1. Upon a thorough investigation of the grain rate structure in
the western district, the Interstate Commerce Commission prescribed
rate-break combinations as the exclusive basis of transit
privileges at primary markets. However, transit privileges at
interior points on routes passing through a primary market were
allowed on the basis of lower rates in effect over competing routes
between the same points.
Held, that, considering the whole history of grain rate
regulation, the differentiation between primary markets and
interior points thus made by the Commission was not an undue or
unreasonable discrimination forbidden by the Interstate Commerce
Act. P.
314 U. S.
544.
2. The contention that the orders of the Commission are invalid
because they deprive the primary markets of natural competitive
advantages is rejected. P.
314 U. S. 548.
3. Whether a discrimination is unreasonable under the Act is a
question of fact that has been confided by Congress to the judgment
and discretion of the Commission, and upon which its decisions,
made the basis of administrative orders operating
in
futuro, are not to be
Page 314 U. S. 535
disturbed by the courts except upon a showing that they are
unsupported by evidence, were made without a hearing, exceed
constitutional limits, or for some other reason amount to a, abuse
of power. P.
314 U. S.
546.
36 F. Supp. 865 affirmed.
Appeal from a decree of the District Court of three judges
dismissing the complaint in a suit to set aside orders of the
Interstate Commerce Commission.
MR. JUSTICE FRANKFURTER delivered the opinion of the Court.
We have before us on this appeal orders embodying a series of
determinations made by the Interstate Commerce Commission after
inquiries into the grain rate structure stretching over a period of
twelve years. The plaintiffs are millers, elevator companies,
boards of trade, grain exchanges, and other business interests in
Kansas City, St. Louis, Omaha, St. Joseph, Atchison, Leavenworth,
and Minneapolis, the great grain centers known in the trade as
"primary markets." The Commission's orders, they complain, create
an unlawful discrimination under the Interstate Commerce Act, §§
1(5), 2, 3(1), by prohibiting the interruption of shipments of
grain for the purpose of being stored, marketed, or processed --
technically characterized as transit privileges -- at these primary
markets on the lower rates under which these privileges are
available at competing interior points (
i.e.,
Page 314 U. S. 536
grain centers other than primary markets). The District Court
dismissed the complaint, 36 F. Supp. 865, and the case is here on
appeal. Judicial Code § 210, 28 U.S.C. § 47a.
As one phase of the effort to relieve agricultural distress,
Congress, in 1925, by the Hoch-Smith Resolution, directed the
Interstate Commerce Commission to make a thorough investigation of
the rate structure of common carriers
"in order to determine to what extent and in what manner
existing rates and charges may be unjust . . . or unduly
preferential, thereby imposing undue burdens, or giving undue
advantage as between the various localities and parts of the
country, the various classes of traffic, and the various classes
and kinds of commodities, and to make, in accordance with law, such
changes, adjustments, and redistribution of rates and charges as
may be found necessary to correct any defects so found to
exist."
43 Stat. 801, 49 U.S.C. § 55.
Accordingly, on September 30, 1926, the Commission instituted a
comprehensive investigation into the rates and practices affecting
grain and grain products in the Western District. [
Footnote 1] The Commission called its
proceeding "unusual," involving as it did
"three-score and more of major issues, affecting every part of a
vast territorial domain, each of which would ordinarily present a
case of more than average importance."
Grain and Grain Products Within the Western Dist. and for
Export, 164 I.C.C. 619, 697. Extensive hearings were held, and, on
the basis of a huge record of some 53,000 pages of testimony,
including 2,100 exhibits, 20,000 pages of memoranda, exceptions,
and oral arguments, the Commission on July 1, 1930, issued a report
and order prescribing maximum rates for grain and grain products.
164 I.C.C. 619. A supplemental report and order were issued on
April
Page 314 U. S. 537
13, 1931. Grain and Grain Products Within the Western Dist. and
for Export, 173 I.C.C. 511. Because the Commission did not take
evidence relating to the drastic changes in economic conditions due
to the depression occurring between the close of its hearings and
the date of its orders, this Court set aside the orders.
Atchison, T. & S.F. Ry. Co. v. United States,
284 U. S. 248. New
and extensive hearings were thereupon held, and on October 22,
1934, the Commission in an elaborate report affirmed some of its
earlier findings and modified others. 205 I.C.C. 301. Upon further
consideration of the record, the Commission issued a supplemental
order to remove discriminations between interior points. 215 I.C.C.
83. Dealers at the primary markets thereupon filed formal
complaints seeking modification of that part of the Commission's
orders which differentiated between transit privileges at primary
markets and those at interior points. Hearings upon these
complaints produced more than 7,000 pages of new testimony and over
250 exhibits. On July 27, 1937, the Commission authorized but did
not require the carriers to meet the requests of the primary
markets. 223 I.C.C. 235. The carriers having declined to act on
this authorization, the Commission was petitioned to enter a
mandatory order. Proceedings were reopened, new arguments were
heard, and on July 12, 1938, the Commission found that the
prescribed rates did not subject the primary markets to any "undue
prejudice and disadvantage." 229 I.C.C. 9, 16. Upon reconsideration
this conclusion was affirmed on March 13, 1939. 231 I.C.C. 793. To
upset these findings and to strike down the orders based upon them
the present suit was filed.
Since the transit privilege is at the core of this litigation, a
brief exposition of its mechanics and manipulations becomes
necessary. The privilege of transit enables grain to be shipped
from point A to point B, there to be stored, marketed, or
processed, and later
Page 314 U. S. 538
reshipped to point C at a rate less than the combination of the
separate rates from A to B and B to C.
See Transit Case,
24 I.C.C. 340;
Atchison, T. & S.F. Ry. v. United
States, 279 U. S. 768,
279 U. S.
777-779; Locklin, Economics of Transportation (1935)
122, 123, 629-631. The shipper pays the local rate on the inbound
shipment to the transit point, B in our illustration. A receipted
freight bill specifying the point of origin, the rate paid, and
other pertinent data, is recorded with the transit bureau as
evidence of intention of further transportation of the inbound
grain or its equivalent. When the outbound shipment is tendered to
the carrier, the freight bill is surrendered in order that the
shipper may obtain an outbound rate lower than that which he would
otherwise be compelled to pay. The privilege belongs, as it were,
to both the grain and its shipper.
"The benefit attaching to grain shipped into the primary market
is commonly so broad that it is transferable not only to another
owner of the same grain, but to like grain coming from the same
country point."
Atchison, T. & S.F. Ry. v. United States,
279 U. S. 768,
279 U. S.
778.
This privilege was available in the primary markets under two
different rate schemes: (1) the "overhead through rate" and (2) the
"rate-break combination."
(1) An overhead through rate is the rate from an originating
point to the final destination, or to a gateway like Chicago, via a
particular point. Thus, on a shipment of grain from Enid, Oklahoma,
to Chicago via Kansas City, the overhead through rate was 38.5
cents per hundred pounds. Under this rate, grain reaching Kansas
City could receive the various privileges of transit upon payment
of 23,5 cents (the local rate from Enid to Kansas City) upon the
inbound shipment, and the difference (known as the "transit
balance") between the overhead through rate, 38.5 cents, and the
23.5 cents inbound rate, upon the outbound shipment.
Page 314 U. S. 539
(2) On a "rate-break" basis, however, grain moved on a
combination of the local or flat rate from the originating point to
the primary market and the "proportional" rate from that market to
a gateway or the final destination. The primary markets therefore
came to be known as "rate-break" points. The "proportional" rate,
representing an average of transit balances under overhead through
rates, was designed to offset the competitive advantages of lines
going through rate-break points, as against lines starting there.
The significance of the rate-break combination lay in the fact
that, for many points of origin, there were no overhead through
rates. In the above example, the proportional rate on outbound
grain shipments from Kansas City to Chicago was 17.5 cents. The
applicable rate on a shipment of grain from an originating point
having no through rate to Chicago via Kansas City, with or without
transit at Kansas City, was a combination of the local rate to
Kansas City and the proportional rate from Kansas City to
Chicago.
Thus, the difference between the two systems permitting transit
at primary markets was the rate at which the outbound traffic
moved. Under the rate-break combination, the outbound shipment
moved at the proportional rate; under the overhead through rate, it
moved at the transit balance. The availability of these two rate
bases, the Commission found, gave rise to serious
discriminations:
"Whether outbound shipments are at proportional rates or transit
balances depends upon the selection of the inbound freight bill. If
the inbound freight bill covers a shipment from an origin point
from which there is no overhead rate with transit to final
destination, the outbound shipment is at the proportional rate. But
grain from a point from which there is no overhead rate with
transit can, under present practice, be substituted for grain from
a point from which there is such an overhead rate with transit, and
can be forwarded, upon presentation
Page 314 U. S. 540
of the inbound expense bill covering inbound transportation from
the latter point at the transit balance due that expense bill."
164 I.C.C. 619, 634.
"The uncertainty in advance as to the outbound basis of charge
arises from the dependence of that charge upon a check of the
individual shipper's range of inbound billing. The outbound charge
will be a transit balance if the inbound freight bill surrendered
covers a shipment from an origin from which there is a one-factor
through rate less than the rate-break combination, and will be the
higher proportional rate if the inbound freight bill surrendered
covers a shipment from an origin from which there is no such
one-factor through rate. Transit balances will vary with the
measure both of the through rates and of the inbound rates to the
transit point."
"The advantage to the user of the transit balance over the user
of the higher proportional rate is evident, and increases in the
ratio of the increase in the storage capacity of the respective
cash-grain dealers at the rate-break markets. In other words, the
greater the storage capacity, the wider the selection of inbound
billing and proportionately more transit balances."
205 I.C.C. 301, 335.
In the judgment of the Commission, these practices
"tended to disrupt the rate-break combinations, disorganize the
general rate structure, make uncertain in advance the outbound
basis of charge, give an undue preference to the users of transit
balances over the users of proportional rates, depress the price of
grain at the rate-break markets and, by direct reflection at the
country points, and reduce the revenues of the carriers."
205 I.C.C. 301, 334.
Thus, the issue before the Commission was
"whether the rates through the primary markets shall be made on
the combination of flat rates to and proportional rates from the
markets exclusively, or in part, or at all."
Putting
Page 314 U. S. 541
in the balance all the complex and conflicting interests, the
Commission reached these conclusions:
"Just so long as transit balances remain a substantial factor in
the adjustment of rates from the primary markets, just so long will
there be undue preferences between outbound shippers, as well as
general instability in rates resulting from shippers seeking the
translation of transit balances into proportional rates. . . . The
best interests not only of the primary markets, but of the
producer, consumer, and carrier will be served by the fullest
possible application of the rate-break combinations through primary
markets."
"164 I.C.C. 619, 644, 645. [
Footnote 2]"
Accordingly, it prescribed new rate-break combinations [
Footnote 3] and made them applicable to
transit both at primary
Page 314 U. S. 542
markets and at interior points on routes passing through such
markets. [
Footnote 4] The
exclusive rate-break combinations were not made applicable to
interior points not on routes passing through rate-break markets
because the rate-break combinations had no relevance to these
points. 164 I.C.C. 619, 645; 173 I.C.C. 511, 516, 517.
A concrete illustration will rob this railroad jargon of its
mystery. The through rate over numerous routes from Kansas City to
Chicago was 16 cents. Some of these routes pass through Omaha, from
which the proportional rate was also 16 cents. Other routes from
Kansas City to Chicago do not pass through Omaha. Interior points
like Falls City and Nebraska City, which are on routes through
Omaha, had to pay 6 1/2 cents, the local rate to Omaha, plus 16
cents, the proportional rate from Omaha to Chicago. But other
interior points lying between Kansas City and Chicago on routes not
passing through Omaha were required to pay only the 16 cents
through rate. The net result was that interior points on routes
passing through rate-break markets were placed at a substantial
competitive disadvantage with interior points not on such
routes.
Dealers at the interior points on routes passing through
rate-break markets like Omaha petitioned the Commission to modify
its orders so as to remove this discrimination between interior
points. They urged on the Commission that, inasmuch as the
fundamental purpose of the rate-break combinations was the
establishment of uniform proportional rates on outbound shipments
from
Page 314 U. S. 543
primary markets, this purpose would not be frustrated if, in
order to meet the lower through rate over competitive routes,
transit on the through rate were permitted at interior points on
routes through rate-break markets. The Commission found that the
requested modification would remove the discrimination between
interior points without subjecting the primary markets to any new
substantial competitive disadvantages. 215 I.C.C. 83, 92, 93. It
found that, under transit on an overhead through rate, dealers at
interior points operated under important competitive disadvantages.
The through rates were applicable only on "reasonably direct," not
"markedly circuitous," routes, and outbound shipments from the
transit point were usually limited to the rails of either the
inbound carrier or a carrier participating with it in a joint rate
via the transit point. Dealers at rate-break markets, on the other
hand, were free from such restrictions as to circuity of routes and
choice of outbound carrier. The proportional rate was applicable to
all lines from primary market to destination regardless of the
inbound shipment's point of origin. The Commission found this to be
a "substantial advantage to the transit operators at the rate-break
markets over the transit operators at the interior transit points."
215 I.C.C. 83, 91. Accordingly, it modified its previous orders so
as to permit transit at interior points on routes passing through a
primary market "on the basis of a lower rate in effect over a
competing route between the same points." 215 I.C.C. 83, 93.
To give this order practical application: at all interior points
lying on routes from Kansas City to Chicago, transit privileges
were available at the 16 cents rate, while shipments stopping for
transit at primary markets along such routes,
e.g., Omaha,
Atchison, Leavenworth, and St. Joseph, could move only at the
rate-break combination of the 6 1/2 cents inbound rate and the 16
cents outbound proportional rate.
Page 314 U. S. 544
The crux of this litigation is the validity of the
differentiation between primary markets and interior points thus
made by the Commission in the setting of the whole history of grain
rate regulation.
Dealers at the primary markets complained against this
differentiation. The Commission again canvassed the perplexing
factors of the tangled problem before it. After pointing out that,
at the earlier stages of the grain rate inquiry, "especially the
markets" had supported the system of "rate-breaks at market points
and overhead rates with transit at local points," the Commission
observed:
"No extensive rate structure can be made perfect, nor can any
rate structure be made permanent in any real sense in a changing
world. . . . The two Grain cases together have demonstrated the
impossibility, even on the part of those most experienced, most
competent, and most expert, of seeing in advance the consequences
of the particular changes in rates and practices here under
consideration. Apparently nothing but experience can furnish a
demonstration, and even the demonstration of experience may not
prove to be conclusive unless it can be had on a scale sufficiently
large and at intervals of time sufficiently close, and under
substantially similar conditions."
223 I.C.C. 235, 245, 246. It took occasion to recall these
guiding considerations from its first report:
"It would be impossible to take any comprehensive action without
adversely affecting certain of the conflicting interests upon this
record. Nothing but experience can demonstrate what the effect will
be regarding certain of these issues. . . . All parties should
cooperate to make careful note of the effect upon their interests,
with the view to bringing to our attention from time to time, after
a reasonable trial, those situations which may require further
consideration."
164 I.C.C. 619, 698. To yield to the wish of the dealers of the
primary markets would, the Commission found, work
"a hardship upon the milling
Page 314 U. S. 545
industry at many intermediate points, with little or no benefit
to the markets, which would still be at a disadvantage in competing
with other rate-break markets and interior points on lower-rated
routes."
223 I.C.C. 235, 245. It concluded, therefore, that the record
did not justify the mandatory order sought by the markets. Instead,
it authorized the carriers by appropriate tariffs to make
"restricted departures from the exclusive application of
proportional rates at rate-break points for a limited period of
time" upon condition that such departures "should be surrounded by
such effective safeguards as will make it impossible to
reestablish" the discriminations incident to the double system of
rates at primary markets. 223 I.C.C. 235, 246.
The carriers having declined to act on this authorization, the
markets again sought a compulsory order. Upon reargument, the
Commission concluded that
"the granting of the transit requested would break down the
rate-break adjustment prescribed in the Grain Case; that said
adjustment should be abandoned, if at all, only upon demonstration
of its failure as a workable adjustment, over an adequate period of
normal conditions in the grain trade; that such a test has not been
given the adjustment."
229 I.C.C. 9, 16. [
Footnote
5] Accordingly, the Commission dismissed the complaints and
withdrew its previous permission to the carriers voluntarily to
establish the rates requested by the primary markets. After a
second reargument, the Commission adhered to this conclusion. 231
I.C.C. 793.
The appellants do not claim that the Commission's findings are
devoid of proof, or that they were reached without observance of
appropriate procedures. Their claim, in
Page 314 U. S. 546
substance, is that whatever benefits the double system affords
the primary markets are natural advantages, and that to deprive
them of these advantages works an unlawful discrimination.
The Act forbids the Commission to establish a rate structure
which would give one transit point an "undue or unreasonable
preference or advantage" and would subject another point to an
"undue or unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage." But this does
not mean that the law compels identity of treatment for like
services at different places. It prohibits only "undue" or
"unreasonable" discriminations.
"Whether a preference or advantage or discrimination is undue or
unreasonable or unjust is one of those questions of fact that have
been confided by Congress to the judgment and discretion of the
Commission . . and upon which its decisions, made the basis of
administrative orders operating
in futuro, are not to be
disturbed by the courts except upon a showing that they are
unsupported by evidence, were made without a hearing, exceed
constitutional limits, or for some other reason amount to an abuse
of power."
Manufacturers' Ry. Co. v. United States, 246 U.
S. 457,
246 U. S. 481;
see Nashville, C. & St.L. Ry. v. Tennessee,
262 U. S. 318,
262 U. S. 322;
United States v. Chicago Heights Trucking Co.,
310 U. S. 344,
310 U. S.
352-353.
The process of ratemaking is essentially empiric. The stuff of
the process is fluid and changing -- the resultant of factors that
must be valued, as well as weighed. Congress has therefore
delegated the enforcement of transportation policy to a permanent
expert body, and has charged it with the duty of being responsive
to the dynamic character of transportation problems.
Cf.
Railroad Commission v. Rowan & Nichols Oil Co.,
310 U. S. 573,
310 U. S.
581-582.
The wisdom of the narrow scope within which Congress has
confined judicial participation in the ratemaking process is
strikingly vindicated by the history of this
Page 314 U. S. 547
controversy. The Commission's laborious investigation into the
grain rate structure disclosed that discriminations were
inseparable from the operation, side by side, of two systems of
rates allowing transit of grain at primary markets. This basic
finding is not challenged. And it is this fact which created the
problem for solution by the Commission. There was no ready answer
either in law reports or in economic experience. Any solution had
to rest on informed judgment. And judgment in a situation like this
implies, ultimately, prophecy based on the facts in the record as
illumined by the seasoned wisdom of the expert body. In this
perspective, the Commission had several choices before it -- but
all inevitably rested upon trial and error. It might have
established the overhead through rate as the exclusive basis of
transit at primary markets. It might have banked on the exclusive
rate-break combination. It might have abolished the privilege of
free transit entirely. Of only one thing could the Commission be
completely certain: no action could be taken without "adversely
affecting certain of the conflicting interests." 164 I.C.C. 619,
698. Weighing the prospective gains and hurts which were part of
all of the proposed remedies, the Commission decided upon the
exclusive rate-break combination. It did so, however, with full
recognition that the wisdom of its action had to meet the test of
experience. Therefore, it treated its conclusion as part of a
continuing process, and requested the parties to give the system
which it adopted a "reasonable trial," contemplating such further
consideration as the practical operation of the system would
require. The Commission refused the modifications asked by the
appellants because the rate-break adjustment was "entitled to a
thorough test over an adequate period of normal conditions in the
grain trade," and it had "received no such fair test up to the
present time." To grant the requested
Page 314 U. S. 548
modifications would "break down the rate-break adjustment." 229
I.C.C. 9, 15, 16. These findings are incontestable.
That the Commission itself was of divided mind in the successive
stages of this controversy emphasizes that the problem is enmeshed
in difficult judgments of economic and transportation policy.
Neither rule of thumb nor formula nor general principles provide a
ready answer. We certainly have neither technical competence nor
legal authority to pronounce upon the wisdom of the course taken by
the Commission. It is not for us to tinker with so sensitive an
organism as the grain rate structure, only a minor phase of which
is caught in the record before us. If we were to grant the relief
sought by the appellants, we would be restoring evils which the
exclusive rate-break adjustment was designed to remove -- evils
which, for all we know, would be far more serious than those
complained of by the appellants.
What we have said sufficiently disposes of the suggestion that
the orders of the Commission must be stricken down because they
wipe out natural competitive advantages of the primary markets. A
rate structure found to involve serious discriminations among
shippers, carriers, and transit points alike is hardly a
manifestation of nature beyond the Commission's power to
repair.
Affirmed.
MR. JUSTICE ROBERTS is of opinion that the decree of the
District Court should be reversed.
[
Footnote 1]
The Western District is defined as the area "on and west of the
Mississippi River, west of Lakes Superior and Michigan, and west of
and including Illinois."
[
Footnote 2]
The Commission specifically found that the adoption of the
exclusive rate-break combination at the primary markets would give
the markets substantial competitive advantages over interior
transit points:
"The proportional rate is applicable over all outbound lines
upon surrender of an inbound freight bill covering an inbound
shipment by rail, whether the transportation through the rate-break
market is over a reasonably direct route or not. It is the
equivalent in all respects, and more, of a local rate. . . . It is
designed for the final gathering in by the rate-break market, for
through transportation at less than the combinations of local rates
that would otherwise apply, of grain not procurable under
one-factor through rates less than the rate-break combinations (and
resulting transit balances less than the proportional), because of
the limitations on out-of-line and back-haul movement incident to
the usual application of the one-factor through rates only over
reasonably direct routes, and because of the further usual
requirement of outbound shipment from the transit point over the
rails of the inbound carrier. The proportional rates therefore open
up to the rate-break markets the widest possible range of
originating and distributing territory and afford, together with
the larger number of carriers usually found converging inbound to
and radiating outbound from the rate-break market, in the direction
of the normal flow of the grain traffic, a decided advantage to
that market over the interior transit point."
205 I.C.C. 301, 340, 341.
[
Footnote 3]
The Commission revised existing rate-break combinations,
reducing both the inbound flat rates and the outbound
proportionals, and ordered that the prescribed rate-break
combinations be made the exclusive basis of charge upon grain
shipments moving through or stopping for transit at primary
markets, and that overhead through rates less than the prescribed
rate-break combinations be cancelled. 164 I.C.C. 619, 645.
[
Footnote 4]
"The restriction is laid on the intermediate points other than
the market, as well as upon the market, in order not to
discriminate against the market in favor of the other intermediate
points."
173 I.C.C. 511, 516.
[
Footnote 5]
To rescind the previous modifications, the Commission found,
"would deprive these interior transit points of the same kind of
transit accorded interior transit points on other routes, and . . .
would not materially benefit complainants, who would still be
confronted with their major competition."
229 I.C.C. 9, 14.