Thirty-one railroad companies, engaged in transportation between
Chicago and the Atlantic coast, formed themselves into an
association known as the Joint Traffic Association, by which they
agreed that the association should have jurisdiction over
competitive traffic, except as noted, passing through the western
termini of the trunk lines and such other points as might be
thereafter designated, and to fix the rates, fares and charges
therefor, and from time to time change the same. No party to the
agreement was to be permitted to deviate from or change those
rates, fares, or charges, and its action in that respect was not to
affect rates disapproved except to the extent of its interest
therein over its own road. It was further agreed that the powers so
conferred upon the managers should be so construed and exercised as
not to permit violation of the Interstate Commerce Act, and that
the managers should cooperate with the Interstate Commerce
Commission to secure stability and uniformity in rates, fares,
charges, etc. The managers were given power to decide and enforce
the course which should be pursued with connecting companies, not
parties to the agreement, which declined or failed to observe the
established rates. Assessments were authorized in order to pay
expenses, and the agreement was to take effect January 1, 1896, and
to continue in existence for five years. The bill, filed on behalf
of the United States, sought a judgment declaring that agreement
void.
Held:
(1) That ,upon comparing this agreement with the one set forth
in
United States v. Trans-Missouri Freight Association,
166 U. S. 290, the
similarity between them suggests that a similar result should be
reached in the two cases, as the point now taken was urged in that
case, and was then intentionally and necessarily decided.
(2) That, so far as the establishment of rates and fares is
concerned, there is no substantial difference between this
agreement and the one set forth in the
Trans-Missouri
case.
(3) That Congress, with regard to interstate commerce and in the
course of regulating it in the case of railroad corporations, has
the power to say that no contract or combination shall be legal
which shall restrain trade and commerce by shutting out the
operation of the general law of competition.
The bill was filed in this case in the Circuit Court of the
United States for the Southern District of New York for the purpose
of obtaining an adjudication that an agreement
Page 171 U. S. 506
entered into between some thirty-one different railroad
companies was illegal, and enjoining its further execution.
These railroad companies formed most (but not all) of the lines
engaged in the business of railroad transportation between Chicago
and the Atlantic coast, and the object of the agreement, as
expressed in its preamble, was to form an association of railroad
companies
"to aid in fulfilling the purpose of the Interstate Commerce
Act, to cooperate with each other and adjacent transportation
associations to establish and maintain reasonable and just rates,
fares, rules, and regulations on state and interstate traffic, to
prevent unjust discrimination, and to secure the reduction and
concentration of agencies, and the introduction of economics in the
conduct of the freight and passenger service."
To accomplish these purposes, the railroad companies adopted
articles of association by which they agreed that the affairs of
the association should be administered by several different boards,
and that it should have jurisdiction over all competitive traffic
(with certain exceptions therein noted) which passed through the
western termini of the trunk lines (naming them) and such other
points as might be thereafter designated by the managers. The duly
published schedules of rates, fares, and charges, and the rules
applicable thereto, which were in force at the time of the
execution of the agreement and authorized by the different
companies and filed with the Interstate Commerce Commission, were
reaffirmed by the companies composing the association. From time to
time, the managers were to recommend such changes in the rates,
fares, charges, and rules as might be reasonable and just, and
necessary for governing the traffic covered by the agreement and
for protecting the interests of the parties to the agreement, and a
failure to observe such recommendations by any of the parties to
the agreement was to be deemed a violation of the agreement. No
company which was a party to it was permitted in any way to deviate
from or to change the rates, fares, charges, or rules set forth in
the agreement or recommended by the managers except by a resolution
of the board of directors of the company, and its action was not to
affect the rates, etc., disapproved, except to the extent
Page 171 U. S. 507
of its interest therein over its own road. A copy of such
resolution of the board of any company authorizing a change of
rates or fares, etc., was to be immediately forwarded by the
company making the same to the managers of the association, and the
change was not to become effective until thirty days after the
receipt of such resolution by the managers. Upon the receipt of
such resolution, the managers were "to act promptly upon the same,
for the protection of the parties hereto." It was further stated in
the agreement that
"the powers conferred upon the managers shall be so construed
and exercised as not to permit violation of the Interstate Commerce
Act, or any other law applicable to the premises, or any provision
of the charters or the laws applicable to any of the companies
parties hereto, and the managers shall cooperate with the
Interstate Commerce Commission to secure stability and uniformity
in the rates, fares, charges, and rules established
thereunder."
One provision of the agreement was to the effect that the
managers were charged with the duty of securing to each company
which was a party to the agreement equitable proportions of the
competitive traffic covered by the agreement, so far as it could be
legally done. The managers were given power to decide and enforce
the course which should be pursued with connecting companies, not
parties to the agreement, which might decline or fail to observe
the rates, etc., established under it, and the interests of parties
injuriously affected by such action of the managers were to be
accorded reasonable protection insofar as the managers could
reasonably do so. When in the judgment of the managers it was
necessary to the purposes of the agreement, they might determine
the divisions of rates and fares between connecting companies who
were parties to the agreement and connections not parties thereto,
keeping in view uniformity and the equities involved.
Joint freight and passenger agencies might be organized by the
managers, and, if established, were to be so arranged as to give
proper representation to each company party to the agreement.
Soliciting or contracting passenger or freight agencies were not to
be maintained by the companies except
Page 171 U. S. 508
with the approval of the managers, and no one that the managers
decided to be objectionable was to be employed or continued in an
agency. The officials and employees of any of the companies could
be examined, and an investigation made, when in the judgment of the
managers their information or any complaint might so warrant. Any
violation of the agreement was to be followed by a forfeiture of
the offending company in a sum to be determined by the managers,
which should not exceed five thousand dollars, or, if the gross
receipts of the transaction which violated the agreement should
exceed five thousand dollars, the offending party should, in the
discretion of the managers, forfeit a sum not exceeding such gross
receipts. The sums thus collected were to go to the payment of the
expenses of the association, except the offending company should
not participate in the application of its own forfeiture.
The agreement also provided for assessments upon the companies
in order to pay the expenses of the association, and also for the
appointment of commissioners and arbitrators, who were to decide
matters coming before them. No one retiring from the agreement
before the time fixed for its final completion, except by the
unanimous consent of the parties, should be entitled to any refund
from the residue of the deposits remaining at the close of the
agreement.
It was to take effect January 1, 1896, and to continue in
existence five years, after which any company could retire upon
giving ninety days' written notice of its desire to do so.
The bill filed by the government contained allegations showing
that all the defendant railroad companies were common carriers duly
incorporated by the several states through which they passed, and
that they were engaged as such carriers in the transportation of
freight and passengers, separately or in connection with each
other, in trade and commerce continuously carried on among the
several states of the Union and between the several states and the
territories thereof. The bill also charged that the defendants,
unlawfully intending to restrain commerce among the several states
and to prevent competition among the railroads named in respect to
all their
Page 171 U. S. 509
interstate commerce, entered into the agreement referred to
above, and it charged that the agreement was an unlawful one, and a
combination and conspiracy, and that it was entered into in order
to terminate all competition among the parties to is for freight
and passenger traffic, and that the agreement unlawfully restrained
trade and commerce among the several states and territories of the
United States and unlawfully attempted to monopolize a part of such
interstate trade and commerce. The bill ended with the allegation
that the companies were preparing to put into full operation all
the provisions of the agreement, and the relief sought was a
judgment declaring the agreement void and enjoining the parties
from operating their roads under the same. The defendant the
Joint-Traffic Association filed an answer (the other defendants
substantially adopting it) which admitted the making of the
contract, but denied its invalidity or that it is or was intended
to be an unlawful contract, combination, or conspiracy to restrain
trade or commerce or that it was an attempt to monopolize the same,
or that it was intended to restrain or prevent legitimate
competition among the railroads which were parties to the
agreement. The answer, in brief, denied all allegations of unlawful
acts or of an unlawful intent, unless the making of the agreement
itself was an unlawful act. The answer then set forth in quite
lengthy terms a general history of the condition of the railroad
traffic among the various railroads which were parties to the
agreement at the time it was entered into, and alleged the
necessity of some such agreement in order to the harmonious
operation of the different roads, and that it was necessary as well
to the public as to the railroads themselves.
The case came on for hearing of bill and answer, and the circuit
court, after a hearing, dismissed the bill, and upon appeal its
decree was affirmed by the Circuit Court of Appeals for the Second
Circuit, and the government has appealed here.
Page 171 U. S. 558
MR. JUSTICE PECKHAM, after stating the facts, delivered the
opinion of the court.
This case has been most ably argued by counsel both for the
government and the railroad companies. The suit is brought to
obtain a decree declaring null and void the agreement mentioned in
the bill. Upon comparing that agreement with the one set forth in
the case of
United States v. Trans-Missouri Freight
Association, 166 U. S. 290, the
great similarity between them suggests that a similar result should
be reached in the two cases. The respondents, however, object to
this, and give several reasons why this case should not be
controlled by the other. It is, among other things, said that one
of the questions sought to be raised in this case might have been,
but was not, made in the other; that the point therein decided,
after holding that the statute applied to
Page 171 U. S. 559
railroad companies as common carriers, was simply that all
contracts, whether in reasonable as well as in unreasonable
restraint of trade, were included in the terms of the act, and the
question whether the contract then under review was in fact in
restraint of trade in any degree whatever was neither made nor
decided, while it is plainly raised in this.
Again it is asserted that there are differences between the
provisions contained in the two agreements of such a material and
fundamental nature that the decision in the case referred to ought
to form no precedent for the decision of the case now before the
Court.
It is also objected that the statute, if construed as it has
been construed in the
Trans-Missouri case, is
unconstitutional in that it unduly interferes with the liberty of
the individual and takes away from him the right to make contracts
regarding his own affairs, which is guarantied to him by the Fifth
Amendment to the Constitution, which provides that
"[n]o person shall be . . . deprived of life, liberty or
property without due process of law, nor shall private property be
taken for public use without just compensation."
This objection was not advanced in the arguments in the other
case.
Finally, a reconsideration of the questions decided in the
former case is very strongly pressed upon our attention because, as
is stated, the decision in that case is quite plainly erroneous,
and the consequences of such error are far-reaching and disastrous,
and clearly at war with justice and sound policy, and the
construction placed upon the antitrust statute has been received by
the public with surprise and alarm.
We will refer to these propositions in the order in which they
have been named.
As to the first, we think the report of the
Trans-Missouri case clearly shows not only that the point
now taken was there urged upon the attention of the Court, but it
was then intentionally and necessarily decided. The whole
foundation of the case on the part of the government was the
allegation that the agreement there set forth was a contract or
combination in restraint of trade, and unlawful on that account.
If
Page 171 U. S. 560
the agreement did not in fact restrain trade, the government had
no case.
If it did not in any degree restrain trade, it was immaterial
whether the statute embraced all contracts in restraint of trade or
only such as were in unreasonable restraint thereof. There was no
admission or concession in that case that the agreement did in fact
restrain trade to a reasonable degree. Hence, it was necessary to
determine the fact as to the character of the agreement before the
case was made out on the part of the government.
The great stress of the argument on both sides was undoubtedly
upon the question as to the proper construction of the statute, for
that seemed to admit of the most doubt; but the other question was
before the Court, was plainly raised, and was necessarily decided.
The opinion shows this to be true. At page
166 U. S. 341
of the report, the opinion contains the following language:
"The conclusion which we have drawn from the examination above
made of the question before us is that the Anti-Trust act applies
to railroads, and that it renders illegal all agreements which are
in restraint of trade or commerce as we have above defined that
expression, and the question then arises whether the agreement
before us is of that nature. . . . Does the agreement restrain
trade or commerce in any way so as to be a violation of the act? We
have no doubt that it does. The agreement on its face recites that
it is entered into for the purpose of mutual protection by
establishing and maintaining reasonable rates, rules, and
regulations on all freight traffic, both through and local."
"To that end the association is formed, and a body created which
is to adopt rates for all the companies, and a violation of which
subjects the defaulting company to the payment of a penalty, and
although the parties have a right to withdraw from the agreement on
giving thirty days' notice of a desire so to do, yet, while in
force, and assuming it to be lived up to, there can be no doubt
that its direct, immediate, and necessary effect is
Page 171 U. S. 561
to put a restraint upon trade or commerce as described in the
act. For these reasons, the suit of the government can be
maintained without proof of the allegation that the agreement was
entered into for the purpose of restraining trade or commerce or
for maintaining rates above what was reasonable. The necessary
effect of the agreement is to restrain trade, no matter what the
intent was on the part of those who signed it."
The bill of the complainants in that case, while alleging an
illegal and unlawful intent on the part of the railroad companies
in entering into the agreement, also alleged that, by means of the
agreement, the trade, traffic, and commerce in the region of
country affected by the agreement had been and were monopolized and
restrained, hindered, injured, and retarded. These allegations were
denied by defendants.
There was thus a clear issue made by the pleadings as to the
character of the agreement -- whether it was or was not one in
restraint of trade.
The extract from the opinion of the Court above given shows that
the issue so made was not ignored, nor was it assumed as a
concession that the agreement did restrain trade to a reasonable
extent. The statement in the opinion is quite plain, and it
inevitably leads to the conclusion that the question of fact as to
the necessary tendency of the agreement was distinctly presented to
the mind of the Court and was consciously, purposely, and
necessarily decided. It cannot, therefore, be correctly stated that
the opinion only dealt with the question of the construction of the
act, and that it was assumed that the agreement did to some
reasonable extent restrain trade. In discussing the question as to
the proper construction of the act, the Court did not touch upon
the other aspect of the case, in regard to the nature of the
agreement itself, but when the question of construction was
finished, the opinion shows that the question as to the nature of
the agreement was then entered upon and discussed as a fact
necessary to be decided in the case, and that it in fact was
decided. An unlawful intent in entering into the agreement was
held
Page 171 U. S. 562
immaterial, but only for the reason that the agreement did in
fact and, by its terms, restrain trade.
Second. We have assumed that the agreements in the two cases
were substantially alike. This the respondents by no means admit,
and they assert that there are such material and substantial
differences in the provisions of the two instruments as to
necessitate a different result in this case from that arrived at in
the other.
The expressed purpose of the agreement in this case is, among
other things, "to establish and maintain reasonable and just rates,
fares, rules, and regulations on state and interstate traffic." The
companies agree that the schedule of rates and fares already duly
published and in force, and authorized by the companies parties to
the agreement, and filed, as to interstate traffic, with the
Interstate Commerce Commission, shall be reaffirmed, and copies of
all such schedules are to be filed with the managers constituted
under the agreement within ten days after it becomes effective. The
managers may, from time to time, recommend changes in the rates,
etc., and a failure to observe the recommendations is deemed a
violation of the agreement. No company can deviate from these rates
except under a resolution of its board of directors, and such
resolution can only take effect thirty days after such service of a
copy thereof on the managers, who, upon receipt thereof, "shall act
promptly for the protection of the parties hereto." For a violation
of the agreement, the offending company forfeits to the association
a sum to be determined by the managers thereof, not exceeding five
thousand dollars, or more upon the contingency named in the
rule.
So far as the establishment of rates and fares is concerned, we
do not see any substantial difference between this agreement and
the one set forth in the
Trans-Missouri case. In that
case, the rates were established by the agreement, and any company
violating the schedule of rates as established under the agreement
was liable to a penalty. A company could withdraw from the
association on giving thirty days' notice, but while it continued,
a member it was bound to charge the rates fixed, under a penalty
for not doing so. In
Page 171 U. S. 563
this case, the companies are bound to charge the rates fixed
upon originally in the agreement or subsequently recommended by the
board of managers, and the failure to observe their recommendations
is deemed a violation of the agreement. The only alternative is the
adoption of a resolution by the board of directors of any company
providing for a change of rates so far as that company is
concerned, and the service of a copy thereof upon the board of
managers, as already stated. This provision for changing rates by
any one company is absent from the other agreement. It is this
provision which is referred to by counsel as most material and
important, and one which constitutes a material and important
distinction between the two agreements. It is said to be designed
solely to prevent secret and illegal competition in rates, while at
the same time providing for and permitting open competition
therein, and that, unless it can be regarded as restraining
competition so as to restrain trade, there is not even an
appearance of restraint of trade in the agreement. It is obvious,
however, that if such deviation from rates by any company from
those agreed upon be tolerated, the principal object of the
association fails of accomplishment, because the purpose of its
formation is the establishment and maintenance of reasonable and
just rates, and a general uniformity therein. If one company is
allowed, while remaining a member of the association, to fix its
own rates and be guided by them, it is plain that, as to that
company, the agreement might as well be rescinded. This result was
never contemplated. In order, therefore, not only to prevent secret
competition, but also to prevent any competition whatever among the
companies parties to the agreements, the provision is therein made
for the prompt action of the board of managers whenever it receives
a copy of the resolution adopted by the board of directors of any
one company for change of the rates as established under the
agreement. By reason of this provision, the board undoubtedly has
authority and power to enforce the uniformity of rates as against
the offending company upon pain of an open, rigorous, and
relentless war of competition against it on the part of the whole
association.
Page 171 U. S. 564
A company desirous of deviating from the rates agreed upon, and
which its associates desire to maintain, is at once confronted with
this probability of a war between itself, on the one side, and the
whole association, on the other, in the course of which rates would
probably drop lower than the company was proposing, and lower than
it would desire or could afford, and such a prospect would be
generally sufficient to prevent the inauguration of the change of
rates and the consequent competition. Thus, the power to commence
such a war on the part of the managers would operated to most
effectually prevent a deviation from rates by any one company
against the desire of the other parties to the agreement.
Competition would be prevented by the fear of the united
competition of the association against the particular member.
Counsel for the association themselves state that the agreement
makes it the duty of the managers, in case the defection should
injuriously affect some particular members more than others, to
endeavor to furnish reasonable protection to such members,
presumably by allowing them to change rates so as to meet such
competition, or by recommending such fierce competition as to
persuade the recalcitrant to fall back into line. By this course,
the competition is open, but nonetheless sufficient on that
account, and the desired and expected result is to be the yielding
of the offending company, induced by the war which might otherwise
be waged against it by the combined force of all the other parties
to the agreement. Under these circumstances, the agreement, taken
as a whole, prevents, and was evidently intended to prevent, not
only secret, but any, competition. The abstract right of a single
company to deviate from the rates becomes immaterial, and its
exercise, to say the least, very inexpedient, in the face of this
power of the managers to enlist the whole association in a war upon
it. This is not all, however, for the agreement further provides
that the managers are to have power to organize such joint freight
and passenger agencies as they may deem desirable, and, if
established, they are to be so arranged as to give proper
representation to each company, and no soliciting or contracting
passenger or freight agency can be maintained by any of the
Page 171 U. S. 565
companies except with the approval of the managers. They are
also charged with the duty of securing to each company party to the
agreement equitable proportions of the competitive traffic covered
by the agreement, so far as can be legally done. The natural,
direct, and necessary effect of all these various provisions of the
agreement is to prevent any competition whatever between the
parties to it for the whole time of its existence. It is probably
as effective in that way as would be a provision in the agreement
prohibiting in terms any competition whatever.
It is also said that the agreement in the first case conferred
upon the association an unlimited power to fix rates in the first
instance, and that the authority was not confined to reasonable
rates, while in the case now before us, the agreement starts out
with rates fixed by each company for itself, and filed with the
Interstate Commerce Commission, and which rates are alleged to be
reasonable. The distinction is unimportant. It was considered in
the other case that the rates actually fixed upon were reasonable,
while the rates fixed upon in this case are also admitted to be
reasonable. By this agreement, the board of managers is, in
substance, and as a result thereof, placed in control of the
business and rates of transportation, and its duty is to see to it
that each company charges the rates agreed upon, and receives its
equitable proportion of the traffic.
The natural and direct effect of the two agreements is the same,
viz., to maintain rates at a higher level than would
otherwise prevail, and the differences between them are not
sufficiently important or material to call for different judgments
in the two cases on any such ground. Indeed, counsel for one of the
railroad companies, on this argument, in speaking of the agreement
in the
Trans-Missouri case, says of it that its terms,
while substantially similar to those of the agreement here, were
less explicit in making it just and reasonable.
Regarding the two agreements as alike in their main and material
features, we are brought to an examination of the question of the
constitutionality of the act, construed as it has
Page 171 U. S. 566
been in the
Trans-Missouri case. It is worthy of remark
that this question was never raised or hinted at upon the argument
of that case, although, if the respondents' present contention be
sound, it would have furnished a conclusive objection to the
enforcement of the act as construed. The fact that not one of the
many astute and able counsel for the transportation companies in
that case raised an objection of so conclusive a character, if well
founded, is strong evidence that the reasons showing the invalidity
of the act as construed do not lie on the surface, and were not
then apparent to those counsel.
The point not being raised, and the decision of that case having
proceeded upon an assumption of the validity of the act under
either construction, it can, of course, constitute no authority
upon this question. Upon the constitutionality of the act, it is
now earnestly contended that contracts in restraint of trade are
not necessarily prejudicial to the security or welfare of society,
and that Congress is without power to prohibit generally all
contracts in restraint to trade, and the effort to do this
invalidates the act in question. It is urged that it is for the
Court to decide whether the mere fact that a contract or
arrangement, whatever its purpose or character, may restrain trade
in some degree renders it injurious or prejudicial to the welfare
or security of society, and if the Court be of opinion that such
welfare or security is not prejudiced by a contract of that kind,
then Congress has no power to prohibit it, and the act must be
declared unconstitutional. It is claimed that the act can be
supported only as an exercise of the police power, and that the
constitutional guaranties furnished by the Fifth Amendment secure
to all persons freedom in the pursuit of their vocations and the
use of their property and in making such contracts or arrangements
as may be necessary therefor. In dwelling upon the far-reaching
nature of the language used in the act as construed in the case
mentioned, counsel contend that the extent to which it limits the
freedom and destroys the property of the individual can scarcely be
exaggerated, and that ordinary contracts and combinations, which
are at the same time most indispensable, have the effect of
somewhat
Page 171 U. S. 567
restraining trade and commerce, although to a very slight
extent, but yet, under the construction adopted, they are
illegal.
As examples of the kinds of contracts which are rendered illegal
by this construction of the act, the learned counsel suggest all
organizations of mechanics engaged in the same business for the
purpose of limiting the number of persons employed in the business,
or of maintaining wages, the formation of a corporation to carry on
any particular line of business by those already engaged therein, a
contract of partnership or of employment between two persons
previously engaged in the same line of business, the appointment by
two producers of the same person to sell their goods on commission,
the purchase by one wholesale merchant of the product of two
producers, the lease or purchase by a farmer, manufacturer, or
merchant of an additional farm, manufactory, or shop, the
withdrawal from business of any farmer, merchant, or manufacturer,
a sale of the goodwill of a business with an agreement not to
destroy its value by engaging in similar business, and a covenant
in a deed restricting the use of real estate. It is added that the
effect of most business contracts or combinations is to restrain
trade in some degree.
This makes quite a formidable list. It will be observed,
however, that no contract of the nature above described is now
before the Court, and there is some embarrassment in assuming to
decide herein just how far the act goes in the direction claimed.
Nevertheless, we might say that the formation of corporations for
business or manufacturing purposes has never, to our knowledge,
been regarded in the nature of a contract in restraint of trade or
commerce. The same may be said of the contract of partnership. It
might also be difficult to show that the appointment by two or more
producers of the same person to sell their goods on commission was
a matter in any degree in restraint of trade.
We are not aware that it has ever been claimed that a lease or
purchase by a farmer, manufacturer, or merchant of an additional
farm, manufactory, or shop, or the withdrawal from business of any
farmer, merchant, or manufacturer, restrained commerce or trade
within any legal definition of that term,
Page 171 U. S. 568
and the sale of a goodwill of a business with an accompanying
agreement not to engage in a similar business was instanced in the
Trans-Missouri case as a contract not within the meaning
of the act, and it was said that such a contract was collateral to
the main contract of sale, and was entered into for the purpose of
enhancing the price at which the vendor sells his business. The
instances cited by counsel have, in our judgment, little or no
bearing upon the question under consideration. In
Hopkins v.
United States, decided at this term,
post,
171 U. S. 578, we
have said that the statute applies only to those contracts whose
direct and immediate effect is a restraint upon interstate
commerce, and that to treat the act as condemning all agreements
under which, as a result, the cost of conducting an interstate
commercial business may be increased would enlarge the application
of the act far beyond the fair meaning of the language used. The
effect upon interstate commerce must not be indirect or incidental
only. An agreement entered into for the purpose of promoting the
legitimate business of an individual or corporation, with no
purpose to thereby affect or restrain interstate commerce, and
which does not directly restrain such commerce, is not, as we
think, covered by the act although the agreement may indirectly and
remotely affect that commerce. We also repeat what is said in the
case above cited, that
"the act of Congress must have a reasonable construction, or
else there would scarcely be an agreement or contract among
business men that could not be said to have, indirectly or
remotely, some bearing upon interstate commerce, and, possibly, to
restrain it."
To suppose, as is assumed by counsel, that the effect of the
decision in the
Trans-Missouri case is to render illegal
most business contracts or combinations, however indispensable and
necessary they may be, because, as they assert, they all restrain
trade in some remote and indirect degree, is to make a most violent
assumption, and one not called for or justified by the decision
mentioned or by any other decision of this Court.
The question really before us is whether Congress, in the
exercise of its right to regulate commerce among the several states
or otherwise, has the power to prohibit, as in restraint
Page 171 U. S. 569
of interstate commerce, a contract or combination between
competing railroad corporations entered into and formed for the
purpose of establishing and maintaining interstate rates and fares
for the transportation of freight and passengers on any of the
railroads parties to the contract or combination, even though the
rates and fares thus established are reasonable. Such an agreement
directly affects, and, of course, is intended to affect, the cost
of transportation of commodities, and commerce consists, among
other things, of the transportation of commodities, and, if such
transportation be between states, it is interstate commerce. The
agreement affects interstate commerce by destroying competition and
by maintaining rates above what competition might produce.
If it did not do that, its existence would be useless, and it
would soon be rescinded or abandoned. Its acknowledged purpose is
to maintain rates, and, if executed, it does so. It must be
remembered, however, that the act does not prohibit any railroad
company from charging reasonable rates. If, in the absence of any
contract or combination among the railroad companies, the rates and
fares would be less than they are under such contract or
combination, that is not by reason of any provision of the act
which itself lowers rates, but only because the railroad companies
would, as it is urged, voluntarily and at once inaugurate a war of
competition among themselves, and thereby themselves reduce their
rates and fares.
Has not Congress, with regard to interstate commerce and in the
course of regulating it, in the case of railroad corporations, the
power to say that no contract or combination shall be legal which
shall restrain trade and commerce by shutting out the operation of
the general law of competition? We think it has.
As counsel for the Traffic Association has truly said, the
ordinary highways on land have generally been established and
maintained by the public. When the matter of the building of
railroads as highways arose, a question was presented whether the
state should itself build them or permit others to do it. The state
did not build them, and, as their building required, among other
things, the appropriation of
Page 171 U. S. 570
land, private individuals could not enforce such appropriation
without a grant from the state.
The building and operation of a railroad thus required a public
franchise. The state would have had no power to grant the right of
appropriation unless the use to which the land was to be put was a
public one. Taking land for railroad purposes is a taking for a
public purpose, and the fact that it is taken for a public purpose
is the sole justification for taking it at all. The business of a
railroad carrier is of a public nature, and in performing it, the
carrier is also performing to a certain extent a function of
government which, as counsel observed, requires them to perform the
service upon equal terms to all. This public service -- that of
transportation of passengers and freight -- is a part of trade and
commerce, and when transported between states, such commerce
becomes what is described as interstate, and comes, to a certain
extent, under the jurisdiction of Congress by virtue of its power
to regulate commerce among the several states.
Where the grantees of this public franchise are competing
railroad companies for interstate commerce, we think Congress is
competent to forbid any agreement or combination among them by
means of which competition is to be smothered.
Although the franchise, when granted by the state, becomes by
the grant the property of the grantee, yet there are some
regulations respecting the exercise of such grants which Congress
may make under its power to regulate commerce among the several
states. This will be conceded by all, the only question being as to
the extent of the power.
We think it extends at least to the prohibition of contracts
relating to interstate commerce which would extinguish all
competition between otherwise competing railroad corporations, and
which would in that way restrain interstate trade or commerce. We
do not think that when the grantees of this public franchise are
competing railroads seeking the business or transportation of men
and goods from one state to another, that ordinary freedom of
contract in the use and management of their property requires the
right to combine
Page 171 U. S. 571
as one consolidated and powerful association for the purpose of
stifling competition among themselves, and of thus keeping their
rates and charges higher than they might otherwise be under the
laws of competition. And this is so even though the rates provided
for in the agreement may, for the time, be not more than are
reasonable. They may easily and at any time be increased. It is the
combination of these large and powerful corporations, covering vast
sections of territory and influencing trade throughout the whole
extent thereof, and acting as one body in all the matters over
which the combination extends, that constitutes the alleged evil,
and in regard to which, so far as the combination operates upon and
restrains interstate commerce, Congress has power to legislate and
to prohibit.
The prohibition of such contracts may, in the judgment of
Congress, be one of the reasonable necessities for the proper
regulation of commerce, and Congress is the judge of such necessity
and propriety unless, in case of a possible gross perversion of the
principle, the courts might be applied to for relief.
The cases cited by the respondents' counsel in regard to the
general constitutional right of the citizen to make contracts
relating to his lawful business are not inconsistent with the
existence of the power of Congress to prohibit contracts of the
nature involved in this case. The power to regulate commerce has no
limitation other than those prescribed in the Constitution. The
power, however, does not carry with it the right to destroy or
impair those limitations and guaranties which are also placed in
the Constitution, or in any of the amendments to that instrument.
Monongahela Navigation Co. v. United States, 148 U.
S. 312,
148 U. S. 336;
Interstate Commerce Commission v. Brimson, 154 U.
S. 447,
154 U. S.
479.
Among these limitations and guaranties, counsel refer to those
which provide that no person shall be deprived of life, liberty, or
property without due process of law, and that private property
shall not be taken for public use without just compensation. The
latter limitation is, we think, plainly irrelevant.
Page 171 U. S. 572
As to the former, it is claimed that the citizen is deprived of
his liberty without due process of law when, by a general statute,
he is arbitrarily deprived of the right to make a contract of the
nature herein involved.
The case of
Allgeyer v. Louisiana, 165 U.
S. 578, is cited as authority for the statement
concerning the right to contract. In speaking of the meaning of the
word "liberty" as used in the Fourteenth Amendment to the
Constitution, it was said in that case to include, among other
things, the liberty of the citizen to pursue any livelihood or
vocation, and for that purpose to enter into all contracts which
might be proper, necessary, and essential to his carrying out those
objects to a successful conclusion.
We do not impugn the correctness of that statement. The citizen
may have the right to make a proper (that is, a lawful) contract,
one which is also essential and necessary for carrying out his
lawful purposes. The question which arises here is whether the
contract is a proper or lawful one, and we have not advanced a step
towards its solution by saying that the citizen is protected by the
Fifth, or any other, Amendment in his right to make proper
contracts to enable him to carry out his lawful purposes. We
presume it will not be contended that the Court meant, in stating
the right of the citizen "to pursue any livelihood or vocation," to
include every means of obtaining a livelihood, whether it was
lawful or otherwise. Precisely how far a legislature can go in
declaring a certain means of obtaining a livelihood unlawful it is
unnecessary here to speak of. It will be conceded it has power to
make some kinds of vocations and some methods of obtaining a
livelihood unlawful, and in regard to those, the citizen would have
no right to contract to carry them on.
Congress may restrain individuals from making contracts under
certain circumstances and upon certain subjects.
Frisbie v.
United States, 157 U. S. 160.
Notwithstanding the general liberty of contract which is
possessed by the citizen under the Constitution, we find that there
are many kinds of contracts which, while not in themselves immoral
or
mala in se, may yet be prohibited by the
Page 171 U. S. 573
legislation of the states, or, in certain cases, by Congress.
The question comes back whether the statute under review is a
legitimate exercise of the power of Congress over interstate
commerce and a valid regulation thereof. The question is, for us,
one of power only, and not of policy. We think the power exists in
Congress, and that the statute is therefore valid.
Finally, we are asked to reconsider the question decided in the
Trans-Missouri case, and to retrace the steps taken
therein, because of the plain error contained in that decision, and
the widespread alarm with which it was received and the serious
consequences which have resulted, or may soon result, from the law
as interpreted in that case.
It is proper to remark that an application for a reconsideration
of a question but lately decided by this Court is usually based
upon a statement that some of the arguments employed on the
original hearing of the question have been overlooked or
misunderstood, or that some controlling authority has been either
misapplied by the Court or passed over without discussion or
notice. While this is not strictly an application for a rehearing
in the same case, yet, in substance, it is the same thing. The
Court is asked to reconsider a question but just decided after a
careful investigation of the matter involved. There have heretofore
been in effect two arguments of precisely the same questions now
before the Court, and the same arguments were addressed to us on
both those occasions. The report of the
Trans-Missouri
case shows a dissenting opinion delivered in that case, and that
the opinion was concurred in by three other members of the
Court.
That opinion, it will be seen, gives with great force and
ability the arguments against the decision which was finally
arrived at by the Court. It was after a full discussion of the
questions involved, and with the knowledge of the views entertained
by the minority as expressed in the dissenting opinion, that the
majority of the Court came to the conclusion it did. Soon after the
decision, a petition for a rehearing of the case was made,
supported by a printed argument in its favor and pressed with an
earnestness and vigor and at a length which were certainly
commensurate with the importance of the case.
Page 171 U. S. 574
This Court, with care and deliberation, and also with a full
appreciation of their importance, again considered the questions
involved in its former decision.
A majority of the Court once more arrived at the conclusion it
had first announced, and accordingly it denied the application. And
now, for the third time, the same arguments are employed and the
Court is again asked to recant its former opinion, and to decide
the same question in direct opposition to the conclusion arrived at
in the
Trans-Missouri case.
The learned counsel, while making the application, frankly
confess that the argument in opposition to the decision in the case
above named has been so fully, so clearly, and so forcibly
presented in the dissenting opinion of MR. JUSTICE WHITE that it is
hardly possible to add to it, nor is it necessary to repeat it.
The fact that there was so close a division of opinion in this
Court when the matter was first under advisement, together with the
different views taken by some of the judges of the lower courts,
led us to the most careful and scrutinizing examination of the
arguments advanced by both sides, and it was after such an
examination that the majority of the Court came to the conclusion
it did.
It is not now alleged that the Court on the former occasion
overlooked any argument for the respondents or misapplied any
controlling authority. It is simply insisted that the Court,
notwithstanding the arguments for an opposite view, arrived at an
erroneous result which, for reasons already stated, ought to be
reconsidered and reversed.
As we have twice already deliberately and earnestly considered
the same arguments which are now for a third time pressed upon our
attention, it could hardly be expected that our opinion should now
change from that already expressed.
While an erroneous decision might be in some cases properly
reconsidered and overruled, yet it is clear that the first
necessity is to convince the Court that the decision was erroneous.
It is scarcely to be assumed that such a result could be
Page 171 U. S. 575
secured by the presentation for a third time of the same
arguments which had twice before been unsuccessfully urged upon the
attention of the Court.
We have listened to them now because the eminence of the counsel
engaged, their earnestness and zeal, their evident belief in the
correctness of their position, and, most important of all, the very
grave nature of the questions argued, called upon the Court to
again give to those arguments strict and respectful attention. It
is not matter for surprise that we still are unable to see the
error alleged to exist in our former decision or to change our
opinion regarding the questions therein involved.
Upon the point that the agreement is not in fact one in
restraint of trade, even though it did prevent competition, it must
be admitted that the former argument has now been much enlarged and
amplified, and a general and most masterly review of that question
has been presented by counsel for the respondents. That this
agreement does in fact prevent competition, and that it most have
been so intended, we have already attempted to show. Whether
stifling competition tends directly to restrain commerce in the
case of naturally competing railroads is a question upon which
counsel have argued with very great ability. They acknowledge that
this agreement purports to restrain competition, although, they
say, in a very slight degree, and on a single point. They admit
that, if competition and commerce were identical, being but
different names for the same thing, then, in assuming to restrain
competition even so far, it would be assuming in a corresponding
degree to restrain commerce. Counsel then add (and therein we
entirely agree with them) that no such identity can be pretended,
because it is plain that commerce can and does take place on a
large scale, and in numerous forms, without competition. The
material considerations therefore turn upon the effects of
competition upon the business of railroads -- whether they are
favorable to the commerce in which the roads are engaged, or
unfavorable, and in restraint of that commerce. Upon that question,
it is contended that agreements between railroad companies of
the
Page 171 U. S. 576
nature of that now before us are promotive, instead of in
restraint, of trade.
This conclusion is reached by counsel after an examination of
the peculiar nature of railroad property and the alleged baneful
effects of competition upon it and also upon the public. It is
stated that the only resort open to railroads to save themselves
from the effects of a ruinous competition is that of agreements
among themselves to check and control it. A ruinous competition is,
as they say, apt to be carried on until the weakest of the
combatants goes to destruction. After that, the survivor, being
relieved from competition, proceeds to raise its prices as high as
the business will bear. Commerce, it is said, thus finally becomes
restrained by the effects of competition, while at the same time
otherwise valuable railroad property is thereby destroyed or
greatly reduced in value. There can be no doubt that the general
tendency of competition among competing railroads is towards lower
rates for transportation, and the result of lower rates is
generally a greater demand for the articles so transported, and
this greater demand can only be gratified by a larger supply, the
furnishing of which increases commerce. This is the first and
direct result of competition among railroad carriers.
In the absence of any agreement restraining competition, this
result, it is argued, is neutralized, and the opposite one finally
reached, by reason of the peculiar nature of railroad property,
which must be operated, and the capital invested in which cannot be
withdrawn, and the railroad managers are therefore, as is claimed,
compelled to not only compete among themselves for business but
also to carry on the war of competition until it shall terminate in
the utter destruction or the buying up of the weaker roads, after
which the survivor will raise the rates as high as is possible.
Thus the indirect but final effect of competition is claimed to be
the raising of rates and the consequent restraint of trade, and it
is urged that this result is only to be prevented by such an
agreement as we have here. In that way alone it is said that
competition is overcome and general uniformity and reasonableness
of rates securely established.
Page 171 U. S. 577
The natural, direct, and immediate effect of competition is,
however, to lower rates, and to thereby increase the demand for
commodities, the supplying of which increases commerce, and an
agreement whose first and direct effect is to prevent this play of
competition restrains, instead of promoting, trade and commerce.
Whether, in the absence of an agreement as to rates, the
consequences described by counsel will in fact follow as a result
of competition is matter of very great uncertainty, depending upon
many contingencies, and in large degree upon the voluntary action
of the managers of the several roads. Railroad companies may, and
often do, continue in existence and engage in their lawful traffic
at some profit, although they are competing railroads, and are not
acting under any agreement or combination with their competitors
upon the subject of rates. It appears from the brief of counsel in
this case that the agreement in question does not embrace all of
the lines or systems engaged in the business of railroad
transportation between Chicago and the Atlantic coast. It cannot be
said that destructive competition, or, in other words, war to the
death, is bound to result unless an agreement or combination to
avoid it is entered into between otherwise competing roads.
It is not only possible, but probable, that good sense and
integrity of purpose would prevail among the managers, and, while
making no agreement and entering into no combination by which the
whole railroad interest as herein represented should act as one
combined and consolidated body, the managers of each road might yet
make such reasonable charges for the business done by it as the
facts might justify. An agreement of the nature of this one, which
directly and effectually stifles competition, must be regarded
under the statute as one in restraint of trade, notwithstanding
there are possibilities that a restraint of trade may also follow
competition that may be indulged in until the weaker roads are
completely destroyed and the survivor thereafter raises rates and
maintains them.
Coming to the conclusion we do in regard to the various
questions herein discussed, we think it unnecessary to
Page 171 U. S. 578
further allude to the other reasons which have been advanced for
a reconsideration of the decision in the
Trans-Missouri
case.
The judgments of the Circuit Court of the United States for
the Southern District of New York and of the Circuit Court of
Appeals for the Second Circuit are reversed, and the case remanded
to the circuit court with directions to take such further
proceedings therein as may be in conformity with this
opinion.
MR. JUSTICE GRAY, MR. JUSTICE SHIRAS, and MR. JUSTICE WHITE
dissented. MR. JUSTICE McKENNA took no part in the decision of the
case.