1. Carriers reaching the port of New Orleans with their own
rails and reaching Texas ports through connections with which they
maintained through routes and joint rates made the same, or
substantially the same, rates on export, import, and coastwise
traffic between New Orleans and inland points as were charged
between those points and the Texas ports, although the rail haul to
and from New Orleans was longer. Ocean freights were the same for
all of these ports, and the object of the rail carriers in
equalizing their rates was to protect their business of the classes
named from the competition of other railroads whose lines tapped
the Texas ports. The charges were neither unreasonably high nor
so
Page 289 U. S. 628
low as to be noncompensatory. The Interstate Commerce
Commission, upon findings of undue preference to New Orleans and
undue prejudice to the Texas ports, entered orders which prescribed
minimum differentials in favor of the latter where the New Orleans
haul was by more than 25 percent the longer.
Held that the
orders should be set aside.
2. The provision of § 3(1) of the Interstate Commerce Act
forbidding any carrier to give any undue or unreasonable preference
or advantage to any particular "locality" or to subject any
particular "locality" to any undue or unreasonable prejudice or
disadvantage does not apply to seaports in respect of import,
export, and coastwise traffic in relation to which they are in no
sense points of origin or destination, but are merely gateways
through which the traffic passes from rail to water carrier and
vice versa. Pp.
289 U. S. 638,
289 U. S.
644.
3. Carriers in competition for export and import business may,
within the zone of reasonableness prescribed by the statute, adjust
their rates so as to retain the desired traffic for their own
lines, and, in so doing, may transport such shipments although not
made on through bills at rates below those charged for domestic
traffic between the same points. P.
289 U. S.
636.
4. The Act was passed for the protection of those who pay or
bear the rates. The standards it establishes are transportation
standards, not criteria of the general welfare. P.
289 U. S.
638.
5. The word "localities," therefore, has its proper office as
denoting the origin or destination of traffic and the shipping,
producing, and consuming areas affected by rates and practices of
carriers. The term was, however, not intended to cover a junction,
a way station, a gateway, or a port as respects traffic passing
through it. P.
289 U. S.
638.
6. The Interstate Commerce Commission has no authority to
readjust rates and prescribe differentials for the purpose of
building up one gateway or port to the injury of another. Pp.
289 U. S. 639,
289 U. S.
646.
7. The legislative history of the Act to Regulate Commerce,
1887, and of the Hepburn Act, 1906, shows that it was not the
intention of Congress to cover ports, as such, among the
"localities" given regulatory protection. Pp.
289 U. S. 639,
289 U. S.
641.
8. Administrative construction of § 3 before and since the
passage of the Transportation Act is found not to justify the
assertion that Congress, by not amending the section, had
acquiesced in adjustment of rates on exports and imports in the
interest of ports as such. P.
289 U. S.
641.
Page 289 U. S. 629
9. Where a statutory body such as the Interstate Commerce
Commission assumes a power plainly not granted, no amount of such
interpretation is binding on the courts. P.
289 U. S.
640.
10. A carrier may not be held responsible for undue prejudice or
preference to a locality in respect of rates unless both of the
localities affected are upon its lines or it effectively
participates in rates to both so that it may have the choice of
raising one rate, lowering the other, or altering both. Earlier
decisions distinguished. Pp.
289 U. S. 646,
289 U. S.
651.
42 F.2d 281 reversed.
Appeal from a decree of the District Court (three judges)
dismissing bills brought by two railroad companies to enjoin
enforcement of orders of the Interstate Commerce Commission.
Page 289 U. S. 630
MR. JUSTICE ROBERTS delivered the opinion of the Court.
The Galveston Commercial Association complained to the
Interstate Commerce Commission that carload commodity rates on
import, export, and coastwise traffic between a portion of western
classification territory and Galveston were unreasonable, and their
relationship with those to and from Houston, Texas City, Beaumont,
Port Arthur, and Orange, Texas, and New Orleans, Louisiana, was
unduly prejudicial to Galveston. [
Footnote 1] The claim of unreasonableness
Page 289 U. S. 631
was abandoned, as was also the assertion of discrimination in
favor of the other Texas ports. The latter intervened and prayed
the same relief as might be accorded Galveston in respect of rate
relationship with New Orleans. The issue was therefore narrowed to
one of prejudice to them and preference of New Orleans. Railroads
serving the Texas ports and various shippers and commercial bodies
intervened in support of the complaint; interests connected with
the Port of New Orleans and shippers intervened in opposition.
The Commission found that export and import rates on fourteen
commodities from or to points in Arkansas, Texas, Oklahoma,
Southern Kansas, and Louisiana west of the Mississippi River were
unduly prejudicial to Galveston and unduly preferential of New
Orleans. In all instances where the distance to Galveston is less
than the distance to New Orleans by not over one hundred miles, it
permitted equal rates, but, for differences in distance exceeding
one hundred miles, it prescribed certain named minimum
differentials in favor of Galveston. [
Footnote 2]
On rehearing, the prior decision was modified by including the
other Texas ports with Galveston in the finding of undue prejudice;
substituting a 25 percent difference in distance for the 100-mile
basis; exempting from the scope of the order rates to or from
points on the Texas & Pacific and the Louisiana Railroad &
Navigation Company; [
Footnote
3] exempting rates on petroleum
Page 289 U. S. 632
and its products, and making certain other changes not here
material. [
Footnote 4]
The proceeding was later reopened for the purpose of deciding
whether the Texas & Pacific and the L.R. & N. should
continue to be exempted. The Commission reversed its previous
finding and included them within its orders. [
Footnote 5] Both carriers filed bills in the
District Court to enjoin the enforcement of all the orders, except
insofar as the second exempted them from the finding of preference
and prejudice. The cases were consolidated, and, upon final hearing
before three judges, the bills were dismissed. [
Footnote 6] The plaintiffs, Texas & Pacific
and L.R. & N., and also the State of Louisiana, the New Orleans
Traffic Bureau, and other interveners appealed.
The Texas ports are served by some half-dozen lines which,
either themselves or through their connections, reach the areas of
origin or destination embraced in the Commission's order. Generally
speaking, their routes trend north, rather than east of Galveston.
The Southern Pacific is the only carrier serving both Galveston and
New Orleans. Texas is also connected with New Orleans by the Gulf
Coast Lines, by the Texas & Pacific, extending east from El
Paso through Dallas and Fort Worth to Shreveport, Louisiana, and
thence southeast to New Orleans, and by the L.R. & N., which
connects Eastern Texas and Western Louisiana with that port.
Several other lines extend between New Orleans and Western
Louisiana, Arkansas, Kansas, and Oklahoma.
With minor and immaterial exceptions, the carriers serving the
Texas ports and New Orleans have for many years equalized the
import and export commodity carload rates between the territory
embraced in the Commission's orders and Galveston and New Orleans.
The gravamen
Page 289 U. S. 633
of the complaint is that, in many instances, the distance to New
Orleans is so much greater than that to the Texas ports, and the
increased haul so important a part of the service rendered, that
this factor should be reflected in a fixed differential in rates.
The Commission's order prescribing differentials is challenged only
insofar as it compels the Texas & Pacific and the L.R. & N.
to establish rates to New Orleans higher by the amount of the fixed
differentials than those charged between the same interior points
and the Texas ports. Inasmuch as the assertion of unreasonableness
was withdrawn and the Commission made no finding that the Galveston
rates were unreasonable, the prohibitions of § 1 of the Act to
regulate commerce, as amended, are not involved. [
Footnote 7] The evidence failed to show that
the rates of the Texas & Pacific and the L.R. & N. on
export and import shipments to and from New Orleans were not
compensatory. The Commission refused to find that they were so low
as to cast a burden on other traffic. There was therefore no basis
for an order fixing minimum reasonable rates under § 15(1) of the
Act. [
Footnote 8] The parties
agree that authority for the order must be found in § 3(1), which
is:
"It shall be unlawful for any common carrier . . . to make or
give any undue or unreasonable preference or advantage to any
particular person, company, firm, corporation, or locality, or any
particular description of traffic, in any respect whatsoever, or to
subject any particular person, company, firm, corporation, or
locality, or any particular description of traffic, to any undue or
unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage in any respect whatsoever.
[
Footnote 9]"
The appellants contend that in the circumstances disclosed the
ports, as such, are not localities preferred or
Page 289 U. S. 634
prejudiced, but that, if they may be so denominated, the Texas
& Pacific and the L.R. & N. cannot be held responsible for
any undue prejudice to the Texas ports, since they do not reach
those ports with their own lines or control the rates to or from
them. They also assert that the orders violate Art. I, § 9, of the
Constitution, which prohibits any regulation of commerce giving
preference to ports of one state over those of another, are without
support in the evidence, and arbitrary.
The cause has been twice argued; it was first presented at the
October Term, 1931, and, on account of the importance of the
questions involved, a reargument was ordered and was had at the
October Term, 1932. [
Footnote
10] Statement of certain facts and settled principles will tend
to clarify and define the issues presented.
The traffic with which we are concerned does not move on through
bills of lading, but the movement is nevertheless from points of
origin to a foreign or coastal destination, or vice versa, and is
therefore essentially through transportation.
Compare Binderup
v. Pathe Exchange, 263 U. S. 291,
263 U. S. 309.
As the Commission said in this case:
"A port is neither the destination nor the origin of traffic
passing through it. It levies toll on the traffic, in substantially
the same manner as do common carriers, in its charges for the use
of its facilities in the transfer of traffic between the rail and
water carriers. "
Page 289 U. S. 635
Although the shipper, in the first instance, consigns the
commodity to the port, and a separate contract is made for ocean
carriage, the through rate nonetheless consists of the rail rate to
the port plus the ocean freight, which is the same from all Gulf
ports. [
Footnote 11]
The choice of route is determined solely by the rail rates from
or to the ports. If these are equalized, the shipper has an option,
but if they are disparate, the route through the port taking the
higher rate is necessarily excluded. A very slight differential in
the rail rate, in some instances as little as a fraction of a cent
per hundred pounds, will divert the traffic through the port so
advantaged. The application of a distance scale to the rail rate
automatically precludes shipment through the more distant port.
Long prior to the passage of the Act to regulate commerce, the
railroads, recognizing this situation and desiring to hold to their
own lines the traffic running to ports which they serve, equalized
rates through the ports reached by their own lines with those
maintained by their rivals to other ports, or established
differentials in favor of their own ports in order to retain a
portion of the competitive export business. And a carrier serving
two ports has, for like reason, fixed an equal or lower rate to the
more distant of the two solely to meet the competition of rivals
who reached it by more direct routes. These practices have not been
indulged either to aid or to harm a port, as such, but solely to
obtain or retain business for the carrier's own line. [
Footnote 12] With the abstract
fairness of such adjustment,
Page 289 U. S. 636
neither the Commission nor the courts have any concern. This is
not to say, however, that the rates promulgated are beyond the
Commission's jurisdiction. While that body has no control over the
ocean rate, it has power to compel a reasonable charge for the rail
haul.
Compare Armour Packing Co. v. United States, 153 F.
1;
News Syndicate Co. v. New York Central R. Co.,
275 U. S. 179,
275 U. S.
186-187. [
Footnote
13] As the carriers are in competition for the business, they
may, within the zone of reasonableness [
Footnote 14] prescribed by the statute, adjust their
rates so as to obtain or retain the desired traffic for their own
lines.
Interstate Commerce Comm'n v. Alabama Midland Ry.
Co., 74 F. 715, 723-724;
168 U. S. 168 U.S.
144,
168 U. S.
172-173;
Skinner & Eddy Corp. v. United
States, 249 U. S. 557,
249 U. S. 564;
United States v. Illinois Central R. Co., 263 U.
S. 515,
263 U. S.
522.
The theory of the Act is that the carriers in initiating rates
may adjust them to competitive conditions, and that such action
does not amount to undue discrimination;
Texas & Pacific
Ry. Co. v. Interstate Commerce Comm'n, 162 U.
S. 197. There, the charging of rates on import traffic
moving from a port on through bills of lading, much lower than
those fixed for domestic transportation, was held not to amount as
matter of law to discrimination forbidden by § 3. The carrier
showed, in justification of the lower rates on import traffic,
that, unless these were permitted, water and rail-and-water
competition would divert the traffic away from the Port of New
Orleans and the carrier's lines extending from that
Page 289 U. S. 637
port. Since that decision, it has been recognized that export
and import shipments, although not made on through bills, might
lawfully be transported at rates below those charged for domestic
traffic between the same points. [
Footnote 15] The same purpose not to stifle competition
justifies relief under § 4 from the prohibition against charging
the same or less for a longer than for a shorter haul.
Interstate Commerce Comm'n v. Baltimore & Ohio R. Co.,
145 U. S. 263,
145 U. S. 276;
Interstate Commerce Comm'n v. Alabama Midland Ry. Co.,
168 U. S. 144,
168 U. S. 164;
Louisville & N. R. Co. v. Behlmer, 175 U.
S. 648,
175 U. S. 671;
Inter-Mountain Rate Cases, 234 U.
S. 476,
234 U. S.
483-485. And relief under the fourth section has been
granted on this ground in respect of export and import rates.
Export and Import Rates, 169 I.C.C. 13.
While the carriers may therefore meet competition by equalizing
rates or maintaining differentials both to interior points and to
ports, they may not adjust their rates with the motive of injuring
or aiding a shipper, a particular kind of traffic, or a locality,
for so to do is to depart from the transportation standard,
conformity to which the Act contemplates, and substitute others
which are prohibited. A tariff published for the purpose of
destroying a market or building up one, of diverting traffic from a
particular place to the injury of that place, or in aid of some
other, is unlawful, and obviously what the carrier may not lawfully
do the Commission may not compel.
Southern Pac. Co. v.
Interstate Commerce Comm'n, 219 U. S. 433,
219 U. S. 444;
Interstate Commerce Comm'n v. Diffenbaugh, 222 U. S.
42,
222 U. S. 46;
Ellis v. Interstate Commerce Comm'n, 237 U.
S. 434,
237 U. S. 445;
United States v. Illinois Central R. Co., 263 U.
S. 515,
263 U. S. 524;
Atchison,
Page 289 U. S. 638
T. & S.F. Ry. Co. v. Interstate Commerce Comm'n,
190 F. 591;
Anchor Coal Co. v. United
States, 25 F.2d
462, 471. [
Footnote
16]
1. In the light of the facts exhibited by the record and the
principles underlying the Act, are ports, in respect of export,
import, and coastwise traffic, localities susceptible of undue
preference or prejudice within the meaning of § 3? The purpose of
§§ 2, 3, and 4, as exhibited by committee reports and explained by
those in charge of the bill in Congress, was to prevent unjust
discrimination resulting from existing practices. Similar
commodities were, without reason or excuse, carried at different
rates. Shippers similarly situated were put on unequal terms.
Producers and consumers at points of origin and destination were
prejudiced by unequal treatment in the matter of rates or service.
Obviously localities of origin or destination might also be
prejudiced by undue discrimination. One of the most prevalent and
reprehensible practices at which the Act was aimed was the charging
of a less or an equal rate for a longer haul upon the same line or
route. The Act was passed for the protection of those who pay or
bear the rates. The standards it establishes are transportation
standards, not criteria of general welfare. The word "localities,"
therefore, has its proper office as denoting the origin or
destination of traffic and the shipping, producing, and consuming
areas affected by rates and practices of carriers. The phrase was,
however, not intended to cover a junction, a way station, a
gateway, or a port as respects traffic passing through it.
Considered as points of origin or destination, any or all of
these are localities within the purview of the section.
Page 289 U. S. 639
All of them may, moreover, though not considered as localities
served, be involved in acts of discrimination. The situation here
presented furnishes a close analogy to proportional rates or
combination rates, and, with respect to either of these, the charge
on shipments through a given gateway or port may discriminate
against traffic passing through another so as to deprive a shipper
of his right of choice of route through either. [
Footnote 17] In such case, however, the
discrimination operates upon the shipper, not upon the port. There
are through rates, proportional rates, and combination rates
applicable to traffic routed through river crossings and gateways.
It seems too plain for argument that the Commission has no
authority, upon a showing by a gateway that, under an existing
tariff, too much traffic passes through another, or too little
through it, to readjust the rates and prescribe differentials so as
to divert traffic through the complaining gateway. The interests
and industries of a gateway are not entitled thus to obtain a
benefit reflected from additional traffic which would be diverted
by such action of the Commission. We perceive no difference in
principle as to export or import traffic routed through ports.
The legislative history of the Act demonstrates that Congress
did not intend to forbid the equalization of export or import rates
by lines serving several ports in order to meet competition. These
rates, it was said, were not to be proportioned to the respective
distances between inland origins or destinations and the ports.
[
Footnote 18] Both
Page 289 U. S. 640
equalizations and differentials had for some time been
maintained in the rates to various Atlantic ports. Congress was
aware of this, and had no intention of interfering with the
maintenance of these rate adjustments.
Appellees say, however, that the Commission has always treated
ports as localities within the meaning of § 3, and exercised the
power to abate discrimination by prescribing differentials in
export rates. They add that, though the Act has been several times
amended, this section has been retained in its original form, and
Congress has thus sanctioned the Commission's interpretation. Where
a statutory body has assumed a power plainly not granted, no amount
of such interpretation is binding upon the courts.
Interstate
Commerce Comm'n v. C., N.O. & T.P. Ry. Co., 167 U.
S. 479,
167 U. S. 510.
This we think is the situation here presented, for, as we have
said, the word "localities" is used with reference to places of
origin and
Page 289 U. S. 641
destination; its employment is not intended to permit the
Commission, in its discretion, to favor or hamper a community
having no such relation to the service of transportation.
Moreover, we do not find that any such settled construction had
been adopted, or that Congress intended to sanction it. With few
and occasional exceptions, the Commission has not, until a recent
date, essayed to prescribe differentials in export rates. Prior to
the Hepburn Amendment in 1906, port differentials were considered
in three cases. [
Footnote
19] In the first, certain carriers applied for leave to
equalize their export rates to Boston with those charged to New
York. The petitions were dismissed on the ground that the
Commission should not authorize what the carriers might lawfully do
without permission. In the second, a New York trade association
complained that the maintenance of differentials in export rates to
Philadelphia and Baltimore voluntarily established by the carriers
worked undue prejudice against New York. The Commission found they
did not result in undue prejudice, though it treated the ports as
localities which would be entitled to relief under a proper
showing. In the third case, shippers and carriers serving north
Atlantic ports submitted to the Commission the question of the
fairness of the current differentials, and that body acted merely
as an arbitrator, and not in its official capacity.
The legislative history of the Hepburn Amendment discloses a
clear intent not to confer power to circumscribe the adjustment of
export and import rates by the carriers to meet competition.
[
Footnote 20] The
expressions used disclose
Page 289 U. S. 642
no thought that the Commission had held the contrary. [
Footnote 21]
Between the dates of the Hepburn Amendment and the
Transportation Act, 1920, the Commission had before it two cases
relevant to the power to prescribe port differentials. [
Footnote 22] In the first, the
Commission recognized its lack of power to deal with the
relationship of the rates. [
Footnote 23] In
Page 289 U. S. 643
the second, the complaint was that Astoria was prejudiced by
exaction of higher export rates from origin territory than those to
Seattle and Tacoma. Though the haul to Astoria was longer, the
Commission required equalization. The Commission, in this case,
asserted its authority to deal with export rate relationship solely
in the interests of the affected ports. Whether the order made was
within the competence of that body or not, the important fact is
that it did not prescribe differentials, but, in the interest of
competition, opened the three ports to export shipment on equal
terms. [
Footnote 24]
We think that, at the date of the passage of the Transportation
Act, no such administrative practice had been established as to
require the conclusion that, in failing to amend § 3, the Congress
approved any asserted power to adjust export and import rates in
the interests of the ports alone.
It remains to determine whether, since 1920, there has been such
a uniform and repeated assertion of this authority as would
constrain us to adopt the principle. The instances in which the
Commission has considered export and import traffic fall into
several classes: first, where shippers' complaints concerning port
differentials established by carriers were dismissed, [
Footnote 25] or were found justified
and prejudice ordered removed; [
Footnote 26] secondly, where, on
Page 289 U. S. 644
shippers' complaint against differentials, equalization of rates
was ordered; [
Footnote 27]
thirdly, where, on complaint by a port, differentials voluntarily
established by the carriers were altered. [
Footnote 28] These are not relevant to the
present controversy. In two decisions rendered prior to the instant
one, the Commission, on complaint of port interests, exercised the
supposed power to compel the establishment of differentials as
between ports. [
Footnote 29]
But we are not persuaded these rulings form a body of
administrative action sufficient to overthrow the evident purpose
of § 3.
We conclude that ports, as such, are not localities, with
respect to export and import traffic routed through them,
susceptible of undue preference or prejudice within the intent of
the Act.
While the Commission's jurisdiction of port rate relation was
fully argued, the appellees seek to support the orders under the
power to abate discrimination between persons and shippers. The
argument is based upon averments of the complaint as to prejudice
of persons at Galveston. There is, however, no allegation that
shippers or consignees in the interior are prejudiced or preferred
by the equalization of the New Orleans rates with those to the
Texas ports, and the Commission made no finding of preference or
prejudice of shippers or consignees, or localities of origin and
destination. [
Footnote 30]
It compared at great
Page 289 U. S. 645
length the facilities of the ports, their volume of traffic, the
relative growth of their export and import business, their
respective steamship facilities, and reached the conclusion that,
though relative distance is not conclusive and competitive
conditions are to be regarded, the Texas ports are entitled to an
advantage in rate consequent upon the shorter haul to and from the
interior territory. The Commission's three reports abound with
statements that a differential in favor of the Texas ports will
divert traffic running to New Orleans and send it through the Texas
ports. Petroleum is one of the commodities as to which complaint
was made. There is no transportation difference discoverable in the
record between this traffic and that of the other freights affected
by the order. But the Commission concluded that New Orleans was not
receiving more than its fair share of this business, and that a
differential advantage would be of little benefit to the Texas
ports by diverting this commodity to them, and therefore refused to
make any order respecting the rates on petroleum and its products.
[
Footnote 31] It has since,
apparently upon similar considerations, refused to prescribe
differentials in the rates on blackstrap molasses. [
Footnote 32] The actual basis of the
decision is, moreover, avowed by the Commission. In the first
report, it said:
"We find that the present relationships of the assailed rates on
export, import, and coastwise traffic . . . are unduly prejudicial
to Galveston and unduly preferential of New Orleans."
100 I.C.C. 122.
In its second report, it stated:
"We find that the present parity of rates as between the Texas
and Louisiana ports . . . does not result in substantial injury to
the Texas ports in respect of
Page 289 U. S. 646
petroleum and its products, but does result in substantial
injury to and prejudice against the Texas ports in respect of the
other commodities considered. . . ."
128 I.C.C. 388.
And finally:
"Upon further consideration, we now find . . . that the present
relationships of the assailed carload rates on export, import, and
coastwise traffic . . . are, and for the future will be, unduly
prejudicial to Galveston and the other Texas ports taking the same
rates, and unduly preferential of New Orleans."
160 I.C.C. 359.
The action of the Commission cannot be justified upon any theory
that it was protecting shippers and consignees, who would naturally
desire all possible routes for foreign shipment. On the contrary,
the orders prohibited a practice born of competition and not proved
to involve a loss of revenue to the appellants. The plain purpose
of the orders was to build up the Texas ports by diverting export
and import traffic to them. As we have shown, § 3 grants no such
power.
2. The Commission's action is challenged for another and wholly
independent reason which, if sustained, also requires a reversal of
the decree. By its second order, the Commission excluded the Texas
& Pacific and the L.R. & N. from its findings of undue
preference and prejudice, and exempted them from the requirement as
to differentials. The Texas & Pacific had been included by the
first order on the theory that it was part of the Missouri Pacific
system which served both New Orleans and the Texas ports. Upon
rehearing, the conclusion was that the line was independently
operated. Exemption was thereupon granted both appellants pursuant
to a rule which the Commission had consistently followed since its
organization -- namely, that a carrier may not be held responsible
for undue prejudice or preference unless both of the localities
affected are upon its lines or it effectively participates in the
rates to both. In the final report, these roads were
Page 289 U. S. 647
denied exemption under the belief that this Court had held the
principle inapplicable in the circumstances here disclosed. The
appellants insist the rule is a reasonable one, consonant with the
purposes of the Act, and that our decisions have not narrowed it so
as to exclude this case from its scope.
The line of the Texas & Pacific in Texas is intersected at
intervals of about 40 miles by north-and-south lines directly or
indirectly serving the Texas ports. The population of these
junction points is over ten times as great as that of all other
open stations on this appellant's line in Texas, and the greater
volume of export and import traffic originates and terminates at
the junctions. [
Footnote 33]
Thus, the question is whether the Texas & Pacific may continue
to participate in the handling of the traffic moving through the
ports to and from points on its own rails on an equality of rates
with competing lines which extend to the Texas ports, or may be
forbidden so to do because it is a party with the competing
carriers to joint rates from stations on its own line to the Texas
ports. The same issue is presented with respect to the L.R. &
N. Neither of the appellants controls the rates to the Texas ports,
and the Commission so finds. [
Footnote 34] Though the Texas port lines can reduce their
rates to and from those ports without the concurrence of the New
Orleans lines, no reductions can be made in those rates by the New
Orleans lines,
Page 289 U. S. 648
even from or to their local stations, without the concurrence of
one or more lines reaching the Texas ports. Clearly the New Orleans
carriers have no effective control over the rates between their
junction points and the Texas ports. As respects local stations,
their participation in joint rates with the lines to Texas ports is
required by § 1(4) of the Act, but such rates may not be higher
than reasonable maxima fixed by national or state authority nor
lower than the amount agreed to by their connections to the Texas
ports. The appellants insist that their compulsory participation in
rates to and from the Texas ports has no legal significance, and
the question remains whether they in fact exercise effective
control over those rates.
The classical case of discrimination in rates is presented where
a single carrier serving two points approximately equidistant from
a common origin on the carrier's line exacts unequal rates for the
two hauls. Not only is the prejudice obvious, but equally so the
ability of the carrier to abate it by raising the rates to the
point enjoying the lower rates, or decreasing those to the point
subject to the higher charge. The principle comprehends, as well,
instances of joint rates where the same carriers participate in the
rates to both points, [
Footnote
35] and where the originating (or delivering) carriers are
different, but the delivering (or originating) carriers are the
same. [
Footnote 36] So too,
a carrier may be responsible for preference or prejudice where it
participates in one of several through routes between point of
origin and the prejudiced destinations although its own line may
reach only one or neither of the latter,
St. Louis S.W. Ry. v.
United States, 245 U. S. 136, for
the discrimination
Page 289 U. S. 649
is brought about by the disparity of rates, and the order
requiring its abatement necessarily runs against all the carriers
parties to them. If one or more of the railroads whose lines make
up the through route should refuse, upon an order to equalize
rates, to afford one of the others a proper division of the rate,
the latter may obtain redress from the Commission under § 15(6).
Where, however, a carrier whose lines reach, or which controls the
rate to, one of the destinations is a party to a joint rate to the
other, but cannot make or control the latter rate, or, though it
were to withdraw as a party thereto, or to cancel the rate, the
discrimination would still continue -- it cannot be held
responsible, nor can any order to remove the prejudice run against
it. [
Footnote 37] This rule
has been consistently applied in respect of export and import rates
to the ports. [
Footnote 38]
The reason for the doctrine is that preference or prejudice can be
found only by a comparison of two rates. If these are the rate of
one
Page 289 U. S. 650
carrier to point A and that of another to point B while a
relationship of one to the other may be determined, neither the
first nor the second carrier alone can be held to have created the
relation. Assuming that neither rate is unreasonable, the one
carrier cannot be compelled to alter its rate because the other's
is higher or lower for the same service. A carrier or group of
carriers must be the common source of the discrimination -- must
effectively participate in both rates -- if an order for correction
of the disparity is to run against it or them. Where an order is
made under § 3, an alternative must be afforded. [
Footnote 39] The offender or offenders may
abate the discrimination by raising one rate, lowering the other,
or altering both.
Compare American Express Co. v.
Caldwell, 244 U. S. 617,
244 U. S. 624;
United States v. Pennsylvania R. Co., 266 U.
S. 191;
Chicago, I. & L. Ry. Co. v. United
States, 270 U. S. 287,
270 U. S. 292;
Minneapolis & St.L. R. Co. v. Peoria & Pekin U. R.
Co., 270 U. S. 580,
270 U. S. 582.
The situation must be such that the carrier or carriers, if given
an option, have an actual alternative.
The principle has been approved in decisions of this Court with
respect to practices,
Interstate Commerce Comm'n v.
Diffenbaugh, 222 U. S. 42;
Central Railroad of New Jersey v. United States,
257 U. S. 247, and
rates,
East Tenn. V. & G. Ry. Co. v. Interstate Commerce
Comm'n, 181 U. S. 1;
Penn Refining Co. v. Western N.Y. & P. R. Co.,
208 U. S. 208,
208 U. S.
221.
In the
Central Railroad case, it was said (p.
257 U. S.
259):
"But participation merely in joint rates does not make
connecting carriers partners. They can be held jointly and
severally responsible for unjust discrimination only if each
carrier has participated in some way in that which causes the
unjust discrimination, as where a lower joint rate is
Page 289 U. S. 651
given to one locality than to another similarly situated.
(Citing cases.) If this were not so, the legality or illegality of
a carrier's practice would depend not on its own act, but on the
acts of its connecting carriers. . . . What Congress sought to
prevent by that § [3], as originally enacted, was not differences
between localities in transportation rates, facilities, and
privileges, but unjust discrimination between them by the same
carrier or carriers."
While this language was used with respect to circumstances
differing from those here disclosed, it applies to the situation of
appellants, who are by the Commission's order held responsible for
what is not and cannot be the result of their own acts -- the level
of the rates to the Texas ports.
In the
East Tennessee case, the Court said (p.
181 U. S.
18):
"The prohibition of the third section, when that section is
considered in its proper relation, is directed against unjust
discrimination or undue preference arising from the voluntary and
wrongful act of the carriers complained of as having given undue
preference, and does not relate to acts the result of conditions
wholly beyond the control of such carriers."
The appellees contend, however, and the Commission concluded
that, in later cases, the Court has held the principle inapplicable
in circumstances so like those here exhibited that it should not
control our decision in the instant case. One of these is
St.
Louis S.W. Ry. Co. v. United States, 245 U.
S. 136, cited for the proposition that the Commission
has power to prevent carriers which participate in rates from
blanket territory from discriminating against a particular
destination, although one of them does not, with its own lines,
reach such destination, but bills through traffic to it over
connecting lines. The order there under review was for the
establishment of a reasonable joint rate, or, in the alternative,
new through routes with joint rates, under § 15 of the Act, and was
held by
Page 289 U. S. 652
this court to be primarily an order under that section, and not
under § 3. The statement with respect to the possibility of unjust
discrimination by all the participating carriers, even though the
rails of some did not reach the locality prejudiced, is clearly
sound, but is beside the point here in issue, for, in that case, no
question as to the control of the rate to both points by any
carrier affected by the order was raised or decided.
Chicago, I. & L. Ry. Co. v. United States,
270 U. S. 287, is
relied upon because of the statement in the opinion that,
"wherever discrimination is, in fact practiced, an order to
remove it may issue, and the order may extend to every carrier who
participates in inflicting the injury."
This was said with respect to a mandate to three carriers
serving Michigan City, each of which had refused to enter into
interchange arrangements with an electric railroad. Their lines did
not connect directly with the electric line, but required for
interchange the service of an intermediate switching carrier. The
order of the Commission was held proper because each defendant
railroad was solely responsible for the prejudice resulting from
its own refusal to maintain interchange arrangements with the
electric line, and for the preference of maintaining such
arrangements with other carriers at Michigan City. Each could,
without reference to the conduct of any other, correct the unjust
discrimination which it individually practiced. The very question
here is whether the New Orleans lines in fact control the rates to
the Texas ports, and the Commission has answered it in the
negative.
Principal reliance is placed upon
United States v. Illinois
Central R. Co., and
Wyoming Ry. Co. v. United States,
263 U. S. 515. In
the first, it appeared that the Illinois Central equalized rates on
lumber to certain destinations from all its main and branch line
points in blanket origin territory, and from points on certain
independent short lines within the blanket area, but refused
Page 289 U. S. 653
to extend similar blanket rates to producing points on the
Fernwood & Gulf, an independent short line serving the same
area. The Illinois Central's excuse was that it could not afford to
shrink its earnings by larger divisions to the Fernwood & Gulf.
The complaint before the Commission was against both carriers, and
the Commission required that both should abate the unjust
discrimination. [
Footnote
40]
In the second case, it was shown that the Burlington published a
blanket rate on lumber to destinations on a portion of its main
line and to points located on its branch lines, but refused to join
in an equal rate to a point on an independent branch line connected
with the blanketed portion of the main line. The service to the
latter point at the higher combination rate was less than was
rendered to points on the Burlington's branch lines. The Commission
ordered both carriers to abolish the undue preference and
prejudice. [
Footnote 41]
It will be noted that, in the one case, the Illinois Central and
in the other, the Burlington, made the one rate and was a party to
the other. Not only so, but in each case, the trunk line carrier
controlled the joint or combination rate to or from the prejudiced
locality. Quite clearly, the independent line could not equalize
that rate with the one in force to the preferred locality without
the concurrence of the trunk line. Both railroads joined in the
bill to enjoin enforcement of the order in the
Illinois
Central case, but only the independent carrier filed the bill
in the
Burlington case.
The appellees insist that, as the orders ran against the
independent road as well as the trunk line, and this Court refused
to set them aside, it necessarily follows that a carrier may be
liable for unjust discrimination by virtue of its mere
participation in one of the rates whether or
Page 289 U. S. 654
not it controls that rate. The argument ignores the substance
and basis of the decision. The trunk line controlled both rates,
and by its action alone could the disparity be corrected. But the
short line was a party to one of the rates which created the
illegal relation, and was therefore properly joined in the order.
Compare Virginian Ry. Co. v. United States, 272 U.
S. 658,
272 U. S. 665.
The fact, however, that the order included the short line is
entirely insignificant on the question whether the same carrier in
fact controlled both rates and was in fact responsible for the
undue preference and prejudice. The contention of the short line
that it did not participate in the discrimination because it did
not join in the lower rates to the preferred locality maintained by
the Illinois Central, and could not therefore by its own act,
remove the discrimination, was properly overruled. As said by the
Court, that carrier, in joining the Illinois Central in
establishing the prejudicial through rate, was as much a party to
the discrimination as if it had also joined in the lower rates to
the other points alleged to be unduly preferred. If Fernwood &
Gulf could not persuade the Illinois Central to join in a new
nondiscriminatory rate and accord it a proper division, it had a
plain remedy under § 15 of the Act. To make the decision a
precedent for the instant case, it would have to be found that the
New Orleans carriers effectively controlled both the rates to New
Orleans and those to the Texas ports. If they did, obviously, an
order might run not only against the New Orleans carriers, but
against their connections to the Texas ports, albeit the latter did
not control those rates.
We find nothing in any of the decisions which renders
inapplicable the principle upon which the Commission has acted,
with the approval of this Court, for more than forty years in the
administration of § 3, and conclude that the New Orleans lines
could not properly be held guilty of unjust discrimination against
the Texas ports in the absence
Page 289 U. S. 655
of a finding of effective participation in the rates to
them.
3. The conclusions announced render it unnecessary to consider
the other questions pressed by the appellants.
The judgment must be reversed, and the cause remanded to the
District Court for further proceedings in conformity with this
opinion.
Reversed.
[
Footnote 1]
The complaint also attacked rates to and from a portion of the
State of Illinois and the Port of Mobile, Alabama. The Commission,
however, did not deal with these, and the averments of the
complaint in this respect are immaterial to the decision of the
case.
[
Footnote 2]
100 I.C.C. 110.
[
Footnote 3]
The Louisiana Railroad & Navigation Company was, at the time
of the earlier hearings, operated under a single ownership with the
Louisiana Railway & Navigation Company of Texas, and the two
are referred to by the Commission as the L.R. & N. System.
Prior to the institution of suit in the court below, both lines
were acquired by the Louisiana & Arkansas Railway Company. The
latter joined with the other two as plaintiffs in the District
Court. In the opinion, the System will, for convenience, be called
the L.R. & N.
[
Footnote 4]
128 I.C.C. 349.
[
Footnote 5]
160 I.C.C. 345.
[
Footnote 6]
42 F.2d 281.
[
Footnote 7]
U.S.C. Tit. 49, § 1.
[
Footnote 8]
U.S.C. Tit. 49, § 15(1).
[
Footnote 9]
U.S.C. Tit. 49, § 3(1).
[
Footnote 10]
"This cause is restored to the docket for reargument upon all
questions involved, and the attention of counsel is invited to the
question whether the respective relations of the Louisiana ports
and the Texas ports to the export, import, and coastwise traffic
affected, and to the rates condemned, by the orders in controversy
are such that the Louisiana ports may be regarded as localities
unduly or unreasonably preferred by such rates within the sense and
meaning of §§ 3(1) and 15(1) of the Interstate Commerce Act, and
that the Texas ports may be regarded as localities unduly or
unreasonably prejudiced by such rates within the sense and meaning
of the same sections."
Journal, October Term, 1931, p. 342.
[
Footnote 11]
The evidence shows that the regular steamship lines make the
same rates to foreign destinations from all Gulf ports. Tramp
steamers occasionally cut the conventional rate, but this may
happen at any port, and the opportunity to obtain such a reduced
rate does not depend upon the choice of port through which shipment
shall be made.
[
Footnote 12]
New York Produce Exchange v. B. & O. R. Co., 7 I.C.C. 612;
In re Differential Rates, 11 I.C.C. 13.
[
Footnote 13]
In Chamber of Commerce of New York v. N.Y.C. & H. R. Co., 24
I.C.C. 55, 74, the Commission said: "We have no jurisdiction of the
ocean rates, and must deal with this question as though the ports
were destinations, instead of gateways."
[
Footnote 14]
Since 1887, § 1 has forbidden that an export or import rate be
unreasonably high, and, since the Transportation Act 1920, § 400
et seq., the Commission has been charged to see that the
rate be not so low as to render the receipts of the business
unremunerative.
[
Footnote 15]
New Orleans Board of Trade v. Illinois Cent. R. Co., 23 I.C.C.
465; In re Import and Domestic Rates, 36 I.C.C. 389; In re Import
and Domestic Rates -- Clay, 39 I.C.C. 132.
[
Footnote 16]
The Commission has recognized the same principle. Ashland Fire
Brick Co. v. Southern Ry. Co., 22 I.C.C. 115, 121; Chamber of
Commerce of New York v. N.Y.C. & H. R. Co., 24 I.C.C. 55, 63,
70, 75; Maritime Assn. of Boston v. Ann Arbor R. Co., 95 I.C.C.
539, 565.
[
Footnote 17]
Mobile Chamber of Commerce v. Mobile & Ohio R. Co., 32
I.C.C. 272; Astoria v. Spokane, Portland & Seattle Ry. Co., 38
I.C.C. 16.
[
Footnote 18]
See the explanation of Senator Cullom, chairman of the
Committee having charge of the original bill, Cong.Rec. 49th Cong.,
1st Sess., vol. 17, part 4, pp. 3471, 3472. House proceedings,
Cong.Rec. vol. 17, part 7, pp. 7277, 7294, 7298.
And see
the Report of the Committee of the Senate, Report No. 46, 49th
Cong., 1st Sess., p. 57, referring to the investigation by a
committee of the British Parliament:
"Other important conclusions were reached by the Committee as
follows:"
" That a system of equal mileage rates, or charges in proportion
to distance, was inexpedient and impracticable for the following
reasons:"
" (a) It would prevent railway companies from lowering their
fares and rates, so as to compete with traffic by sea, by canal, or
by a shorter or otherwise cheaper railway, and would thus deprive
the public of the benefit of competition, and the company of a
legitimate source of profit."
"
* * * *"
" In short, to impose equal mileage on companies would be to
deprive the public of the benefit of much of the competition which
now exists, or has existed, to raise the charges on the public in
many cases where the companies now find it to their interest to
lower them, and to perpetuate monopolies in carriage, trade, and
manufacture in favor of those rates and places which are nearest or
least expensive where the varying charges of the companies now
create competition."
[
Footnote 19]
Export Trade of Boston, 1 I.C.C. 25; New York Produce Exchange
v. B. & O. R. Co. , 7 I.C.C. 612; In the Matter of Differential
Rates, 11 I.C.C. 13.
[
Footnote 20]
Cong.Rec. 59th Cong., 1st Sess., vol. 40, Part 2, pp. 1777,
1788; Part 3, pp. 2084, 2085, 2086, 2247, 2248; Part 4, p. 3792;
Part 5, p. 4111; Part 7, p. 6683. Representative Mann, a member of
the committee, said, in explaining the purposes of the bill before
the House (Cong.Rec. vol. 40, Part 3, p. 2247):
". . . We do not give them the power to say which port shall be
built up, which city shall be preferred; we leave open the
competitive forces of the railways. The old bills which we had
sought to stifle competition; we leave competition in force. The
railroads running south, west of the Mississippi, and the railroads
running east, north of the Ohio, will have to fight out the
question as to which road shall carry the grain for export
abroad."
And again:
"It will not give the Commission the power to determine
differentials, the power to say whether grain from the Northwest
shall be shipped for export by way of the Gulf ports or the north
Atlantic ports, the power to destroy the law of competition. . .
."
There is much more to the same effect.
[
Footnote 21]
Report No. 591, 59th Cong., 1st Sess., p. 3:
"As but little complaint has been made to the committee
concerning classification, it was not deemed wise at this time to
suggest new legislation upon that subject. So too with the question
of the relation of rates. The committee has not deemed it wise at
this time to suggest new legislation to change existing law upon
that subject. It is one of very great importance -- interesting,
however, as a rule -- to certain particular communities, rather
than to the public at large. It involves conflicts between towns
and cities, rather than the public generally, and it relates more
to the building up of certain local interests of a local nature,
rather than to the interests of the people of the whole
country."
[
Footnote 22]
Chamber of Commerce of N.Y. v. N.Y.C. & H. R. Co., 24 I.C.C.
55; Astoria v. S., P. & S. Ry. Co., 38 I.C.C. 16.
[
Footnote 23]
It said (24 I.C.C. 75):
". . . The Boston interests join in the contention that the
railroads should so adjust their rates as to insure movement of a
certain or substantial part of the traffic through those ports.
Neither the carriers nor the Commission has any right to undertake
to so apportion the traffic between rival ports or cities. . . .
The Pennsylvania and the Baltimore & Ohio have the lawful right
to maintain lower rates to and from Baltimore and Philadelphia than
they contemporaneously maintain to and from New York. They would
probably also have the right to make these rates the same to and
from all of those ports if they chose to do so. The Boston lines
have an undoubted right to make such rates to and from Boston as
their interests demand, subject only to the limitations that the
rates must be reasonable. . . ."
[
Footnote 24]
Compare, however, Galveston Commercial Assn. v. A.
& S. Ry. Co., 109 I.C.C. 114, 125.
[
Footnote 25]
Cotton and Cotton Linters to Pacific Coast Ports, 69 I.C.C. 735;
Sugar cases of 1922, 81 I.C.C. 448.
[
Footnote 26]
Canned Goods and Iron & Steel from Gulf Ports, 91 I.C.C.
623.
[
Footnote 27]
Inland Empire Shippers League v. Director General, 59 I.C.C.
321.
[
Footnote 28]
Maritime Assn. v. Ann Arbor R. Co., 95 I.C.C. 539; 126
I.C.C.199.
[
Footnote 29]
Coffee from Galveston, Tex. and other Gulf Ports, 58 I.C.C. 716;
64 I.C.C. 26; Charleston Traffic Bureau v. Alabama G.S. R. Co., 89
I.C.C. 501. In a number of other cases, the Commission has
indicated a belief that it possessed such authority.
[
Footnote 30]
In a dissenting opinion Commissioner Hall said (Galveston
Commercial Assn. v. G., H. & S.A. Ry. Co., 128 I.C.C. 399):
"In deciding this strife between Texas ports and Louisiana
ports, confined as it is to import, export, and coastwise rates,
the producers and shippers who pay those rates seem to have been
lost from sight."
[
Footnote 31]
See the Commission's findings, 128 I.C.C. 366, 372,
374-376, and the opinions of Commissioners McManamy and Taylor, 128
I.C.C. 399.
[
Footnote 32]
Blackstrap Molasses from Louisiana Points to Kansas and
Oklahoma, 171 I.C.C. 583; 171 I.C.C. 591.
[
Footnote 33]
The conditions on the L.R. & N., while differing in fact
from those affecting the T. & P., present the same question and
need not be separately stated.
[
Footnote 34]
The finding is:
"The New Orleans carriers participate in a full line of joint
commodity rates to and from Gulf ports from and to both the
junction and local points on their lines. While, under the rules
governing the southwestern carriers and their tariff-publishing
agents, the New Orleans carriers have the power to increase the
rates from points served by them to the Texas ports without
concurrence of their connections, a reduction in such rates would
require the consent and concurrence of the participating Texas
lines."
160 I.C.C. 356.
[
Footnote 35]
Southern Ry. Co. v. United States, 204 F. 465;
Chicago, I. & L. Ry. v. United States, 270 U.
S. 287; Rates on Grain Milled in Transit, 35 I.C.C.
27.
[
Footnote 36]
Lake Dock Coal cases, 89 I.C.C. 170; Seneca Wire & Mfg. Co.
v. B. & O. R. Co., 112 I.C.C. 95.
[
Footnote 37]
This doctrine has been applied by the Commission in at least
forty-five cases, under varying circumstances containing one or
more of the elements mentioned. It was first announced soon after
the organization of the Commission in Eau Claire Board of Trade v.
C.M. & St. P. R. Co., 5 I.C.C. 264, was elaborated in Ashland
Fire Brick Co. v. Southern Ry. Co., 22 I.C.C. 115, and has been
referred to as the doctrine of the Ashland Fire Brick case since
that time. For a reference to some of the decisions applying the
rule,
see the dissenting opinion of Commissioner Porter in
Duluth Chamber of Commerce v. C. & N.W. Ry. Co., 156 I.C.C.
156, 173.
[
Footnote 38]
Chamber of Commerce of New York v. N.Y.C. & H. R. Co., 24
I.C.C. 55, 75; Molasses Rates from Mobile, 28 I.C.C. 666, 669;
Sugar cases of 1922, 81 I.C.C. 448, 471; Valley Camp Coal Co. v. B.
& O. R. Co., 88 I.C.C. 682, 686; Maritime Assn. of Boston v.
Ann Arbor R. Co., 95 I.C.C. 539, 565, 572-575; 126 I.C.C. 215; Lake
Cargo Coal Rates, 1925, 101 I.C.C. 513, 545; Mobile Chamber of
Commerce v. M.S., B. & P. R. Co., 129 I.C.C. 419, 422; Bananas
from Gulf Ports, 140 I.C.C. 682 (Eastman, Commissioner, concurring,
at 684); Lake Charles Harbor & T. Dist. v. Brimstone R. &
C. Co., 157 I.C.C. 720, 723.
[
Footnote 39]
This is not true of an order pursuant to § 15(1), prescribing
maximum or minimum or maximum and minimum rates, but the present
orders were not issued under that section.
[
Footnote 40]
Swift Lumber Co. v. F. & G.R. Co., 61 I.C.C. 485.
[
Footnote 41]
Pioneer Lumber Co. v. Director General, 64 I.C.C. 485.
MR. JUSTICE STONE, dissenting.
The Interstate Commerce Commission, acting under § 3(1) and §
15(1), of the Interstate Commerce Act, 24 Stat. 379, as amended by
Transportation Act, 1920, 41 Stat. 456, after extensive
investigation, has found that the rates of rail carriers on
commodities moving in import, export, and coastwise transportation
from or to points in Texas, Oklahoma, and Southern Kansas, and in
Louisiana west of the Mississippi River, were unduly prejudicial to
Galveston and other Texas Gulf ports and unduly preferential of New
Orleans. Its order, framed to restrict, but not to remove entirely,
the discrimination, sustained by the District Court of three judges
below, is now held void and set aside by this Court. I think that
the order is within the competency of the Commission, is supported
by the evidence, and should in all respects be upheld.
Stated generally, the discrimination complained of is the
maintenance of rates by the rail carriers which give no recognition
to the proximity of Galveston and other Texas ports to the interior
points involved. The rates thus deprive the Texas ports of the
natural advantage of their geographical position over that of a
rival port, New Orleans, and, as the commercial advantages of New
Orleans exceed those of the Texas ports, the rates result in the
diversion of traffic to the former from territory normally
tributary to the latter. The Commission found that, although the
length of haul from the interior shipping
Page 289 U. S. 656
points to the Texas ports is less than that to New Orleans, that
difference varying from 162 to 213 miles from typical points,
[
Footnote 2/1] the carriers have
long maintained the same, and in many instances substantially lower
rates to New Orleans. In territory nearer to New Orleans than to
the Texas ports, the lesser service has, on the other hand, been
given recognition by correspondingly lower rates. The Commission
has found, and it is not questioned, that transportation costs and
conditions throughout the southwest territory are substantially the
same; that the rates established by the carriers disregard
generally and materially the amounts and costs of service; that the
discrimination has deprived, and will continue to deprive, the
Texas ports of the natural advantage of their more favorable
geographical position, and has resulted, and will continue to
result, in building up the Port of New Orleans to their detriment
and at their expense. The order assailed seeks to curtail this
discrimination and the injury which it inflicts. It leaves
undisturbed the lower rates in force to New Orleans from points
nearer that city than Galveston, and permits parity of rates where
the distance to New Orleans does not exceed that to Galveston by
more than 25 percent, but, for differences in distance exceeding 25
percent, it has named minimum differentials under the rates
maintained to New Orleans.
In holding that the Commission is without power to make the
order, the Court does not deny that a discrimination which is
produced by charging equal rates for unequal service is prohibited
by the statute as much as one resulting from unequal rates for
equal service.
Compare The Shreveport Case, 234 U.
S. 342,
234 U. S. 346.
Nor does the Court consider material, in this respect, the
findings
Page 289 U. S. 657
of the Commission that the rates to Texas ports and New Orleans
are both reasonable to shippers, in that the former are not too
high, or the latter so low, as to cast a burden on other traffic.
For it is not denied that the Commission may remove a
discrimination effected by rates which are within the zone of
reasonableness if the discrimination is one forbidden by § 3(1) of
the Act.
American Express Co. v. Caldwell, 244 U.
S. 617;
United States v. Illinois Central Ry.
Co., 263 U. S. 515,
263 U. S. 524.
It is not suggested that a discrimination effected by reasonable
rates may not result in gross injury to the locality discriminated
against, and the opinion does not question the correctness of the
findings here that such injury is inflicted on the Texas ports by
the prohibited rates. The issue is thus narrowed to two questions
-- first, whether the Acts of Congress giving broad powers to the
Commission to remove discriminations resulting in undue or
unreasonable prejudice to a "locality" have conferred any power on
the Commission to curtail an unduly prejudicial discrimination
against a port, and second, whether, assuming that the Commission
has such power, it may order the removal of the discrimination by
the appellant carriers who participate in the discriminatory rates,
although their rails reach only New Orleans, and not the Texas
ports.
First. The Court holds that this power is lacking
because the locality injured by the discrimination, a port, is
neither the origin nor the ultimate destination of the traffic
involved, but a gateway through which it passes, albeit it is
arrested there pending its transshipment upon a new and independent
contract for ocean transportation. It is said that a gateway is not
a "locality" within the meaning of the Act because it was never
intended that the statute should forbid discrimination against
localities which are not points of origin or ultimate destination,
however unreasonable and unjust the discrimination may be.
Page 289 U. S. 658
The words of the statute neither state nor suggest such an
exception.
Section 3(1) of the Interstate Commerce Act declares:
"It shall be unlawful for any common carrier . . . to make or
give any undue or unreasonable preference or advantage to any
particular person, company, firm, corporation, or locality, or any
particular description of traffic, in any respect whatsoever, or to
subject any particular person, company, firm, corporation, or
locality, or any particular description of traffic, to any undue or
unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage in any respect
whatsoever."
Section 15(1) gives to the Commission plenary power to remove
any such "unjustly discriminatory or unduly preferential"
individual or joint rate by ordering the carrier or carriers to
cease and desist from the violation and by prescribing a just and
reasonable individual or joint rate to be observed by the carrier
or carriers concerned. On its face, the prohibition of any undue
and unreasonable prejudice to "any particular locality" "in any
respect whatsoever" would seem so plainly to include a port as to
leave no room for construction.
Compare United States v.
Shreveport Grain & Elevator Co., 287 U. S.
77;
Crooks v. Harrelson, 282 U. S.
55;
Van Camp & Sons v. American Can Co.,
278 U. S. 245,
278 U. S.
253.
I can find nothing in the purpose or history of the statute
which suggests that it means any less than it says. This Court has
often declared that the purpose of the all-embracing language of
the statute was to suppress every form of unreasonable
discrimination which it was within the power of Congress to
condemn.
Merchants' Warehouse Co. v. United States,
283 U. S. 501,
283 U. S. 512;
Louisville & Nashville R. Co. v. United States,
282 U. S. 740,
282 U. S.
749-750;
The Shreveport Case, supra,
234 U. S. 356;
Louisville & Nashville R. Co. v. Mottley, 219 U.
S. 467. It has said that discrimination was the
principal thing aimed at, and "the
Page 289 U. S. 659
purpose of Congress was to cut up by the roots every form of
discrimination, favoritism, and inequality."
Louisville &
Nashville R. Co. v. Mottley, supra, 219 U. S.
478.
Statutory language so unambiguous and a purpose so comprehensive
do not readily yield to the conclusion that a locality which is a
port is not a "locality" within the meaning of the Act. The bare
fact that a port is a gateway, and not the ultimate destination of
the traffic, does not support that conclusion, for the commercial
interests of a port, always of great magnitude, may suffer the same
destruction from discriminatory rates as do shippers or other
industrial interests at points of origin or destination. A rate
structure which diverts from one port to another a portion of the
ocean-borne traffic which would otherwise naturally pass through
the former, sufficient to destroy the business of banks, marine
insurance companies, freight forwarders, freight and ship brokers,
stevedores, tonnage companies, pilots, drydocks, ship supply and
bunker coal merchants, customs brokers, export and import
commission houses centered there would seem to have an effect upon
the commerce and general welfare of the country of precisely the
kind which the Act was intended to prohibit and the Commission
empowered to prevent. So the Commission has concluded in a series
of cases dealing with discrimination against ports, going back to
the first years of its existence.
See New York Produce
Exch. v. B. & O. R. Co., 7 I.C.C. 612, 658, 660; In re Export
and Domestic Rates, 8 I.C.C. 214; In re Differential Rates, 11
I.C.C. 13; Chamber of Commerce of N.Y. v. New York Central & H.
R. Co., 24 I.C.C. 55; 27 I.C.C. 238; Astoria v. S. P. & S. R.
Co., 38 I.C.C. 16; In re Import Rates, 24 I.C.C. 78; New York
Harbor Case, 47 I.C.C. 643; Mobile Chamber of Commerce v. Mobile
& O. R. Co., 57 I.C.C. 554; Coffee from Galveston and other
Gulf Ports, 58 I.C.C. 716; Id., 64 I.C.C. 26; Charleston Traffic
Bureau v. Ala. &
Page 289 U. S. 660
G.S. R. Co., 89 I.C.C. 501; Maritime Assn. of Boston Chamber of
Commerce v. Ann Arbor R. Co., 95 I.C.C. 539; Oswego v. B. & O.
R. Co., 151 I.C.C. 717.
This administrative practice and construction cannot be
dismissed with the observation that, where "a statutory body has
assumed a power plainly not granted, no amount of such
interpretation is binding upon the court," for the question
obviously is whether or not a power was granted which the language
of the statute plainly embraces and which certainly was not plainly
denied. In determining that question when the meaning of the
statute is doubtful on its face, we have often said that
administrative construction is of persuasive force,
see United
States v. Chicago, North Shore & Milwaukee R. Co.,
288 U. S. 1;
New
York, N.H. & H. R. Co. v. Interstate Commerce Comm'n,
200 U. S. 361,
200 U. S. 401,
particularly where, as here, the statute has been frequently
amended and the provision relied upon retained in identical form.
Compare Brewster v. Gage, 280 U.
S. 327,
280 U. S. 336;
National Lead Co. v. United States, 252 U.
S. 140,
252 U. S. 147.
This construction certainly cannot be summarily disregarded in
favor of another which departs both from the plain meaning of the
words and from the policy which has hitherto been thought to have
inspired their use.
To support such a departure, it is said that, as the railroads,
before the enactment of the statute, had in some instances
attempted to equalize competing ports by setting up a rate
structure which did not conform wholly to the carrier service
involved, and as Congress, in the Interstate Commerce Act, evinced
no intention to prevent competition for business between rail
carriers, it could not have intended by this legislation forbidding
discrimination prejudicial to localities to forbid discriminations
between rival ports, however unreasonable and injurious.
The port differentials and equalizations maintained prior to the
passage of the original act, in order to secure
Page 289 U. S. 661
a fair distribution of traffic among the Atlantic ports and the
carriers serving them, were very different in quality and
prejudicial effect upon the localities concerned from the rate
structure resulting in the discrimination disclosed here. [
Footnote 2/2] The existence of those
equalizations before 1887 and the fact that, in some instances
since that date, they have been regarded as innocuous even by the
Commission itself, can hardly lend support to the supposition that
the statute was not intended to forbid destructive discriminations
in that form as well as in any other. The argument seems to be that
the statute cannot be deemed to forbid unjust discriminations
against ports, since, if it did, all rates to competing ports not
measured by mileage or carrier service would be forbidden, whether
unjust or not. With equal plausibility, it was argued that, because
competition between carriers was an established practice before the
enactment of § 3 and is not forbidden by the Act, no discrimination
induced by carrier competition was forbidden. But that construction
was rejected by this Court,
Wight v. United States,
167 U. S. 512,
167 U. S. 517;
United States v. Illinois Central R. Co., supra; Merchants'
Warehouse Co. v. United States, supra, for the same reason
that the present construction should be rejected -- that, although
carrier competition was not destroyed by the Interstate Commerce
Act, it was limited by the prohibition of § 3 of those
discriminations which, in the light of all the circumstances, are
found to be undue or unreasonable.
Page 289 U. S. 662
The statute does not purport to prohibit all discriminations. It
reaches only those against either localities or shippers which
result in prejudice which is "undue or unreasonable."
Cf.
Nashville, C. & St.L. Ry. v. Tennessee, 262 U.
S. 318,
262 U. S. 322.
Hence, in determining whether a discrimination involved in a port
equalization is "undue or unreasonable," competition is a factor
which may not be ignored (
see Interstate Commerce Commission v.
Alabama Midland Ry., 168 U. S. 144,
168 U. S.
170), the Commission is not to leave out of account
either past history or practical experience, or the effect of the
discrimination on the ports concerned. But, even though the
exigencies of competition may be entitled to greater consideration
in a case of discrimination between ports than in one of
discrimination between shippers, the weight which is given to it
and to the other relevant facts in determining whether the
discrimination is so unjust as to be forbidden does not go to the
Commission's power, but to the propriety of its exercise.
United States v. Illinois Central R. Co., supra,
263 U. S. 525;
Interstate Commerce Commission v. Alabama Midland Ry.,
supra. That the Commission so conceives its powers and
function in considering a rate adjustment equalizing ports is
apparent from its statement of the problem in the present case:
"Such an adjustment necessarily disregards distance and
commercial, instead of natural, advantages control. We have
consistently refused to condemn such an adjustment where it is
shown to serve the best interests of the public, but where, as
here, it builds up one port at the expense of another equally
favored by natural advantages from the origin territory here
considered, a line must be found beyond which distance may not be
disregarded."
This language of the Commission appears to me to suggest the
only reasonable interpretation of the statute consonant with its
language, its history, and its background. The statute does not
command, or the Commission's order
Page 289 U. S. 663
direct, that the rates shall be measured exclusively by mileage
or carrier service; carrier competition for business passing
through gateways or elsewhere is not forbidden, but, when the
discrimination goes so far beyond the line of reasonableness as to
result in the commercial destruction of a locality, the Commission
may declare it "undue or unreasonable," and therefore forbidden by
the statute, whether aimed at ports or points of shipment or
destination. Nothing that this Court has ever said is inconsistent
with this conclusion. The legislative history of the statute seems
to support, rather than to deny, it.
Close scrutiny of the legislative history of the original act
and of the Hepburn Amendment fails to disclose any intention to
except from the forbidden discriminations against localities, undue
or unreasonable discriminations against ports. Senator Cullom, who
was in charge of the earlier bill, made no reference to the present
question in his explanatory statement, [
Footnote 2/3] cited in the opinion of the
Page 289 U. S. 664
Court, [
Footnote 2/4] and none
is to be found in the House proceedings to which reference is also
made. [
Footnote 2/5] Senator Cullom
emphasized the fact that the discriminations forbidden included
those against localities, and nowhere suggested any exceptions.
Mention in the Report of the Senate Committee of the investigation
of a committee of the British Parliament and the quotation of its
conclusions [
Footnote 2/6] are
without significance here. Those conclusions were not indorsed by
the Senate Committee, and did not deal with undue discriminations
produced by railroad competition. It is true that, in the debates
in Congress on the Hepburn Amendment, it was pointed out in several
instances that the bill did not confer on the Commission the
general
Page 289 U. S. 665
power to fix differentials to ports or to any other points,
[
Footnote 2/7] but it was also
pointed out that
"Section 3 of the original act applies just the same. We have
not undertaken to amend, limit, or extend § 3. Whatever is unjust
and discriminatory under § 3 is unjust under the provisions of this
bill, and such will be prohibited. . . . [
Footnote 2/8]"
Moreover, the basis for this want of power to fix differentials
was not that a port is not a "locality" within the meaning of § 3,
but that differential rates on different roads cannot be fully
controlled without the fixing of a minimum rate. [
Footnote 2/9] And it was recognized in the
decisions of
Page 289 U. S. 666
this Court prior to the enactment of Transportation Act 1920,
conferring the power to fix minimum rates, that unjust
discriminations produced by the relation of rates charged or
participated in by the same carrier might be forbidden by the
Commission by lowering the higher rate (
compare St. Louis S.W.
Ry. Co. v. United States, 245 U. S. 136,
245 U. S. 144)
or by an order which left the carrier free to raise or continue the
lower rate; "the compulsion being that, if the low rate is
retained, the rate applicable to the locality or article
discriminated against must be reduced."
Skinner & Eddy
Corp. v. United States, 249 U. S. 557,
249 U. S.
566.
Second. The Court also holds that, even if a port is a
"locality" within the meaning of the statute, and prejudicial
discriminations against it are forbidden, still the Commission is
without power to order the Texas & Pacific Railroad Company and
the Louisiana Railroad & Navigation Company
Page 289 U. S. 667
to remove the discrimination. Both these lines reach New Orleans
with their own rails, and both participate in through rates and a
full line of joint rates between local and junction points on their
own lines and the Texas ports. They thus control the rate to New
Orleans, and are parties to rates to the Texas ports and to the
prejudicial discrimination. Nevertheless, it is said that the
Commission is without power to make an order removing the
discrimination which does not afford to the carriers an alternative
method of removing it, either by lowering the rates to the Texas
ports or raising those to New Orleans, and that the present order
does not afford such an alternative because of the appellants'
inability to control the rates to the Texas ports.
The Commission may, in directing the removal of a discriminatory
rate or practice, not otherwise objectionable,
Page 289 U. S. 668
allow to the carrier a choice of methods of removing the
discrimination by the modification of one rate or practice or the
other. By the present order, the two carriers are left free to
remove the discrimination by raising the New Orleans rate which
they control, or by entering into lower joint or through rates with
the connecting carriers to the Texas ports -- a latitude which may
serve the interest of the carriers better than would an order
specifically directing them to raise the New Orleans rates. Beyond
question, these roads can remove the discrimination by raising the
New Orleans rates, and it neither appears nor is it argued that
they cannot remove it by lowering the rates to the Texas ports by
agreement with their connecting carriers or, in default of
agreement, by reducing their own division and securing a
corresponding reduction of the joint rate on application to the
Commission under § 15(6).
See St. Louis Southwestern R. Co. v.
United States, 245 U. S. 136,
245 U. S. 139,
note 2;
compare United States v. Illinois Central R. Co.,
supra, 263 U. S.
521.
But the statute does not compel the Commission to afford such an
alternative or permit an offending carrier to avoid its salutary
provisions merely for the reason that, although participating in
both the offending rates, it can with certainty control only one.
It is true that, in cases arising before the enactment of
Transportation Act 1920, by which power was given to the Commission
to fix a minimum rate, it could not remove a discrimination by
prescribing a minimum rate to one of the competing localities. But
it could remove the discrimination by imposing a lower maximum
rate, even though a joint rate participated in by the carrier whose
rails did not reach the locality discriminated against (
compare
St. Louis Southwestern Ry. Co. v. United States, supra), or,
as already mentioned, it could leave the carriers free to remove
the discrimination by raising one or lowering the other.
See
American Express Co. v. Caldwell, supra, 244 U. S. 624;
United
Page 289 U. S. 669
States v. Pennsylvania R. Co., 266 U.
S. 191. And now that the Commission has power under §
15(1) to fix a minimum rate, it may equally command the removal of
the discrimination by directing a rate to be raised, just as, where
the carrier maintains discriminatory practices, the Commission may
direct the modification of one and not the other, and is not bound
to allow the carrier a choice.
Merchants' Warehouse Co. v.
United States, supra,
283 U. S. 513;
New York, New Haven & Hartford R.
v. Interstate Commerce Comm'n, supra, 200 U. S. 404.
The fact that the Commission has given to the carrier an option to
remove the discrimination by arrangement with the connecting
carriers, through which the traffic reaches the Texas ports, does
not afford to the carrier any ground for complaint or impair the
power of the Commission to make the order.
The situation here appears to be identical with that presented
to this Court in
United States v. Illinois Central R. Co.,
supra, and in
St. Louis Southwestern Ry. Co. v. United
States, supra. In both cases, the carriers' rails reached one
of the competing points only through its connections. In the first,
the order leaving the carrier free to remove the discrimination by
raising one rate or lowering the other, and in the second, an order
requiring the carrier to remove the discrimination by establishing
a lower joint rate with its connections was upheld by this Court.
In
St. Louis Southwestern Ry. Co. v. United States, this
Court said, page
245 U. S.
144:
"Carriers insist also that the order is void on the ground,
that, since their 'rails do not reach Paducah, they cannot be
guilty of discrimination against that city.' They, however, bill
traffic via Cairo or Memphis through to Paducah in connection with
the Illinois Central, thus reaching Paducah, although not on their
own rails. And, thereby, they become effective instruments of
discrimination. Localities require protection as much from
combinations of connecting carriers as from single carriers whose
'rails'
Page 289 U. S. 670
reach them. Clearly the power of Congress and of the Commission
to prevent interstate carriers from practicing discriminating
against a particular locality is not confined to those whose rails
enter it."
The judgment should be affirmed.
THE CHIEF JUSTICE, MR. JUSTICE BRANDEIS, and MR. JUSTICE CARDOZO
concur in this opinion.
[
Footnote 2/1]
The distances range from 162 miles from typical points in
Southern Kansas and 174 miles from typical points in Oklahoma to
213 miles from typical points in Northern Texas. Waco is 233,
Dallas 291, and Fort Worth 308 miles nearer Galveston than New
Orleans.
[
Footnote 2/2]
Differentials were adopted by voluntary agreement of the
carriers to eliminate competitive rate wars, ruinous to the
railroads, and to the localities concerned. Their effect was to
preserve, rather than to destroy, a fair distribution of the
traffic from the West to the Atlantic Seaboard.
See John
B. Daish, Atlantic Port Differentials (1918); Preferential
Transportation Rates, Report of the United States Tariff
Commission, 1922, p. 279.
Cf. Commissioner Prouty, In the
Matter of Differential Rates, 11 I.C.C. 13, 61 ff., and the briefs
in the same case reprinted in the appendix to the hearings on the
Hepburn Amendment before the Senate Committee on Interstate
Commerce (1905), Vol. V, p. 407.
[
Footnote 2/3]
With respect to § 3, Senator Cullom said:
"The third section . . . contains a general prohibition of every
variety of unjust discrimination. The section covers two subjects.
The first paragraph prohibits the giving of any undue or
unreasonable preference to any particular person or locality, or
any particular description of traffic, in any respect whatever, and
declares such a preference unlawful. . . . This covers in general
terms, though by no means so completely, the provision of § 2 as to
discriminations against persons, but goes further and includes
discriminations against localities or particular descriptions of
traffic. The language adopted in this paragraph is substantially
that of the English statute on the subject, which has been
repeatedly construed by the English courts, so that its meaning has
already been judicially established. . . ."
Cong.Rec. 49th Cong., 1st Sess., vol. 17, p. 3472. It may not be
without significance that the English antecedents of § 3, The
Railway and Canal Traffic Act of 1854 (17 & 18 Vict., c. 31, §
2), and the Act of 1873, amending it (36 & 37 Vict., c. 48, §
11), failed to include preference of localities.
See also Senator Cullom's final answer to Senator
Hoar's question whether the effect of § 4 of the proposed act,
prohibiting the charging of more for a shorter than a longer
distance over the same line under substantially similar conditions,
would not eliminate port differentials, then in existence, favoring
Boston:
". . . If we are going to regulate these corporations at all, if
we are going to stop unjust discriminations and the secret rebates
by which towns are built up and towns are destroyed, by which
individuals are destroyed and individuals are built up, we must
have something in the bill which will mean something, or else we
might as well lay the bill on the table and go at other
business."
Cong.Rec., 49th Cong., 2d Sess., vol. 15, pp. 485, 486.
Compare his statement in discussing the conference
report:
"It has been said over and over again here that the railroad
companies would build up one man and crush another; that their
policy has been to destroy one locality or city and build up
another. Here we have undertaken to so regulate them as to prevent
them from doing those things so far as we can do so."
Cong.Rec. 49th Cong., 2d Sess., vol. 18, p. 660.
[
Footnote 2/4]
See the opinion of the Court,
note 18
[
Footnote 2/5]
See Cong.Rec. 49th Cong., 1st Sess., vol. 17, pp. 7277,
7294, 7298.
[
Footnote 2/6]
Report No. 46, 49th Cong., 1st Sess., p. 57.
Compare
the Committee's statement of the fundamental theory and purpose of
the bill (p. 215):
"The provisions of the bill are based upon the theory that the
paramount evil chargeable against the operation of the
transportation systems of the United States as now conducted is
unjust discrimination between persons, places, commodities, or
particular descriptions of traffic. The underlying purpose and aim
of the measure is the prevention of these discriminations. . .
."
[
Footnote 2/7]
See Cong. Rec., 59th Cong., 1st Sess., vol. 40, pp.
1788, 2084-5, 2247, 2248, 3792, 6683.
[
Footnote 2/8]
For the full quotation,
see 289
U.S. 627fn2/9|>note 9,
infra.
[
Footnote 2/9]
Compare the statement of Mr. Stevens, a member of the
House Committee:
"My people are just as much interested that there should not be
any undue control of differential rates. . . . But it is just as
clear to us and to the whole committee that there is no such power
in this bill. . . . The situation presented by the bill and the
reasons why differentials are not covered are very simple. Under
this bill, the Commission would have authority to fix what, in its
judgment, would be a just, reasonable, and fairly remunerative rate
or rates as the maximum to be charged. It would have no authority
to fix an absolute rate, which must be observed by the carrier, and
no authority to fix a minimum rate below which the carrier cannot
go, and a preferential cannot be controlled without there is
authority to control absolutely both legs of the differential. In
this case, the Commission cannot control either. It must fix a rate
which shall be just and reasonable and fairly remunerative as the
maximum to be charged. This leaves the carrier to charge anything
it pleases below the maximum. And since there is no power to fix
any absolute rate and no minimum rate, there is no power in the
Commission to control the relation of rates, and so no power to
control the differential."
Mr. Olmsted then asked whether, "under this bill, the railroads
may make as many unjust discriminations as they please and the
Commission would be powerless to correct them." Mr. Stevens
answered:
"Oh, no; . . . Section 3 of the original act applies just the
same. We have not undertaken to amend, limit, or extend § 3.
Whatever is unjust and discriminatory under § 3 is unjust under the
provisions of this bill, and such will be prohibited; but we will
not allow the making of a minimum or absolute rate, which is the
only adequate way of controlling a differential."
It was also pointed out that relative rates on different roads
were not within the control of the Commission. In discussing
differentials, Senator Raynor pointed out that the provisions of
the bill
"are limited to discriminations upon the same roads. The words
'unjustly discriminatory' or 'unduly preferential' or 'prejudicial'
apply to rates and regulations and practices upon the same road,
because there can be no such thing as an unjust discrimination or
an undue preference between different roads supplying different
territory and terminating at different points. . . . If one road
charges an unreasonable rate or a discriminating rate, that would
surely not justify the Commission's adjusting the rate between this
road and some other road
that has no connection with it by law
or privity of contract. . . ."
Cong.Rec. vol. 40, p. 6683. Read in the light of this statement,
there is nothing to support the conclusion of the Court in the
other statement of Senator Raynor referred to in the opinion
(
289
U.S. 627fn20|>note 20) that there is no
"power whatever in the Commission to adjust relative rates and
strike the proper proportions between them. The ports of the United
States therefore are not within the jurisdiction of the Hepburn
Act. If there is a differential between different ports upon
different lines of railroads, there is no provision in this measure
that invests the Commission with the right to change it. It has a
perfect right, of course, where discrimination exists upon the same
line, as if a rate to an inland point compared with a rate to a
terminal point is unreasonable or unjustly discriminatory, to
prescribe a maximum rate; but it has no right to bring competitive
roads struggling for competitive markets within its jurisdiction,
and I deny in its entirety the proposition that the Commission
could, by any exercise of its power, direct or inferential, take
away from any railroad its right to charge its own rates, unless
the rate is unreasonable or unduly preferential or discriminatory
upon its own line."
Cong.Rec. vol. 40. p. 3792.