The term "import," as used in that clause of the Constitution
which says, that "no state shall levy any imposts or duties on
imports or exports," does not refer to articles imported from one
state into another, but only to articles imported from foreign
countries into the United States. Hence, a uniform tax imposed by a
state on all sales made in it, whether they be made by a citizen of
it or a citizen of some other state, and whether the goods sold are
the produce of that state enacting the law or of some other state,
is valid.
The Constitution thus ordains:
"Congress shall have power to regulate commerce with foreign
nations and among the several states."
"No state shall levy any imposts or duties on
imports
or exports."
"The citizens of each state shall be entitled to all the
immunities and privileges of citizens of the several states."
With these declarations of the Constitution in force, the City
of Mobile, Alabama, in accordance with a provision in its charter,
authorized the collection of a tax for municipal purposes on real
and personal estate,
sales at auction, and sales of
merchandise, capital employed in business and income within the
city. This ordinance being on the city statute book Woodruff and
others, auctioneers, received, in the course of their business for
themselves, or as consignees and
Page 75 U. S. 124
agents for others, large amounts of goods and merchandise,
the product of states other than Alabama, and sold the same in
Mobile to purchasers in the original and unbroken packages.
Thereupon, the tax collector for the city, demanded the tax levied
by the ordinance. Woodruff refused to pay the tax, asserting that
it was repugnant to the above-quoted provisions of the
Constitution. The question coming finally, on a case stated, into
the supreme court of the state, where the first two of the
above-quoted provisions of the Constitution were relied on by the
auctioneers as a bar to the suit, the said court decided in favor
of the tax. And the question was now here for review.
Page 75 U. S. 130
MR. JUSTICE MILLER delivered the opinion of the Court.
The case was heard in the courts of the State of Alabama upon an
agreed statement of facts, and that statement fully raises the
question whether merchandise brought from other states and sold,
under the circumstances stated, comes within the prohibition of the
federal Constitution, that no state shall, without the consent of
Congress, levy any imposts or duties on imports or exports. And it
is claimed that it also brings the case within the principles laid
down by this Court in
Brown v. Maryland. [
Footnote 1]
That decision has been recognized for over forty years as
governing the action of this Court in the same class of cases, and
its reasoning has been often cited and received with approbation in
others to which it was applicable. We do not now propose to
question its authority or to depart from its principles.
The tax of the State of Maryland, which was the subject of
controversy in that case, was limited by its terms to importers of
foreign articles or commodities, and the proposition that we are
now to consider is whether the provision of
Page 75 U. S. 131
the Constitution to which we have referred extends, in its true
meaning and intent, to articles brought from one state of the Union
into another.
The subject of the relative rights and powers of the federal and
state governments in regard to taxation, always delicate, has
acquired an importance by reason of the increased public burdens
growing out of the recent war, which demands of all who may be
called in the discharge of public duty to decide upon any of its
various phases, that it shall be done with great care and
deliberation. Happily for us, much the larger share of these
responsibilities rests with the legislative departments of the
state and federal governments. But when, under the pressure of a
taxation necessarily heavy, and in many cases new in its character,
the parties affected by it resort to the courts to ascertain
whether their individual rights have been infringed by legislation,
and assert rights supposed to be guaranteed by the federal
Constitution, they, in every such case properly brought before us,
devolve upon this Court an obligation to decide the question raised
from which there is no escape.
The words impost, imports, and exports are frequently used in
the Constitution. They have a necessary correlation, and when we
have a clear idea of what either word means in any particular
connection in which it may be found, we have one of the most
satisfactory tests of its definition in other parts of the same
instrument.
In the case of
Brown v. Maryland, the word imports, as
used in the clause now under consideration, is defined, both on the
authority of the lexicons and of usage, to be articles brought into
the country; and impost is there said to be a duty, custom, or tax
levied on articles brought into the country. In the ordinary use of
these terms at this day, no one would, for a moment, think of them
as having relation to any other articles than those brought from a
country foreign to the United States, and at the time the case of
Brown v. Maryland was decided -- namely, in 1827 -- it is
reasonable to suppose that the general usage was the same, and that
in defining imports as articles brought into the country,
Page 75 U. S. 132
the Chief Justice used the word country as a synonym for United
States.
But the word is susceptible of being applied to articles
introduced from one state into another, and we must inquire if it
was so used by the framers of the Constitution.
Leaving, then, for a moment, the clause of the Constitution
under consideration, we find the first use of any of these
correlative terms in that clause of the eighth section of the first
article, which begins the enumeration of the powers confided to
Congress.
"The Congress shall have power to levy and collect taxes,
duties, imposts, and excises, . . . but all duties, imposts, and
excises shall be uniform throughout the United States."
Is the word impost, here used, intended to confer upon Congress
a distinct power to levy a tax upon all goods or merchandise
carried from one state into another? Or is the power limited to
duties on foreign imports? If the former be intended, then the
power conferred is curiously rendered nugatory by the subsequent
clause of the ninth section, which declares that no tax shall be
laid on articles exported from any state, for no article can be
imported from one state into another which is not, at the same
time, exported from the former. But if we give to the word imposts,
as used in the first-mentioned clause, the definition of Chief
Justice Marshall, and to the word export the corresponding idea of
something carried out of the United States, we have, in the power
to lay duties on imports from abroad, and the prohibition to lay
such duties on exports to other countries, the power and its
limitations concerning imposts.
It is also to be remembered that the Convention was here giving
the right to lay taxes by national authority in connection with
paying the debts and providing for the common defense and the
general welfare, and it is a reasonable inference that they had in
view, in the use of the word imports, those articles which, being
introduced from other nations and diffused generally over the
country for consumption, would contribute, in a common and general
way, to the support
Page 75 U. S. 133
of the national government. If internal taxation should become
necessary, it was provided for by the terms taxes and excises.
There are two provisions of the clause under which exemption
from state taxation is claimed in this case, which are not without
influence on that prohibition, namely that any state may, with the
assent of Congress, lay a tax on imports, and that the net produce
of such tax shall be for the benefit of the Treasury of the United
States. The framers of the Constitution, claiming for the general
government, as they did, all the duties
on foreign goods
imported into the country, might well permit a state that wished to
tax more heavily than Congress did, foreign liquors, tobacco, or
other articles injurious to the community, or which interfered with
their domestic policy, to do so, provided such tax met the
approbation of Congress, and was paid into the federal Treasury.
But that it was intended to permit such a tax to be imposed by such
authority on the products of neighboring states for the use of the
federal government, and that Congress, under this temptation, was
to arbitrate between the state which proposed to levy the tax and
those which opposed it, seems altogether improbable.
Yet this must be the construction of the clause in question if
it has any reference to goods imported from one state into
another.
If we turn for a moment from the consideration of the language
of the Constitution to the history of its formation and adoption,
we shall find additional reason to conclude that the words imports
and imposts were used with exclusive reference to articles imported
from foreign countries.
Section three, article six, of the Confederation provided that
no state should lay imposts or duties which might interfere with
any stipulation in treaties entered into by the United States; and
section one, article nine, that no treaty of commerce should be
made whereby the legislative power of the respective states should
be restrained from imposing such imposts and duties on foreigners
as their own people were subjected to, or from prohibiting the
exportation or
Page 75 U. S. 134
importation of any species of goods or commodities whatsoever.
In these two articles of the Confederation, the words "imports,
exports," and "imposts" are used with exclusive reference to
foreign trade, because they have regard only to the treatymaking
power of the federation.
As soon as peace was restored by the success of the Revolution,
and commerce began to revive, it became obvious that the most
eligible mode of raising revenue for the support of the general
government and the payment of its debts was by duties on foreign
merchandise imported into the country. The Congress accordingly
recommended the states to levy a duty of five percent on all such
imports, for the use of the Confederation. To this Rhode Island,
which, at that time, was one of the largest importing states,
objected, and we have a full report of the remonstrance addressed
by a committee of Congress to that state on that subject. [
Footnote 2] And the discussions of the
Congress of that day, as imperfectly as they have been preserved,
are full of the subject of the injustice done by the states who had
good seaports, by duties levied in those ports on foreign goods
designed for states who had no such ports.
In this state of public feeling in this matter, the
Constitutional Convention assembled.
Its very first grant of power to the new government about to be
established, was to lay and collect imposts or duties on foreign
goods imported into the country, and among its restraints upon the
states was the corresponding one that they should lay no duties on
imports or exports. It seems, however, from Mr. Madison's account
of the debates, that while the necessity of vesting in Congress the
power to levy duties on foreign goods was generally conceded, the
right of the states to do so likewise was not given up without
discussion, and was finally yielded with the qualification to which
we have already referred, that the states might lay such duties
with the assent of Congress. Mr. Madison moved that the words "nor
lay imposts or duties on imports" be placed in
Page 75 U. S. 135
that class of prohibitions which were absolute, instead of those
which were dependent on the consent of Congress. His reason was
that the states interested in this power (meaning those who had
good seaports) by which they could tax the imports of their
neighbors passing through their markets were a majority, and could
gain the consent of Congress to the injury of New Jersey, North
Carolina, and other non-importing states. But his motion failed.
[
Footnote 3] In the Convention
of Virginia, called to adopt the Constitution, that distinguished
expounder and defender of the instrument, so largely the work of
his own hand, argued in support of the authority to lay direct
taxes that without this power, a disproportion of burden would be
imposed on the Southern states because, having fewer manufactures,
they would consume more imports and pay more of the imposts.
[
Footnote 4] So, in defending
the clause of the Constitution now under our consideration, he
says:
"Some states export the produce of other states. Virginia
exports the produce of North Carolina, Pennsylvania those of New
Jersey and Delaware, and Rhode Island those of Connecticut and
Massachusetts. The exporting states wished to retain the power of
laying duties on exports to enable them to pay expenses incurred.
The states whose produce was exported by other states were
extremely jealous lest a contribution should be raised of them by
the exporting states by laying heavy duties on their own
commodities. If this clause be fully considered, it will be found
to be more consistent with justice and equity than any other
practicable mode, for if the states had the exclusive imposition of
duties on exports, they might raise a heavy contribution of the
other states for their own exclusive emoluments. [
Footnote 5]"
Similar observation from the same source are found in the 42d
number of the Federalist, but with more direct reference to the
power to regulate commerce.
Governor Ellsworth, in opening the debate of the Connecticut
Convention on the adoption of the Constitution, says:
"Our being tributary to our sister states is in consequence
of
Page 75 U. S. 136
the want of a federal system. The State of New York raises
�60,000 or �80,000 in a year by impost. Connecticut consumes about
one-third of the goods upon which this impost is laid, and
consequently pays one-third of this sum to New York. If we import
by the medium of Massachusetts, she has an impost, and to her we
pay tribute. [
Footnote 6]"
A few days later he says: "I find, on calculation, that a
general impost of five percent would raise a sum of �245,000," and
adds:
"it is a strong argument in favor of an impost that the
collection of it will interfere less with the internal police of
the states than any other species of taxation. It does not fill the
country with revenue officers, but is confined to the seacoast, and
is chiefly a water operation. . . . If we do not give it to
Congress, the individual states will have it. [
Footnote 7]"
It is not too much to say that, so far as our research has
extended, neither the word "export, import," or "impost" is to be
found in the discussions on this subject, as they have come down to
us from that time, in reference to any other than foreign commerce,
without some special form of words to show that foreign commerce is
not meant. The only allusion to imposts in the Articles of
Confederation is clearly limited to duties on goods imported from
foreign states. Wherever we find the grievance to be remedied by
this provision of the Constitution alluded to, the duty levied by
the states on foreign importations is alone mentioned, and the
advantages to accrue to Congress from the power confided to it, and
withheld from the states, is always mentioned with exclusive
reference to foreign trade.
Whether we look, then, to the terms of the clause of the
Constitution in question, or to its relation to the other parts of
that instrument, or to the history of its formation and adoption,
or to the comments of the eminent men who took part in those
transactions, we are forced to the conclusion that no intention
existed to prohibit, by
this clause, the right of one
state to tax articles brought into it from another. If we examine
for a moment the results of an opposite doctrine,
Page 75 U. S. 137
we shall be well satisfied with the wisdom of the Constitution
as thus construed.
The merchant of Chicago who buys his goods in New York and sells
at wholesale in the original packages, may have his millions
employed in trade for half a lifetime and escape all state, county,
and city taxes; for all that he is worth is invested in goods which
he claims to be protected as imports from New York. Neither the
state nor the city which protects his life and property can make
him contribute a dollar to support its government, improve its
throughfares or educate its children. The merchant in a town in
Massachusetts, who deals only in wholesale, if he purchase his
goods in New York, is exempt from taxation. If his neighbor
purchase in Boston, he must pay all the taxes which Massachusetts
levies with equal justice on the property of all its citizens.
These cases are merely mentioned as illustrations. But it is
obvious that if articles brought from one state into another are
exempt from taxation, even under the limited circumstances laid
down in the case of
Brown v. Maryland, the grossest
injustice must prevail, and equality of public burdens in all our
large cities is impossible.
It is said, however, that as a Court we are bound by our former
decisions to a contrary doctrine, and we are referred to the cases
of
Almy v. State of California and
Brown v.
Maryland, in support of the assertion.
The case first mentioned arose under a statute of California
which imposed a stamp tax on bills of lading for the transportation
of gold and silver from any point within the state to any point
without the state.
The master of the ship
Rattler was fined for violating
this law by refusing to affix a stamp to a bill of lading for gold
shipped on board his vessel from San Francisco to New York. It
seems to have escaped the attention of counsel on both sides, and
of the Chief Justice who delivered the opinion, that the case was
one of interstate commerce. No distinction of the kind is taken by
counsel, none alluded to by the Court except in the incidental
statement of the
termini of the voyage. In the language of
the Court, citing
Brown v. Maryland
Page 75 U. S. 138
as governing the case, the statute of Maryland is described as a
tax on foreign articles and commodities. The only question
discussed by the Court is whether the bill of lading was
so intimately connected with the articles of export described in it
that a tax on it was a tax on the articles exported. And in arguing
this proposition, the Chief Justice says that
"a bill of lading, or some equivalent instrument of writing, is
invariably associated with every cargo of merchandise exported to
a foreign country, and consequently a duty upon that is,
in substance and effect, a duty on the article exported."
It is impossible to examine the opinion without perceiving that
the mind of the writer was exclusively directed to foreign
commerce, and there is no reason to suppose that the question which
we have discussed was in his thought. We take it to be a sound
principle, that no proposition of law can be said to be overruled
by a court, which was not in the mind of the court when the
decision was made. [
Footnote
8]
The case, however, was well decided on the ground taken by Mr.
Blair, counsel for defendant, namely that such a tax was a
regulation of commerce, a tax imposed upon the transportation of
goods from one state to another, over the high seas, in conflict
with that freedom of transit of goods and persons between one state
and another, which is within the rule laid down in
Crandall v.
Nevada, [
Footnote 9] and
with the authority of Congress to regulate commerce among the
states. We do not regard it, therefore, as opposing the views which
we have announced in this case.
The case of
Brown v. Maryland, as we have already said,
arose out of a statute of that state taxing by way of
discrimination importers who sold, by wholesale, foreign goods.
Chief Justice Marshall, in delivering the opinion of the Court,
distinctly bases the invalidity of the statutes (1) on the clause
of the Constitution which forbids a state to levy imposts or duties
on imports, and (2) that which confers on Congress the power to
regulate commerce with foreign nations, among the states and with
the Indian tribes.
Page 75 U. S. 139
The casual remark, therefore, made in the close of the opinion,
"that we suppose the principles laid down in this case to apply
equally to importations from a sister state," can only be received
as an intimation of what they might decide if the case ever came
before them, for no such case was then to be decided. It is not,
therefore, a judicial decision of the question, even if the remark
was intended to apply to the first of the grounds on which that
decision was placed.
But the opinion in that case discusses, as we have said, under
two distinct heads, the two clauses of the Constitution which he
supposed to be violated by the Maryland statute, and the remark
above quoted follows immediately the discussion of the second
proposition, or the applicability of the commerce clause to that
case.
If the Court then meant to say that a tax levied on goods from a
sister state which was not levied on goods of a similar character
produced within the state, would be in conflict with the clause of
the Constitution giving Congress the right "to regulate commerce
among the states," as much as the tax on foreign goods, then under
consideration, was in conflict with the authority "to regulate
commerce with foreign nations," we agree to the proposition.
It may not be inappropriate here to refer to the License Cases.
[
Footnote 10]
The separate and diverse opinions delivered by the judges on
that occasion leave it very doubtful if any material proposition
was decided, though the precise point we have here argued was
before the court and seemed to require solution. But no one can
read the opinions which were delivered without perceiving that none
of them held that goods imported from one state into another are
within the prohibition to the states to levy taxes on imports, and
the language of the Chief Justice and Judge McLean leave no doubt
that their views are adverse to the proposition.
We are satisfied that the question, as a distinct
proposition
Page 75 U. S. 140
necessary to be decided, is before the court now for the first
time.
But, we may be asked, is there no limit to the power of the
states to tax the produce of their sister states brought within
their borders? And can they so tax them as to drive them out or
altogether prevent their introduction or their transit over their
territory?
The case before us is a simple tax on sales of merchandise,
imposed alike upon all sales made in Mobile, whether the sales be
made by a citizen of Alabama or of another state, and whether the
goods sold are the produce of that state or some other. There is no
attempt to discriminate injuriously against the products of other
states or the rights of their citizens, and the case is not,
therefore, an attempt to fetter commerce among the states or to
deprive the citizens of other states of any privilege or immunity
possessed by citizens of Alabama. But a law having such operation
would, in our opinion, be an infringement of the provisions of the
Constitution which relate to those subjects, and therefore void.
There is also, in addition to the restraints which those provisions
impose by their own force on the states, the unquestioned power of
Congress, under the authority to regulate commerce among the
states, to interpose, by the exercise of this power, in such a
manner as to prevent the states from any oppressive interference
with the free interchange of commodities by the citizens of one
state with those of another.
Judgment affirmed.
[
Footnote 1]
25 U. S. 12 Wheat.
419.
[
Footnote 2]
1 Elliot's Debates 131-133.
[
Footnote 3]
5 Madison Papers 486.
[
Footnote 4]
3 Elliot's Debates 248.
[
Footnote 5]
2
id. 443-444.
[
Footnote 6]
2 Elliott's Debates 192.
[
Footnote 7]
2
id. 196.
[
Footnote 8]
The Victory, 6
Wall. 382.
[
Footnote 9]
73 U. S. 6 Wall.
35.
[
Footnote 10]
46 U. S. 5 How.
504.
MR. JUSTICE NELSON, dissenting.
I am unable to agree to the judgment of the Court in this case.
The naked question is whether a state can tax the sale of an
article, the product of a sister state, in the original package,
when imported into the former for a market, under the Constitution
of the United States? If she can, then no security or protection
exists in this government against obstructions and interruptions of
commerce among the states, and one of the principal grievances that
led to
Page 75 U. S. 141
the Convention of 1787, and to the adoption of the federal
Constitution, has failed to be remedied by that instrument. And
hereafter (for this is the first time since its adoption that the
clause in question has received the interpretation now given to
it), this interstate commerce is necessarily left to the regulation
of the legislatures of the different states. We think we hazard
nothing in saying that heretofore the prevailing opinion of jurists
and statesmen of this country has been that this commerce was
protected by the clause -- the subject of discussion -- namely:
"No state shall, without the consent of Congress, lay any
imposts or duties
on imports or exports, except what may
be absolutely necessary for executing its inspection laws."
An attempt was made by the State of Maryland, in 1821, to lay a
tax upon foreign imports, but which was pronounced unconstitutional
by this Court after an elaborate argument of counsel and a very
full and carefully considered opinion of Chief Justice Marshall,
concurred in by the whole court, and he closed it by saying: "It
may be proper to add, that we suppose the principles laid down in
this case to apply equally to importations from a sister state." A
tax was attempted by the state of California, in 1857, upon an
export from that state to the state of New York, but was pronounced
unconstitutional by this Court, the opinion delivered by the late
Chief Justice. He observed:
"If the tax was laid on the gold or silver exported (it was in
form a stamp tax on the bill of lading), everyone would see that it
was repugnant to the Constitution of the United States, which, in
express terms, declares that 'no state shall, without the consent
of Congress, lay any imposts or duties on imports or exports,
except what may be absolutely necessary for executing its
inspection laws.'"
Again he observes:
"In the case now before the Court, the intention to tax the
export of gold and silver, in the form of a tax on the bill of
lading, is too plain to be misunderstood."
It is now said, however, that this clause relates only to
foreign commerce, and is no prohibition against taxation upon
commerce among the states; and, as we have already
Page 75 U. S. 142
said, if this be so, it is left to the unrestricted imposition
by a state of duties, or tax, upon all articles imported into the
same from sister states. In looking at this clause, it will be seen
that there is nothing in its terms, or connection, that affords the
slightest indication that it was intended to be confined to the
prohibition of a tax upon foreign imports. Surely, if this had been
intended, it must have occurred to the distinguished members of the
Convention, it would be quite important to say so that the
prohibition might not be misunderstood, especially when we take
into consideration the eminent men who not only discussed and
settled the terms and meaning of the clause, but to whom the whole
instrument was committed for special and final revision. It would
have been easy to have made the clause clear by affixing the word
"foreign" before the word "imports." Then the clause would read
"foreign imports," that now is affixed, by construction, a pretty
liberal one of the fundamental charter of the government.
The same clause also provides: "No state shall, without the
consent of Congress, lay any duty of tonnage," &c. Does this
also relate to tonnage employed in foreign trade? If so, then it
will be competent hereafter for the states to levy a tax upon the
tonnage of vessels employed in carrying on commerce among the
states, including the tonnage employed in the coasting trade. But
independently of the terms of the clause and the connection in
which it is found, why should not the prohibition extend to
imports and exports of commerce among the states? At the
time of the Convention and formation of the Constitution, the
states were independent and foreign to each other, except as bound
together by the feeble "league of friendship" in the Articles of
Confederation in 1777, the second article of which provided,
that
"each state retains its sovereignty, freedom, and independence,
and every power, jurisdiction, and right which is not by this
Confederation expressly delegated to the United States in Congress
assembled."
And the only specified restraint then submitted to in respect to
their commercial relations is found in the third section of the
article, namely:
Page 75 U. S. 143
"No state shall lay any imposts or duties which may interfere
with any stipulations in treaties entered into by the United
States, in Congress assembled, with any king, prince, or state, in
pursuance of any treaties already proposed by Congress to the
courts of France and Spain."
There is another provision relating to commerce among the states
in the fourth article, to which we shall hereafter refer.
Now, as is seen, at the time the delegates assembled in 1787 to
form the Constitution, they represented states that for all the
substantial purposes of government were foreign and independent,
and especially so in respect to all commercial relations among them
or with foreign countries. Looking at this condition of things, and
to the delegates in the Convention representing such
constituencies, is it reasonable or consistent with proper rules of
construction to suppose, in the absence of any indication from the
words of this clause prohibiting the tax on imports or exports, the
members used the terms with exclusive reference to foreign
countries -- that is, countries foreign to the states -- and not in
reference to the states themselves? We again ask, if this
distinction was intended, why was not the clause so framed as to
indicate it on its face, and not left to mere conjecture and
speculation?
Again, at the time the Convention was assembled, as it has been
ever since and now is, the commerce among the states was manyfold
greater and vastly more productive of wealth, independence, and
happiness of the people then all the foreign commerce of the
country. Its magnitude and importance therefore invited protection
and encouragement far beyond that of foreign commerce, and could
not and did not escape the particular care and attention of the
members of the Convention. Besides the clause in question, it is
provided in the ninth section that
"No tax or duty shall be laid on articles exported from any
state. No preference shall be given by any regulation of commerce
or revenue to the ports of one state over those of another, nor
shall vessels bound to or from one state be obliged to enter,
clear, or pay duties in another."
And in the clause conferring
Page 75 U. S. 144
upon the federal Government the general power over commerce, it
is given in terms "to regulate commerce with foreign nations and
among the several states." The two are placed upon the same footing
without any discrimination. The power is equally broad and absolute
over the one as over the other. No distinction is made between
foreign and interstate commerce, and why should the specific
prohibitions to be found in the Constitution in relation to this
subject receive a different interpretation in the absence of any
words indicating any such distinction? Take as an example the
prohibition upon the federal Government: "No tax or duty shall be
laid on articles exported from any state." Is this clause also to
receive the narrow and strained construction given to the one in
question, and be applied only to exports to a foreign country? If
so, then Congress may tax all exports from one state to another. If
the terms in the clause before us do not embrace interstate
commerce, then the above clause does not. As was said by the Chief
Justice in
Brown v. Maryland, [
Footnote 2/1] "There is some diversity in the language,
but none is perceivable in the act which is prohibited." Now this
is a prohibition or limitation upon the general commercial power
conferred upon Congress, but if it only applies to foreign
commerce, it loses more than half its efficiency as heretofore
supposed to belong to it.
We will now recur to a provision in the Articles of
Confederation to which we have heretofore alluded. It is the fourth
section:
"The better to secure and perpetuate mutual friendship and
intercourse among the people of the different states in this Union,
the free inhabitants of each of these states shall be entitled to
all the privileges and immunities of free citizens of the several
states, and the people of each state shall have free ingress and
regress to and from any other state and
shall enjoy therein all
the privileges of trade and commerce, subject to the same
restrictions as the inhabitants thereof, respectively."
It will be seen the last clause of this article contains the
doctrine of my brethren in the case before us.
Page 75 U. S. 145
The people of one state have the right of egress and regress to
and from any other for the purposes of trade and commerce, and the
articles may be taxed by the state into which they are carried; but
there must be no discrimination. We have gone back to the Articles
of Confederation, and have incorporated into the Constitution, by
construction, a provision which the framers of that instrument had
rejected as wholly inadequate for the protection of interstate
commerce. Instead, therefore, of adopting this article into that
instrument, they adopted a more complete and thorough security to
the enjoyment of the privileges of this commerce -- "no state
shall, without the consent of the Congress, lay any imposts or
duties on imports or exports."
Why this change? If there had been no diversity of soil or
climate in the states of the Confederacy or in the mineral riches
of the earth, any commercial regulation among them would have been
of little importance. Foreign trade and commerce would have been
their only dependence for a market of their surplus productions.
The products would, as a general rule, have been common among all
the states. But the fact was otherwise. From the diversity of soil
and climate, the Middle and Eastern states were mostly
grain-growing states, and their surplus products were flour, pork,
beef, butter, and cheese, with a modicum of the manufacture of
woolens.
The Southern states were cotton, tobacco, and rice-growing
states. It was the exchange of these commodities that constituted
the bulk of interstate commerce.
Virginia and North Carolina looked to the Middle and Eastern
states for their products in exchange for tobacco, tar, rosin, and
turpentine; South Carolina and Georgia for their cotton and rice.
Now the provision in the Articles of Confederation securing egress
and regress for the purposes of trade and commerce furnished no
protection to either state. New York and Pennsylvania could lay a
tax upon all sales of cotton, tobacco, or rice within these states,
which would be a tax without any discrimination, and yet it would
be in fact, in its operation and effect, exclusively upon these
Page 75 U. S. 146
Southern products. So in respect to the wheat, flour, pork,
beef, butter, and cheese, when shipped to these Southern states.
Each state not producing the article sold, the general tax would
not affect their people. We have no doubt the case before us falls
within this category.
Alabama is a cotton-growing state, and depends upon the Northern
states bordering on the Mississippi and Ohio Rivers for most of her
corn, wheat, and flour. She cannot be, therefore, a state largely
engaged in the manufacture of whiskey. The tax, so far as regards
her own people, is probably nearly nominal. We see from the above
view why this nondiscriminating article in the Confederation was
not incorporated into the Constitution. It was entirely worthless
as a protection against the taxation of the interstate
commerce.
The same results will follow applying the principle to commerce
among the states as it exists at the present time. The State of
Pennsylvania supplies New York with the article of coal from her
mines which is consumed in that state. The trade is very great, and
is increasing every year as the facilities for the conveyance of
the article by railroads into the interior of the state are
multiplied. According to the judgment of the court in the present
case, the State of New York may tax these sales if she makes no
discrimination. She may therefore pass a law imposing a tax on all
sales of coal in the state, as the State of Alabama has done in
respect to sales of whiskey. Such a law may be passed and enforced
without imposing any burden upon her own people, as there is no
coal of any comparative value in the state but what is brought into
it from abroad. So, in turn, Pennsylvania can tax the salt and
plaster of New York carried into that state with like impunity to
her people. Massachusetts may tax the grain and flour of the West
carried into the state by a like law, as she does not raise a
sufficient supply for home consumption, and a general tax upon all
sales would not harm her people. In like manner, she can tax the
cotton and rice of the Southern states, and sugar of Louisiana, and
those in turn can tax her cotton, woolen manufacture, and shoes
carried into those states.
Page 75 U. S. 147
The lumber of Wisconsin can be taxed at Chicago, its principal
mart, by a general law of Illinois without any serious prejudice to
the interests of the people of that state. The gold dust and gold
and silver bars of California carried to New York can be taxed upon
a like principle without prejudice to her people.
We have extended this discussion much further than we had
intended, and will close it by referring to the views expressed by
Judge Story on this clause of the Constitution. After stating the
history of the clause in the Convention, he observes in his
valuable Commentaries on the Constitution: [
Footnote 2/2]
"So it seems that a struggle for state powers was constantly
maintained with zeal and pertinacity throughout the whole
discussion. If there is wisdom and sound policy in restraining the
United States (referring to the prohibition upon it in respect to
articles exported from the state) from exercising the power of
taxation unequally in the states, there is, he observes, at least
equal wisdom and policy in restraining the states themselves from
the exercise of the same power injuriously to the interests of each
other. A petty warfare of regulation is thus prevented which would
rouse resentments and create dissensions to the ruin of the amity
of the states. The power to enforce their inspection laws is still
retained, subject to the revision and control of Congress. So that
sufficient provision is made for the convenient arrangement of the
domestic and internal trade whenever it is not injurious to the
general interests."
Judge Story entertained no doubt but that this clause applied to
the domestic and internal commerce of the states as well as to the
foreign. We have therefore the deliberate opinions of Marshall and
Taney and Story concurring in this construction -- great names in
this and in every country where jurisprudence is cultivated as a
science, and especially eminent at home as expounders of our
constitutional law.
Page 75 U. S. 148
[
Footnote 2/1]
25 U. S. 12
Wheat. 445.
[
Footnote 2/2]
Vol. i. § 1016.