery of a
competitor of the lessor except at the risk of forfeiting the right
to use the machines furnished by the United Company, which may be
absolutely essential to the prosecution and success of his
business."
258 U.S. at
258 U. S.
457-458.
In the
International Business Machines case, the
defendants were the sole manufacturers of a patented tabulating
machine requiring the use of unpatented cards. The lessees of the
machines were bound by tying clauses to use in them only the cards
supplied by the defendants,
Page 337 U. S. 302
who, between them, divided the whole of the $3,000,000 annual
gross of this business also. The Court concluded:
"These facts and others which we do not stop to enumerate can
leave no doubt that the effect of the condition in appellant's
leases 'may be to substantially lessen competition,' and that it
tends to create monopoly and has in fact been an important and
effective step in the creation of monopoly."
298 U.S. at
298 U. S.
136.
The
Fashion Originators' Guild case involved an
association of dress manufacturers which sold more than 60% of all
but the cheapest women's garments. In rejecting the relevance of
evidence that the Guild's use of requirements contracts was a
"reasonable and necessary" measure of protection against "the
devastating evils growing from the pirating of original designs,"
the Court again emphasized the presence and the consequences of
economic power:
"The purpose and object of this combination, its potential
power, its tendency to monopoly, the coercion it could and did
practice upon a rival method of competition, all brought it within
the policy of the prohibition declared by the Sherman and Clayton
Acts."
312 U.S. at
312 U. S.
467-468.
It is thus apparent that none of these cases controls the
disposition of the present appeal, for Standard's share of the
retail market for gasoline, even including sales through
company-owned stations, is hardly large enough to conclude as a
matter of law that it occupies a dominant position, nor did the
trial court so find. The cases do indicate, however, that some sort
of showing as to the actual or probable economic consequences of
the agreements, if only the inferences to be drawn from the fact of
dominant power, is important, and, to that extent, they tend to
support appellant's position.
Page 337 U. S. 303
Two of the three cases decided by this Court which have held § 3
inapplicable also lend support to the view that such a showing is
necessary. These are
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Sinclair Co.,
261 U. S. 463, and
Pick Mfg. Co. v. General Motors Corp., 299 U. S.
3. The third --
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Curtis Pub.
Co., 260 U. S. 568 --
went off on the ground that the contract involved was one of
agency, and so is of no present relevance. The
Sinclair
case involved the lease of gasoline pumps and storage tanks on
condition that the dealer would use them only for Sinclair's
gasoline, but Sinclair did not own patents on the pumps or tanks,
and evidently did not otherwise control their supply. Although the
Trade Commission had found that few dealers needed more than one
pump, the Court concluded that "the record does not show that the
probable effect of the practise will be unduly to lessen
competition." 261 U.S. at
261 U. S. 475.
The basis of this conclusion was thus summarized:
"Many competitors seek to sell excellent brands of gasoline, and
no one of them is essential to the retail business. The lessee is
free to buy wherever he chooses; he may freely accept and use as
many pumps as he wishes, and may discontinue any or all of them. He
may carry on business as his judgment dictates and his means
permit, save only that he cannot use the lessor's equipment for
dispensing another's brand. By investing a comparatively small sum,
he can buy an outfit and use it without hindrance. He can have
respondent's gasoline, with the pump or without the pump, and many
competitors seek to supply his needs."
Id. at
261 U. S.
474.
The present case differs, of course, in the fact that a dealer
who has entered a requirements contract with Standard cannot,
consistently with that contract, sell the petroleum products of a
competitor of Standard's, no
Page 337 U. S. 304
matter how many pumps he has, [
Footnote 6] but the case is significant for the importance
it attaches, in the absence of a showing that the supplier
dominated the market, to the practical effect of the contracts. The
same is true of the
Pick case, in which this Court
affirmed in a brief per curiam opinion the finding of the District
Court, concurred in by the Court of Appeals, that the effect of
contracts by which dealers agreed not to sell other automobile
parts than those manufactured by General Motors "had not been in
any way substantially to lessen competition or to create a monopoly
in any line of commerce." 299 U.S. at
299 U. S. 4.
But then came
International Salt Co. v. United States,
332 U. S. 392.
That decision, at least as to contracts tying the sale of a
nonpatented to a patented product, rejected the necessity of
demonstrating economic consequences once it has been established
that "the volume of business affected" is not "insignificant or
insubstantial" and that the effect of the contracts is to
"foreclose competitors from [a] substantial market."
Id.
at
332 U. S. 396.
Upon that basis, we affirmed a summary judgment granting an
injunction against the leasing of machines for the utilization of
salt products on the condition that the lessee use in
Page 337 U. S. 305
them only salt supplied by defendant. It was established by
pleadings or admissions that defendant was the country's largest
producer of salt for industrial purposes, that it owned patents on
the leased machines, that about 900 leases were outstanding, and
that, in 1944, defendant sold about $500,000 worth of salt for use
in these machines. It was not established that equivalent machines
were unobtainable, it was not indicated what proportion of the
business of supplying such machines was controlled by defendant,
and it was deemed irrelevant that there was no evidence as to the
actual effect of the tying clauses upon competition. [
Footnote 7] It is clear therefore that,
unless a distinction is to be drawn for purposes of the
applicability of § 3 between requirements contracts and contracts
tying the sale of a nonpatented to a patented product, the showing
that Standard's requirements contracts affected a gross business of
$58,000,000 comprising 6.7% of the total in the area goes far
toward supporting the inference that competition has been or
probably will be substantially lessened. [
Footnote 8]
In favor of confining the standard laid down by the
International Salt case to tying agreements, important
economic differences may be noted. Tying agreements serve hardly
any purpose beyond the suppression of competition.
Page 337 U. S. 306
The justification most often advanced in their defense -- the
protection of the goodwill of the manufacturer of the tying device
-- fails in the usual situation because specification of the type
and quality of the product to be used in connection with the tying
device is protection enough. If the manufacturer's brand of the
tied product is, in fact, superior to that of competitors, the
buyer will presumably choose it anyway. The only situation, indeed,
in which the protection of good will may necessitate the use of
tying clauses is where specifications for a substitute would be so
detailed that they could not practicably be supplied. In the usual
case, only the prospect of reducing competition would persuade a
seller to adopt such a contract, and only his control of the supply
of the tying device, whether conferred by patent monopoly or
otherwise obtained, could induce a buyer to enter one.
See
Miller, Unfair Competition 199
et seq. (1941); Note, 49
Col.L.Rev. 241, 246 (1949). The existence of market control of the
tying device therefore affords a strong foundation for the
presumption that it has been or probably will be used to limit
competition in the tied product also.
Requirements contracts, on the other hand, may well be of
economic advantage to buyers as well as to sellers, and thus
indirectly of advantage to the consuming public. In the case of the
buyer, they may assure supply, afford protection against rises in
price, enable long-term planning on the basis of known costs,
[
Footnote 9] and obviate the
expense and risk of storage in the quantity necessary for a
commodity having a fluctuating demand. From the seller's point of
view, requirements contracts may make possible the substantial
reduction of selling expenses, give protection
Page 337 U. S. 307
against price fluctuations, and -- of particular advantage to a
newcomer to the field to whom it is important to know what capital
expenditures are justified -- offer the possibility of a
predictable market.
See Stockhausen, The Commercial and
Anti-Trust Aspects of Term Requirements Contracts, 23
N.Y.U.L.Q.Rev. 412, 413-14 (1948). They may be useful, moreover, to
a seller trying to establish a foothold against the counterattacks
of entrenched competitors.
See id. at 424
et seq.;
Excelsior Motor Mfg. & Supply Co. v. Sound Equipment,
Inc., 73 F.2d 725, 728;
General Talking Pictures Corp. v.
American Tel. & Tel. Co., 18 F.
Supp. 650, 666. [
Footnote
10] Since these advantages of requirements contracts may often
be sufficient to account for their use, the coverage by such
contracts of a substantial amount of business affords a weaker
basis for the inference that competition may be lessened than would
similar coverage by tying clauses, especially where use of the
latter is combined with market control of the tying device. A
patent, moreover, although in fact there may be many competing
substitutes for the patented article, is at least
prima
facie evidence of such control. And so we could not dispose of
this case merely by citing
International Salt Co. v. United
States, 332 U. S. 392.
Thus, even though the qualifying clause of § 3 is appended
without distinction of terms equally to the prohibition of tying
clauses and of requirements contracts, pertinent considerations
support, certainly as a matter of economic reasoning, varying
standards as to each for the
Page 337 U. S. 308
proof necessary to fulfill the conditions of that clause. If
this distinction were accepted, various tests of the economic
usefulness or restrictive effect of requirements contracts would
become relevant. Among them would be evidence that competition has
flourished despite use of the contracts and, under this test, much
of the evidence tendered by appellant in this case would be
important.
See, as examples of the consideration of such
evidence,
B. S. Pearsall Butter Co. v. Federal Trade
Comm'n, 292 F. 720;
Pick Mfg. Co. v. General Motors
Corp., 80 F.2d 641, 644,
aff'd, 299 U. S.
3. Likewise bearing on whether or not the contracts were
being used to suppress competition would be the conformity of the
length of their term to the reasonable requirements of the field of
commerce in which they were used.
See Corn Products Refining
Co. v. Federal Trade Comm'n, 144 F.2d 211, 220,
aff'd, 324 U. S. 324 U.S.
726;
United States v. Pullman Co., 50 F. Supp.
123, 127-129. Still another test would be the status of the
defendant as a struggling newcomer or an established competitor.
Perhaps most important, however, would be the defendant's degree of
market control, for the greater the dominance of his position, the
stronger the inference that an important factor in attaining and
maintaining that position has been the use of requirements
contracts to stifle competition, rather than to serve legitimate
economic needs.
See Standard Fashion Co. v. Magrane-Houston
Co., supra, 258 U. S. 346;
Fashion Originators' Guild v. Federal Trade Comm'n, supra,
312 U. S. 457.
[
Footnote 11]
Yet serious difficulties would attend the attempt to apply these
tests. We may assume, as did the court below, that no improvement
of Standard's competitive
Page 337 U. S. 309
position has coincided with the period during which the
requirements contract system of distribution has been in effect. We
may assume further that the duration of the contracts is not
excessive, and that Standard does not by itself dominate the
market. But Standard was a major competitor when the present system
was adopted, and it is possible that its position would have
deteriorated but for the adoption of that system. When it is
remembered that all the other major suppliers have also been using
requirements contracts, and when it is noted that the relative
share of the business which fell to each has remained about the
same during the period of their use, [
Footnote 12] it would not be far-fetched to infer that
their effect has been to enable the established suppliers
individually to maintain their own standing and at the same time
collectively, even though not collusively, to prevent a late
arrival from wresting away more than an insignificant portion of
the market. If, indeed, this were a result of the system, it would
seem unimportant that a short-run byproduct of stability may have
been greater efficiency and lower costs, for it is the theory of
the antitrust laws that the long-run advantage of the community
depends upon the removal of restraints upon competition.
See
Fashion Originators' Guild v. Federal Trade Comm'n,
312 U. S. 457,
312 U. S.
467-468;
United States v. Aluminum Co. of
America, 148 F.2d 416, 427-429.
Moreover, to demand that bare inference be supported by evidence
as to what would have happened but for
Page 337 U. S. 310
the adoption of the practice that was in fact, adopted or to
require firm prediction of an increase of competition as a probable
result of ordering the abandonment of the practice, would be a
standard of proof, if not virtually impossible to meet, at least
most ill suited for ascertainment by courts. [
Footnote 13] Before the system of requirements
contracts was instituted, Standard sold gasoline through
independent service station operators as its agents, and it might
revert to this system if the judgment below were sustained. Or it
might, as opportunity presented itself, add service stations now
operated independently to the number managed by its subsidiary,
Standard Stations, Inc. From the point of view of maintaining or
extending competitive advantage, either of these alternatives would
be just as effective as the use of requirements contracts,
although, of course, insofar as they resulted in a tendency to
monopoly they might encounter the anti-monopoly provisions of the
Sherman Act.
See United States v. Aluminum Co. of America,
148 F.2d 416. As appellant points out, dealers might order
petroleum products in quantities sufficient to meet their estimated
needs for the period during which requirements contracts are now
effective, and even that would foreclose competition to some
degree. So long as these diverse ways of restricting competition
remain open, therefore, there can be no conclusive proof that the
use of requirements contracts has actually reduced
Page 337 U. S. 311
competition below the level which it would otherwise have
reached or maintained.
We are dealing here with a particular form of agreement
specified by § 3, and not with different arrangements, by way of
integration or otherwise, that may tend to lessen competition. To
interpret that section as requiring proof that competition has
actually diminished would make its very explicitness a means of
conferring immunity upon the practices which it singles out.
Congress has authoritatively determined that those practices are
detrimental where their effect may be to lessen competition. It has
not left at large for determination in each case the ultimate
demands of the "public interest," as the English lawmakers,
considering and finding inapplicable to their own situation our
experience with the specific prohibition of trade practices
legislatively determined to be undesirable, have recently chosen to
do. [
Footnote 14] Though it
may be that such an alternative to the present system as buying out
independent dealers and making
Page 337 U. S. 312
them dependent employees of Standard Stations, Inc., would be a
greater detriment to the public interest than perpetuation of the
system, this is an issue, like the choice between greater
efficiency and freer competition, that has not been submitted to
our decision. We are faced, not with a broadly phrased expression
of general policy, but merely a broadly phrased qualification of an
otherwise narrowly directed statutory provision.
In this connection, it is significant that the qualifying
language was not added until after the House and Senate bills
reached Conference. The conferees responsible for adding that
language were at pains, in answering protestations that the
qualifying clause seriously weakened the Section, to disclaim any
intention seriously to augment the burden of proof to be sustained
in establishing violation of it. [
Footnote 15] It seems hardly likely that, having with one
hand set up an express prohibition against a practice thought to be
beyond the reach of the Sherman Act, Congress meant, with the other
hand, to reestablish the necessity of meeting the same tests of
detriment to the public interest as that Act had been interpreted
as requiring. [
Footnote
16]
Page 337 U. S. 313
Yet the economic investigation which appellant would have us
require is of the same broad scope as was adumbrated with reference
to unreasonable restraints of trade in
Chicago Board of Trade
v. United States, 246 U. S. 231.
[
Footnote 17] To insist upon
such an investigation would be to stultify the force of Congress'
declaration that requirements contracts are to be prohibited
wherever their effect "may be" to substantially lessen competition.
If in fact it is economically desirable for service stations to
confine themselves to the sale of the petroleum products of a
single supplier, they will continue
Page 337 U. S. 314
to do so though not bound by contract, and if in fact it is
important to retail dealers to assure the supply of their
requirements by obtaining the commitment of a single supplier to
fulfill them, competition for their patronage should enable them to
insist upon such an arrangement without binding them to refrain
from looking elsewhere.
We conclude, therefore, that the qualifying clause of § 3 is
satisfied by proof that competition has been foreclosed in a
substantial share of the line of commerce affected. It cannot be
gainsaid that observance by a dealer of his requirements contract
with Standard does effectively foreclose whatever opportunity there
might be for competing suppliers to attract his patronage, and it
is clear that the affected proportion of retail sales of petroleum
products is substantial. In view of the widespread adoption of such
contracts by Standard's competitors and the availability of
alternative ways of obtaining an assured market, evidence that
competitive activity has not actually declined is inconclusive.
Standard's use of the contracts creates just such a potential clog
on competition as it was the purpose of § 3 to remove wherever,
were it to become actual, it would impede a substantial amount of
competitive activity.
Since the decree below is sustained by our interpretation of § 3
of the Clayton Act, we need not go on to consider whether it might
also be sustained by § 1 of the Sherman Act.
One last point remains to be disposed of. Appellant contends
that its requirements contracts with California dealers, because
nearly all the products sold to them are produced in California, do
not substantially affect interstate commerce, and therefore should
have been exempted from the decree. It finds support for this
contention in
Addyston Pipe & Steel Co. v. United
States, 175 U. S. 211,
175 U. S. 247.
But the effect of appellant's requirements contracts with
California retail dealers is to prevent them
Page 337 U. S. 315
from dealing with suppliers from outside the State as well as
within the State, and is thus to lessen competition in both
interstate and intrastate commerce. Appellant has not suggested
that, if these dealers were not bound by their contracts with it,
that they would continue to purchase only products originating
within the State. The
Addyston case, on the other hand,
dealt not with the diminution of competition between suppliers
brought about by the action of one at the expense of the rest,
whether within or without the State, but a combination among them
to restrain competition. Modification of the decree was required
only to make clear that it did not reach a combination among the
defendants doing business in a single State which was confined to
transactions taking place within that same State.
The judgment below is
Affirmed.
[
Footnote 1]
Standard Stations, Inc., has no independent status in these
proceedings; since 1944, its activities have been confined to
managing service stations owned by the Standard Oil Co. of
California.
[
Footnote 2]
"Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise,
or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several
States, or with foreign nations, is hereby declared to be illegal.
. . ."
26 Stat. 209, as amended, 50 Stat. 693, 15 U.S.C. § 1.
[
Footnote 3]
"It shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce, in the
course of such commerce, to lease or make a sale or contract for
sale of goods, wares, merchandise, machinery, supplies, or other
commodities, whether patented or unpatented, for use, consumption,
or resale within the United States or any Territory thereof or the
District of Columbia or any insular possession or other place under
the jurisdiction of the United States, or fix a price charged
therefor, or discount from, or rebate upon, such price, on the
condition, agreement, or understanding that the lessee or purchaser
thereof shall not use or deal in the goods, wares, merchandise,
machinery, supplies, or other commodities of a competitor or
competitors of the lessor or seller, where the effect of such
lease, sale, or contract for sale or such condition, agreement, or
understanding may be to substantially lessen competition or tend to
create a monopoly in any line of commerce."
38 Stat. 731, 15 U.S.C. § 14.
[
Footnote 4]
After the Clayton Bill, H.R. 15657, had passed the House, the
Senate struck § 4, the section prohibiting tying clauses and
requirements contracts, on the ground that such practices were
subject to condemnation by the Federal Trade Commission under the
then pending Trade Commission Bill. In support of a motion to
reconsider this vote, Senator Reed of Missouri argued that the
Trade Commission would be unlikely to outlaw agreements of a type
held by this Court, in
Henry v. A. B. Dick Co.,
224 U. S. 1, not to
be in violation of the Sherman Act.
See 51 Cong.Rec.
14088, 14090-92. The motion was agreed to.
Id. at
14223.
[
Footnote 5]
It is clear, of course, that the "line of commerce" affected
need not be nationwide, at least where the purchasers cannot, as a
practical matter, turn to suppliers outside their own area.
Although the effect on competition will be quantitatively the same
if a given volume of the industry's business is assumed to be
covered, whether or not the affected sources of supply are those of
the industry as a whole or only those of a particular region, a
purely quantitative measure of this effect is inadequate, because
the narrower the area of competition, the greater the comparative
effect on the area's competitors. Since it is the preservation of
competition which is at stake, the significant proportion of
coverage is that within the area of effective competition.
Cf.
Indiana Farmer's Guide Publishing Co. v. Prairie Farmer Publishing
Co., 293 U. S. 268,
293 U. S. 279;
United States v. Yellow Cab Co., 332 U.
S. 218,
332 U. S. 226.
The criteria of substantiality deemed relevant in cases involving a
nationwide market are thus also relevant in measuring the effect of
Standard's requirements contracts in the seven-state Western
area.
[
Footnote 6]
Standard urges that the effect of its contracts is similarly
confined in view of the fact that they apply not to all sales by a
dealer, but only to those made through a designated service
station. Putting aside the fact that it does not appear that
dealers commonly own more than one service station, there is marked
difference between a contract which confines an entire retail
outlet to the sale of a single brand and a contract which merely
confines the use of a dispensing mechanism to a single brand:
service station sites, and therefore retail outlets, are limited in
number; the number of pumps which a dealer may choose to set up is
not, or so at least, the Court assumed in the
Sinclair
case. It is reasonable to assume therefore that competition between
suppliers is directed rather toward exclusive contracts with the
maximum number of strategically located outlets than toward
exclusive arrangements with dealers as such.
[
Footnote 7]
The Court considered and found inadequate defendant's attempt to
establish that the successful use of the machines depended upon a
quality of salt which only it could supply, but the Court's
willingness to consider such evidence does not weaken the holding
that coverage of a more than insignificant volume of business by
such tying clauses is an adequate basis for finding a lessening of
competition or a tendency to monopoly.
[
Footnote 8]
It may be noted in passing that the exclusive supply provisions
for tires, tubes, batteries, and other accessories which are a part
of some of Standard's contracts with dealers who have also agreed
to purchase their requirements of petroleum products should perhaps
be considered, as a matter of classification, tying, rather than
requirements, agreements.
[
Footnote 9]
This advantage is not conferred by Standard's contracts, each of
which provides that the price to be paid by the dealer is to be the
"Company's posted price to its dealers generally at time and place
of delivery."
[
Footnote 10]
Some members of the House opposed § 4 of H.R. 15657 (the
equivalent of what is now § 3) as denying this benefit to the
newcomer,
see 51 Cong.Rec.9267, and Representative McCoy
of New Jersey offered an amendment,
id. at 9398, to make
the agreements in question illegal only when entered "with the
intent of obtaining or establishing a monopoly or of destroying the
business of a competitor," which he and others supported on this
ground.
See id. at 9400-02, 9409. The amendment was
rejected.
Id. at 9410.
[
Footnote 11]
For an exposition of the considerations here summarized,
see Stockhausen, The Commercial and Anti-Trust Aspects of
Term and Requirements Contracts, 23 N.Y.U.L.Q.Rev. 412, 417-31
(1948).
[
Footnote 12]
Upon the request of Standard, its six largest competitors filled
out questionnaires showing the number of retail dealers who
distributed their products during the years 1937 through 1946.
Though their position relative to each other has fluctuated, the
figures show that as a group they have maintained or improved their
control of the market. Together with Standard, these six companies
distributed, as of 1946, through 26,439 of approximately 35,000
independent service stations in the Western area.
[
Footnote 13]
The dual system of enforcement provided for by the Clayton Act
must have contemplated standards of proof capable of administration
by the courts, as well as by the Federal Trade Commission and other
designated agencies.
See 38 Stat. 734, 736, as amended, 15
U.S.C. §§ 21, 25. Our interpretation of the Act therefore should
recognize that an appraisal of economic data which might be
practicable if only the latter were faced with the task may be
quite otherwise for judges unequipped for it either by experience
or by the availability of skilled assistance.
[
Footnote 14]
The Monopolies and Restrictive Practices (Inquiry and Control)
Act, 1948, adopted July 30, 1948, provides, as one mode of
procedure, for reference of restrictive trade practices by the
Board of Trade to a permanent Commission for investigation in order
to determine "whether any such things as are specified in the
reference . . . operate or may be expected to operate against the
public interest." 11 & 12 Geo. VI, c. 66, § 6(2). The Act does
not define what is meant by "the public interest," although, in §
14, it sets up broad criteria to be taken into account. It is
noteworthy, however, that, having established so broad a basis for
investigation, the Act entrusts the task to an expert body without
provision for judicial review. This approach was repeatedly
contrasted in debate with that of the United States.
See
449 H.C.Deb. 2046-47, 2058, 2063 (5th ser.1948); 157 H.L.Deb. 350
(5th ser.1948).
Compare § 5(2) of the Interstate Commerce
Act, as amended, 41 Stat. 480, 49 U.S.C. § 5(2), referring to the
Interstate Commerce Commission determination of the more defined
issues of "public interest" under review in
New York Central
Securities Corp. v. United States, 287 U. S.
12,
287 U. S. 24;
United States v. Lowden, 308 U. S. 225.
[
Footnote 15]
Representative Floyd of Arkansas, one of the managers on the
part of the House, explained the use of the word "substantially" as
deriving from the opinion of this Court in
Addyston Pipe &
Steel Co. v. United States, 175 U. S. 211, and
quoted the passage from
id. at
175 U. S. 229,
in which it is said that
"the power of Congress to regulate interstate commerce comprises
the right to enact a law prohibiting a citizen from entering into
these private contracts which directly and substantially, and not
merely indirectly, remotely, incidentally, and collaterally,
regulate to a greater or less degree commerce among the
States."
51 Cong.Rec. 16317-18. Senator Chilton, one of the managers on
the part of the Senate, denying that the clause weakened the bill,
stated that the words "where the effect may be" mean "where it is
possible for the effect to be."
Id. at 16002. Senator
Overman, also a Senate conferee, argued that even the elimination
of competition in a single town would substantially lessen
competition.
Id. at 15935.
[
Footnote 16]
See United States v. American Tobacco Co., 221 U.
S. 106,
221 U. S.
179:
"Applying the rule of reason to the construction of the statute,
it was held in the
Standard Oil Case that, as the words
'restraint of trade' at common law and in the law of this country
at the time of the adoption of the antitrust act only embraced acts
or contracts or agreements or combinations which operated to the
prejudice of the public interests by unduly restricting
competition, or unduly obstructing the due course of trade, or
which, either because of their inherent nature or effect, or
because of the evident purpose of the acts, etc., injuriously
restrained trade, that the words as used in the statute were
designed to have and did have but a like significance."
See also Handler, A Study of the Construction and
Enforcement of the Federal Antitrust Laws 3-9 (T.N.E.C. Monograph
No. 38, 1941).
Compare § 4 of the Australian Industries
Preservation Act, 1906, which forbids combinations entered "with
intent to restrain trade or commerce to the detriment of the
public," construed in
Attorney General v. Adelaide S.S.
Co., [1913] A.C. 781, as requiring proof of actual economic
detriment.
[
Footnote 17]
"The true test of legality is whether the restraint imposed is
such as merely regulates and perhaps thereby promotes competition,
or whether it is such as may suppress or even destroy competition.
To determine that question, the court must ordinarily consider the
facts peculiar to the business to which the restraint is applied;
its condition before and after the restraint was imposed; the
nature of the restraint, and its effect, actual or probable. The
history of the restraint, the evil believed to exist, the reason
for adopting the particular remedy, the purpose or end sought to be
attained, are all relevant facts."
246 U.S. at
246 U. S.
238.
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS.
The economic theories which the Court has read into the
Anti-Trust Laws have favored, rather than discouraged, monopoly. As
a result of the big business philosophy underlying
United
States v. United Shoe Machinery Co., 247 U. S.
32;
United States v. United States Steel Corp.,
251 U. S. 417;
United States v. International Harvester Co., 274 U.
S. 693, big business has become bigger and bigger.
Monopoly has flourished. Cartels have increased their hold on the
nation. The trusts wax strong. [
Footnote 2/1] There is less and less place for the
independent.
Page 337 U. S. 316
The full force of the Anti-Trust Laws has not been felt on our
economy. It has been deflected. Niggardly interpretations have
robbed those laws of much of their efficacy. There are exceptions.
Price fixing is illegal
per
Page 337 U. S. 317
se. [
Footnote 2/2] The
use of patents to obtain monopolies on unpatented articles is
condemned. [
Footnote 2/3] Monopoloy
that has been built as a result of unlawful tactics,
e.g.,
through practices that are restraints of trade, is broken up.
[
Footnote 2/4] But when it comes to
monopolies built in gentlemanly ways -- by mergers, purchases of
assets or control and the like -- the teeth have largely been drawn
from the Act.
Page 337 U. S. 318
We announced that the existence of monopoly power, coupled with
the purpose or intent to monopolize, was unlawful. [
Footnote 2/5] But, to date, that principle has not
shown bright promise in application. [
Footnote 2/6] Under the guise of increased efficiency,
big business has received approval for easy growth.
United
States v. Columbia Steel Co., 334 U.
S. 495, represents the current attitude of the Court on
this problem. In that case, United States Steel -- the giant of the
industry -- was allowed to fasten its tentacles tighter on the
economy by acquiring the assets of a steel company in the Far West
where competition was beginning to develop.
The increased concentration of industrial power in the hands of
a few has changed habits of thought. A new age has been introduced.
It is more and more an age of "monopoly competition." Monopoly
competition is a regime of friendly alliances, of quick and easy
accommodation of prices even without the benefit of trade
associations, of what Brandeis said was euphemistically called
"cooperation." [
Footnote 2/7] While
this is not true in all fields, it has become alarmingly apparent
in many.
The lessons Brandeis taught on the curse of bigness have largely
been forgotten in high places. Size is allowed to become a menace
to existing and putative competitors. Price control is allowed to
escape the influences of the competitive market and to gravitate
into the hands of the few. But, beyond all that, there is the
effect on the community when independents are swallowed up by the
trusts and entrepreneurs become employees of absentee
Page 337 U. S. 319
owners. Then there is a serious loss in citizenship. Local
leadership is diluted. He who was a leader in the village becomes
dependent on outsiders for his action and policy. Clerks
responsible to a superior in a distant place take the place of
resident proprietors beholden to no one. These are the prices which
the nation pays for the almost ceaseless growth in bigness on the
part of industry.
These problems may not appear on the surface to have
relationship to the case before us. But they go to the very heart
of the problem.
It is common knowledge that a host of filling stations in the
country are locally owned and operated. Others are owned and
operated by the big oil companies. This case involves directly only
the former. It pertains to requirements contracts that the oil
companies make with these independents. It is plain that a filling
station owner who is tied to an oil company for his supply of
products is not an available customer for the products of other
suppliers. The same is true of a filling station owner who
purchases his inventory a year in advance. His demand is withdrawn
from the market for the duration of the contract in the one case,
and for a year in the other. The result in each case is to lessen
competition if the standard is day-to-day purchases. Whether it is
a substantial lessening of competition within the meaning of the
Anti-Trust Laws is a question of degree, and may vary from industry
to industry.
The Court answers the question for the oil industry by a formula
which, under our decisions, promises to wipe out large segments of
independent filling station operators. The method of doing business
under requirements contracts at least keeps the independents alive.
They survive as small business units. The situation is not
ideal
Page 337 U. S. 320
from either their point of view [
Footnote 2/8] or that of the nation. But the alternative
which the Court offers is far worse from the point of view of
both.
The elimination of these requirements contracts sets the stage
for Standard and the other oil companies to build service station
empires of their own. The opinion of the Court does more than set
the stage for that development. It is an advisory opinion as well,
stating to the oil companies how they can with impunity build their
empires. The formula suggested by the Court is either the use of
the "agency" device, which in practical effect means control of
filling stations by the oil companies,
cf. Federal Trade
Commission v. Curtis Co., 260 U. S. 568, or
the outright acquisition of them by subsidiary corporations or
otherwise.
See United States v. Columbia Steel Co., supra.
Under the approved judicial doctrine, either of those devices means
increasing the monopoly of the oil companies over the retail
field.
When the choice is thus given, I dissent from the outlawry of
the requirements contract on the present facts. The effect which it
has on competition in this field is minor as compared to the damage
which will flow from the judicially approved formula for the growth
of bigness tendered by the Court as an alternative. Our choice must
be made on the basis not of abstractions, but of the realities of
modern industrial life.
Today there is vigorous competition between the oil companies
for the market. That competition has left some room for the
survival of the independents. But when this inducement for their
survival is taken away, we
Page 337 U. S. 321
can expect that the oil companies will move in to supplant them
with their own stations. There will still be competition between
the oil companies. But there will be a tragic loss to the nation.
The small, independent businessman will be supplanted by clerks.
Competition between suppliers of accessories (which is involved in
this case) will diminish or cease altogether. The oil companies
will command an increasingly larger share of both the wholesale and
the retail markets.
That is the likely result of today's decision. The requirements
contract which is displaced is relatively innocuous as compared
with the virulent growth of monopoly power which the Court
encourages. The Court does not act unwittingly. It consciously
pushes the oil industry in that direction. The Court approves what
the Anti-Trust Laws were designed to prevent. It helps remake
America in the image of the cartels.
[
Footnote 2/1]
See Final Report and Recommendations of the Temporary
National Economic Committee, Sen.Doc. No. 35, 77th Cong., 1st Sess.
(1941). For more detailed analyses,
see Competition and
Monopoly in American Industry (TNEC Monograph 21, 1940) pp. 299
et seq.; The Structure of Industry (TNEC Monograph 27,
1941) pp. 231
et seq.; The Distribution of Ownership in
the 200 Largest Nonfinancial Corporations (TNEC Monograph 29,
1940); Relative Efficiency of Large, Medium-Sized, and Small
Business (TNEC Monograph 13, 1941).
The merger and acquisition movement, which has been evident
since the turn of the century and which contributed to the
spiraling concentration of corporate wealth into the hands of the
few, has not ended. We are presently in the midst of a similar
movement.
See the Federal Trade Commission report, The
Present Trend of Corporate Mergers and Acquisitions, Sen.Doc. No.
17, 80th Cong., 1st Sess. (1947), p. 6, where it is shown that
"the increase in the merger movement following V-J day parallels
very closely the sharp upward movement which took place at the end
of World War I."
The causes which have recently contributed to the growing
bigness of big corporations are varied.
See Lynch, The
Concentration of Economic Power (1946), pp. 3-4 where it is
said:
"Even before the entrance of the United States into the war, the
placing of defense contracts served to augment the growth of
bigness in industry and to intensify the struggle for survival by
small concerns. By 1941, the pattern of defense contracts which,
with modifications, was to remain for the duration of the war had
been established. It is reported that, in that year, fifty-six
firms, less than one-half of 1 percent of the manufacturing
establishments of the country, were awarded 75 percent of all the
contracts. Concentration was even more marked within this group,
however, inasmuch as six corporations held 31 percent of the total.
Between June, 1940, and March, 1943, more than 100 million dollars
worth of prime war supply contracts were awarded. Seventy percent
of these were held by the leading 100 corporations; 10 corporations
held 32 percent, and the leading 50 held 60 percent."
"Studies by the United States Department of Commerce during
1943-1944 throw additional light on this trend toward industrial
concentration. After Pearl Harbor, the total number of firms in
business declined precipitously. Despite the wartime industrial
boom, the number of firms which discontinued operations was greater
than that replaced by new entries; it is estimated that the number
in business in 1943 was nearly 17 percent less than in 1941. There
are numerous indications that the relative importance of small
business has declined during the war period, and that the dominance
of big business has become more marked. Between 1938 and 1942, it
appears that the total number of workers employed by 95 percent of
the nation's corporations (the smallest) declined 23 percent,
whereas those employed by 5 percent of the corporations (the
largest) increased 22 percent. A related study indicates that,
between January 1, 1941, and January 1, 1943, business firms
employing fewer than 125 workers each experienced an increase in
employment of 1 percent and an increase in the value of their
product (attributable principally to price increases) of 16
percent; during the same period, however, the increase in
employment by the large establishments employing more than 125
workers was 62 percent, and the increase in the value of the
product 96 percent."
[
Footnote 2/2]
See, for example, United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil
Co., 310 U. S. 150.
[
Footnote 2/3]
See, for example, Mercoid Corp. v. Mid-Continent Co.,
320 U. S. 661.
[
Footnote 2/4]
See United States v. Griffith, 334 U.
S. 100;
Schine Theaters v. United States,
334 U. S. 110;
United States v. Paramount Pictures, 334 U.
S. 131,
334 U. S.
172.
Those cases have largely expended the force of
Hartford
Empire Co. v. United States, 323 U. S. 386 --
an indefensible decision whereby the Court allowed those who had
built one of the tightest monopolies in American history largely to
retain their ill gotten gains and continue their hold on the
economy. The philosophy of that decision can be summed up in the
words Brandeis used to describe the decree effecting a so-called
dissolution of the American Tobacco Co. He said that its
defenders
"appear to have discovered in the Constitution a new implied
prohibition: 'What man has illegally joined together, let no court
put asunder.'"
The Curse of Bigness (1935) p. 103.
[
Footnote 2/5]
See Schine Theaters v. United States, supra, at
334 U. S.
129-130.
[
Footnote 2/6]
It should be noted in this connection that a majority of the
Court could not be obtained for holding illegal
per se the
vertical integration in the motion picture industry.
See United
States v. Paramount Pictures, supra, at
334 U. S.
173-174.
[
Footnote 2/7]
Other People's Money (1933) p. 110.
[
Footnote 2/8]
For the plight of the independent service station operator
see Control of the Petroleum Industry by Major Oil
Companies (TNEC Monograph No. 39, 1941) pp. 46, 47, 52.
See
also Review and Criticism on Behalf of Standard Oil Co. (New
Jersey) and Sun Oil Co. of Monograph No. 39 with Rejoinder by
Monograph Author (TNEC Monograph 39-A, 1941).
MR. JUSTICE JACKSON, with whom THE CHIEF JUSTICE and MR. JUSTICE
BURTON join, dissenting.
I am unable to join the judgment or opinion of the Court or
reasons I will state, but shortly.
Section 3 of the Clayton Act does not make any lease, sale, or
contract unlawful unless
"the effect of such lease, sale, or contract for sale or such
condition, agreement, or understanding may be to substantially
lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in any line of
commerce."
38 Stat. 730, 731, 15 U.S.C. § 14. It is indispensable to the
Government's case to establish that either the actual or the
probable effect of the accused arrangement is to substantially
lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly.
I am unable to agree that this requirement was met. To be sure,
the contracts cover "a substantial number of outlets and a
substantial amount of products, whether considered comparatively or
not."
78 F.
Supp. 850, 875.
Page 337 U. S. 322
But that fact does not automatically bring the accused
arrangement within the prohibitions of the statute. The number of
dealers and the volume of sales covered by the arrangement, of
course, was sufficient to be substantial. That is to say, this
arrangement operated on enough commerce to violate the Act,
provided its effects were substantially to lessen competition or
create a monopoly. But proof of their quantity does not prove that
they had this forbidden quality and the assumption that they did,
without proof, seems to me unwarranted.
Moreover, the trial court not only made the assumption, but he
did not allow the defendant affirmatively to show that such effects
do not flow from this arrangement. Such evidence on the subject as
was admitted was not considered in reaching the decision that these
contracts are illegal.
I regard it as unfortunate that the Clayton Act submits such
economic issues to judicial determination. It not only leaves the
law vague as a warning or guide, and determined only after the
event, but the judicial process is not well adapted to exploration
of such industrywide, and even nationwide, questions.
But if they must decide, the only possible way for the courts to
arrive at a fair determination is to hear all relevant evidence
from both parties and weigh not only its inherent probabilities of
verity, but also compare the experience, disinterestedness and
credibility of opposing witnesses. This is a tedious process, and
not too enlightening, but, without it, a judicial decree is but a
guess in the dark. That is all we have here, and I do not think it
is an adequate basis on which to upset longstanding and widely
practiced business arrangements.
I should therefore vacate this decree and direct the court below
to complete the case by hearing and weighing the Government's
evidence and that of defendant as to the effects of this
device.
Page 337 U. S. 323
However, if the Court refuses to do that, I cannot agree that
the requirements contract is
per se an illegal one under
the antitrust law, and that is the substance of what the Court
seems to hold. I am not convinced that the requirements contract as
here used is a device for suppressing competition instead of a
device for waging competition. If we look only at its effect in
relation to particular retailers who become parties to it, it does
restrain their freedom to purchase their requirements elsewhere and
prevents other companies from selling to them. Many contracts have
the effect of taking a purchaser out of the market for goods he
already has bought or contracted to take. But the retailer in this
industry is only a conduit from the oil fields to the driver's
tank, a means by which the oil companies compete to get the
business of the ultimate consumer -- the man in whose automobile
the gas is used. It means to me, if I must decide without evidence,
that these contracts are an almost necessary means to maintain this
all-important competition for consumer business, in which it is
admitted competition is keen. The retail stations, whether
independent or company-owned, are the instrumentalities through
which competition for this ultimate market is waged.
It does not seem to me inherently to lessen this real
competition when an oil company tries to establish superior service
by providing the consumer with a responsible dealer from which the
public can purchase adequate and timely supplies of oil, gasoline,
and car accessories of some known and reliable standard of quality.
No retailer, whether agent or independent, can long remain in
business if he does not always, and not just intermittently, have
gas to sell. Retailers' storage capacity usually is limited, and
they are in no position to accumulate large stocks. They can take
gas only when and as they can sell it. The Government can hardly
force someone to contract to stand by, ever ready to fill
Page 337 U. S. 324
fluctuating demands of dealers who will not, in turn, undertake
to buy from that supplier all their requirements. And it is
important to the driving public to be able to rely on retailers to
have gas to retail. It is equally important that the wholesaler
have some incentive to carry the stocks, and have the transport
facilities to make the irregular deliveries caused by varied
consumer demands.
It may be that the Government, if required to do so, could prove
that this is a bad system and an illegal one. It may be that the
defendant, if permitted to do so, can prove that it is, in its
overall aspects, a good system, and within the law. But, on the
present record, the Government has not made a case.
*
If the courts are to apply the lash of the antitrust laws to the
backs of businessmen to make them compete, we cannot in fairness
also apply the lash whenever they hit upon a successful method of
competing. That, insofar as I am permitted by the record to learn
the facts, appears to be the case before us. I would reverse.
* The Government can derive no comfort for this sort of thing
from
International Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.
S. 392. There, the defendant started with a patent
monopoly of the machine for utilization of its product. The
customers, canners, were in effect the ultimate consumers of salt
as such. But they could get the advantages of the invention only if
they tied themselves to use no other salt therein.