NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before
publication in the preliminary print of the United States
Reports. Readers are requested to notify the Reporter of Decisions,
Supreme Court of the United States, Washington, D. C. 20543,
of any typographical or other formal errors, in order that
corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to
press.
SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
_________________
No. 13–534
_________________
NORTH CAROLINA STATE BOARD OF DENTAL EXAMINERS, PETITIONER
v. FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
on writ of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for
the fourth circuit
[February 25, 2015]
Justice Kennedy delivered the opinion of the Court.
This case arises from an antitrust challenge to the actions of a
state regulatory board. A majority of the board’s members are
engaged in the active practice of the profession it regulates. The
question is whether the board’s actions are protected from Sherman
Act regulation under the doctrine of state-action antitrust
immunity, as defined and applied in this Court’s decisions
beginning with
Parker v.
Brown,317 U. S. 341
(1943).
I
A
In its Dental Practice Act (Act), North Carolina has declared
the practice of dentistry to be a matter of public concern
requiring regulation. N. C. Gen. Stat. Ann. §90–22(a) (2013).
Under the Act, the North Carolina State Board of Dental Examiners
(Board) is “the agency of the State for the regulation of the
practice of dentistry.” §90–22(b).
The Board’s principal duty is to create, administer, and enforce
a licensing system for dentists. See §§90–29 to 90–41. To perform
that function it has broad authority over licensees. See §90–41.
The Board’s authority with respect to unlicensed persons, however,
is more restricted: like “any resident citizen,” the Board may file
suit to “perpetually enjoin any person from . . .
unlawfully practicing dentistry.” §90–40.1.
The Act provides that six of the Board’s eight members must be
licensed dentists engaged in the active practice of dentistry.
§90–22. They are elected by other licensed dentists in North
Carolina, who cast their ballots in elections conducted by the
Board.
Ibid. The seventh member must be a licensed and
practicing dental hygienist, and he or she is elected by other
licensed hygienists.
Ibid. The final member is referred to
by the Act as a “consumer” and is appointed by the Governor.
Ibid. All members serve 3-year terms, and no person may
serve more than two consecutive terms.
Ibid. The Act does
not create any mechanism for the removal of an elected member of
the Board by a public official. See
ibid.
Board members swear an oath of office, §138A–22(a), and the
Board must comply with the State’s Administrative Procedure Act,
§150B–1
et seq., Public Records Act, §132–1
et seq., and open-meetings law, §143–318.9
et seq. The Board may promulgate rules and regulations
governing the practice of dentistry within the State, provided
those mandates are not inconsistent with the Act and are approved
by the North Carolina Rules Review Commission, whose members are
appointed by the state legislature. See §§90–48, 143B–30.1,
150B–21.9(a).
B
In the 1990’s, dentists in North Carolina started whitening
teeth. Many of those who did so, including 8 of the Board’s 10
members during the period at issue in this case, earned substantial
fees for that service. By 2003, nondentists arrived on the scene.
They charged lower prices for their services than the dentists did.
Dentists soon began to complain to the Board about their new
competitors. Few complaints warned of possible harm to consumers.
Most expressed a principal concern with the low prices charged by
nondentists.
Responding to these filings, the Board opened an investigation
into nondentist teeth whitening. A dentist member was placed in
charge of the inquiry. Neither the Board’s hygienist member nor its
consumer member participated in this undertaking. The Board’s chief
operations officer remarked that the Board was “going forth to do
battle” with nondentists. App. to Pet. for Cert. 103a. The Board’s
concern did not result in a formal rule or regulation reviewable by
the independent Rules Review Commission, even though the Act does
not, by its terms, specify that teeth whitening is “the practice of
dentistry.”
Starting in 2006, the Board issued at least 47 cease-and-desist
letters on its official letterhead to nondentist teeth whitening
service providers and product manufacturers. Many of those letters
directed the recipient to cease “all activity constituting the
practice of dentistry”; warned that the unlicensed practice of
dentistry is a crime; and strongly implied (or expressly stated)
that teeth whitening constitutes “the practice of dentistry.” App.
13, 15. In early 2007, the Board persuaded the North Carolina Board
of Cosmetic Art Examiners to warn cosmetologists against providing
teeth whitening services. Later that year, the Board sent letters
to mall operators, stating that kiosk teeth whiteners were
violating the Dental Practice Act and advising that the malls
consider expelling violators from their premises.
These actions had the intended result. Nondentists ceased
offering teeth whitening services in North Carolina.
C
In 2010, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) filed an
administrative complaint charging the Board with violating §5 of
the Federal Trade Commission Act,38Stat.719, as amended,15
U. S. C. §45. The FTC alleged that the Board’s concerted
action to exclude nondentists from the market for teeth whitening
services in North Carolina constituted an anticompetitive and
unfair method of competition. The Board moved to dismiss, alleging
state-action immunity. An Administrative Law Judge (ALJ) denied the
motion. On appeal, the FTC sustained the ALJ’s ruling. It reasoned
that, even assuming the Board had acted pursuant to a clearly
articulated state policy to displace competition, the Board is a
“public/private hybrid” that must be actively supervised by the
State to claim immunity. App. to Pet. for Cert. 49a. The FTC
further concluded the Board could not make that showing.
Following other proceedings not relevant here, the ALJ conducted
a hearing on the merits and determined the Board had unreasonably
restrained trade in violation of antitrust law. On appeal, the FTC
again sustained the ALJ. The FTC rejected the Board’s public safety
justification, noting,
inter alia, “a wealth of evidence
. . . suggesting that non-dentist provided teeth
whitening is a safe cosmetic procedure.”
Id., at 123a.
The FTC ordered the Board to stop sending the cease-and-desist
letters or other communications that stated nondentists may not
offer teeth whitening services and products. It further ordered the
Board to issue notices to all earlier recipients of the Board’s
cease-and-desist orders advising them of the Board’s proper sphere
of authority and saying, among other options, that the notice
recipients had a right to seek declaratory rulings in state
court.
On petition for review, the Court of Appeals for the Fourth
Circuit affirmed the FTC in all respects. 717 F. 3d 359, 370
(2013). This Court granted certiorari. 571 U. S. ___
(2014).
II
Federal antitrust law is a central safeguard for the Nation’s
free market structures. In this regard it is “as important to the
preservation of economic freedom and our free-enterprise system as
the Bill of Rights is to the protection of our fundamental personal
freedoms.”
United States v.
Topco Associates,
Inc.,405 U. S. 596,610 (1972). The antitrust laws declare
a considered and decisive prohibition by the Federal Government of
cartels, price fixing, and other combinations or practices that
undermine the free market.
The Sherman Act,26Stat.209, as amended,15 U. S. C. §1
et seq., serves to promote robust competition, which in
turn empowers the States and provides their citizens with
opportunities to pursue their own and the public’s welfare. See
FTC v.
Ticor Title Ins. Co.,504 U. S. 621,632
(1992). The States, however, when acting in their respective realm,
need not adhere in all contexts to a model of unfettered
competition. While “the States regulate their economies in many
ways not inconsistent with the antitrust laws,”
id., at
635–636, in some spheres they impose restrictions on occupations,
confer exclusive or shared rights to dominate a market, or
otherwise limit competition to achieve public objectives. If every
duly enacted state law or policy were required to conform to the
mandates of the Sherman Act, thus promoting competition at the
expense of other values a State may deem fundamental, federal
antitrust law would impose an impermissible burden on the States’
power to regulate. See
Exxon Corp. v.
Governor of
Maryland,437 U. S. 117,133 (1978); see also Easterbrook,
Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism, 26 J. Law &
Econ. 23, 24 (1983).
For these reasons, the Court in
Parker v.
Brown
interpreted the antitrust laws to confer immunity on
anticompetitive conduct by the States when acting in their
sovereign capacity. See 317 U. S., at 350–351. That ruling
recognized Congress’ purpose to respect the federal balance and to
“embody in the Sherman Act the federalism principle that the States
possess a significant measure of sovereignty under our
Constitution.”
Community Communications Co. v.
Boulder,455 U. S. 40,53 (1982). Since 1943, the Court
has reaffirmed the importance of
Parker’s central holding.
See,
e.g., Ticor,
supra, at 632–637;
Hoover v.
Ronwin,466 U. S. 558,568 (1984);
Lafayette v.
Louisiana Power & Light Co.,435 U. S. 389–400
(1978).
III
In this case the Board argues its members were invested by North
Carolina with the power of the State and that, as a result, the
Board’s actions are cloaked with
Parker immunity. This
argument fails, however. A nonsovereign actor controlled by active
market participants—such as the Board—enjoys
Parker immunity
only if it satisfies two requirements: “first that ‘the challenged
restraint . . . be one clearly articulated and
affirmatively expressed as state policy,’ and second that ‘the
policy . . . be actively supervised by the State.’ ”
FTC v.
Phoebe Putney Health System, Inc., 568
U. S. ___, ___ (2013) (slip op., at 7) (quoting
California
Retail Liquor Dealers Assn. v
. Midcal Aluminum, Inc.,
445 U. S. 97,105 (1980)). The parties have assumed that the
clear articulation requirement is satisfied, and we do the same.
While North Carolina prohibits the unauthorized practice of
dentistry, however, its Act is silent on whether that broad
prohibition covers teeth whitening. Here, the Board did not receive
active super-vision by the State when it interpreted the Act as
ad-dressing teeth whitening and when it enforced that policy by
issuing cease-and-desist letters to nondentist teeth whiteners.
A
Although state-action immunity exists to avoid conflicts between
state sovereignty and the Nation’s commitment to a policy of robust
competition,
Parker immunity is not unbounded. “[G]iven the
fundamental national values of free enterprise and economic
competition that are embodied in the federal antitrust laws, ‘state
action immunity is disfavored, much as are repeals by
implication.’ ”
Phoebe Putney,
supra, at ___
(slip op., at 7) (quoting
Ticor,
supra, at 636).
An entity may not invoke
Parker immunity unless the
actions in question are an exercise of the State’s sovereign power.
See
Columbia v.
Omni Outdoor Advertising, Inc.,499
U. S. 365,374 (1991). State legislation and “decision[s] of a
state supreme court, acting legislatively rather than judicially,”
will satisfy this standard, and “
ipso facto are exempt from
the operation of the antitrust laws” because they are an undoubted
exercise of state sovereign authority.
Hoover,
supra,
at 567–568.
But while the Sherman Act confers immunity on the States’ own
anticompetitive policies out of respect for federalism, it does not
always confer immunity where, as here, a State delegates control
over a market to a non-sovereign actor. See
Parker,
supra, at 351 (“[A] state does not give immunity to those
who violate the Sherman Act by authorizing them to violate it, or
by declaring that their action is lawful”). For purposes of
Parker, a nonsovereign actor is one whose conduct does not
automatically qualify as that of the sovereign State itself. See
Hoover,
supra, at 567–568. State agencies are not
simply by their governmental character sovereign actors for
purposes of state-action immunity. See
Goldfarb v.
Virginia State Bar,421 U. S. 773,791 (1975) (“The fact
that the State Bar is a state agency for some limited purposes does
not create an antitrust shield that allows it to foster
anticompetitive practices for the benefit of its members”).
Immunity for state agencies, therefore, requires more than a mere
facade of state involvement, for it is necessary in light of
Parker’s rationale to ensure the States accept political
accountability for anticompetitive conduct they permit and control.
See
Ticor, 504 U. S., at 636.
Limits on state-action immunity are most essential when the
State seeks to delegate its regulatory power to active market
participants, for established ethical standards may blend with
private anticompetitive motives in a way difficult even for market
participants to discern. Dual allegiances are not always apparent
to an actor. In consequence, active market participants cannot be
allowed to regulate their own markets free from antitrust
account-ability. See
Midcal,
supra, at 106 (“The
national policy in favor of competition cannot be thwarted by
casting [a] gauzy cloak of state involvement over what is
essentially a private price-fixing arrangement”). Indeed,
prohibitions against anticompetitive self-regulation by active
market participants are an axiom of federal antitrust policy. See,
e.g., Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v.
Indian
Head, Inc.,486 U. S. 492,501 (1988);
Hoover,
supra, at 584 (Stevens, J., dissenting) (“The risk that
private regulation of market entry, prices, or output may be
designed to confer monop-oly profits on members of an industry at
the expense of the consuming public has been the central concern of
. . . our antitrust jurisprudence”); see also Elhauge,
The Scope of Antitrust Process, 104 Harv. L. Rev. 667, 672
(1991). So it follows that, under
Parker and the Supremacy
Clause, the States’ greater power to attain an end does not include
the lesser power to negate the congressional judgment embodied in
the Sherman Act through unsupervised delegations to active market
participants. See Garland, Antitrust and State Action: Economic
Efficiency and the Political Process, 96 Yale L. J. 486, 500
(1986).
Parker immunity requires that the anticompetitive conduct
of nonsovereign actors, especially those authorized by the State to
regulate their own profession, result from procedures that suffice
to make it the State’s own. See
Goldfarb, supra, at 790; see
also 1A P. Areeda & H. Hovencamp, Antitrust Law ¶226, p. 180
(4th ed. 2013) (Areeda & Hovencamp). The question is not
whether the challenged conduct is efficient, well-functioning, or
wise. See
Ticor,
supra, at 634–635. Rather, it is
“whether anticompetitive conduct engaged in by [nonsovereign
actors] should be deemed state action and thus shielded from the
antitrust laws.”
Patrick v.
Burget,486 U. S.
94,100 (1988).
To answer this question, the Court applies the two-part test set
forth in
California Retail Liquor Dealers Assn. v.
Midcal
Aluminum, Inc.,445 U. S. 97, a case arising from
California’s delegation of price-fixing authority to wine
merchants. Under
Midcal, “[a] state law or regulatory scheme
cannot be the basis for antitrust immunity unless, first, the State
has articulated a clear policy to allow the anticompetitive
conduct, and second, the State provides active supervision of [the]
anticompetitive conduct.”
Ticor,
supra, at 631
(citing
Midcal,
supra, at 105).
Midcal’s clear articulation requirement is satisfied
“where the displacement of competition [is] the inherent, logical,
or ordinary result of the exercise of authority delegated by the
state legislature. In that scenario, the State must have foreseen
and implicitly endorsed the anticompetitive effects as consistent
with its policy goals.”
Phoebe Putney, 568 U. S., at
___ (slip op., at 11). The active supervision requirement demands,
inter alia, “that state officials have and exercise power to
review particular anticompetitive acts of private parties and
disapprove those that fail to accord with state policy.”
Patrick,
supra, U. S., at 101.
The two requirements set forth in
Midcal provide a proper
analytical framework to resolve the ultimate question whether an
anticompetitive policy is indeed the policy of a State. The first
requirement—clear articulation—rarely will achieve that goal by
itself, for a policy may satisfy this test yet still be defined at
so high a level of generality as to leave open critical questions
about how and to what extent the market should be regulated. See
Ticor,
supra, at 636–637. Entities purporting to act
under state authority might diverge from the State’s considered
definition of the public good. The resulting asymmetry between a
state policy and its implementation can invite private
self-dealing. The second
Midcal requirement—active
supervision—seeks to avoid this harm by requiring the State to
review and approve interstitial policies made by the entity
claiming immunity.
Midcal’s supervision rule “stems from the recognition
that ‘[w]here a private party is engaging in anticompetitive
activity, there is a real danger that he is acting to further his
own interests, rather than the governmental interests of the
State.’ ”
Patrick,
supra, at 100. Concern about
the private incentives of active market participants animates
Midcal’s supervision mandate, which demands “realistic
assurance that a private party’s anticompetitive conduct promotes
state policy, rather than merely the party’s individual interests.”
Patrick,
supra, at 101.
B
In determining whether anticompetitive policies and conduct are
indeed the action of a State in its sovereign capacity, there are
instances in which an actor can be excused from
Midcal’s
active supervision requirement. In
Hallie v.
Eau
Claire, 471 U. S. 34
, 45 (1985), the Court held
municipalities are subject exclusively to
Midcal’s
“ ‘clear articulation’ ” requirement. That rule, the
Court observed, is consistent with the objective of ensuring that
the policy at issue be one enacted by the State itself.
Hallie explained that “[w]here the actor is a municipality,
there is little or no danger that it is involved in a private
price-fixing arrangement. The only real danger is that it will seek
to further purely parochial public interests at the expense of more
overriding state goals.” 471 U. S., at 47.
Hallie
further observed that municipalities are electorally accountable
and lack the kind of private incentives characteristic of active
participants in the market. See
id., at 45, n. 9.
Critically, the municipality in
Hallie exercised a wide
range of governmental powers across different economic spheres,
substantially reducing the risk that it would pursue private
interests while regulating any single field. See
ibid. That
Hallie excused municipalities from
Midcal’s
supervision rule for these reasons all but confirms the rule’s
applicability to actors controlled by active market participants,
who ordinarily have none of the features justifying the narrow
exception
Hallie identified. See 471 U. S., at 45.
Following
Goldfarb,
Midcal, and
Hallie,
which clarified the conditions under which
Parker immunity
attaches to the conduct of a nonsovereign actor, the Court in
Columbia v.
Omni Outdoor Advertising, Inc.,499
U. S. 365, addressed whether an otherwise immune entity could
lose immunity for conspiring with private parties. In
Omni,
an aspiring billboard merchant argued that the city of Columbia,
South Carolina, had violated the Sherman Act—and forfeited its
Parker immunity—by anticompetitively conspiring with an
established local company in passing an ordinance restricting new
billboard construction. 499 U. S., at 367–368. The Court
disagreed, holding there is no “conspiracy exception” to
Parker.
Omni, supra, at 374.
Omni, like the cases before it, recognized the importance
of drawing a line “relevant to the purposes of the Sherman Act and
of
Parker: prohibiting the restriction of competition for
private gain but permitting the restriction of competition in the
public interest.” 499 U. S., at 378. In the context of a
municipal actor which, as in
Hallie, exercised substantial
governmental powers,
Omni rejected a conspiracy exception
for “corruption” as vague and unworkable, since “virtually all
regulation benefits some segments of the society and harms others”
and may in that sense be seen as “ ‘corrupt.’ ” 499
U. S., at 377.
Omni also rejected subjective tests for
corruption that would force a “deconstruction of the governmental
process and probing of the official ‘intent’ that we have
consistently sought to avoid.”
Ibid. Thus, whereas the cases
preceding it addressed the preconditions of
Parker immunity
and engaged in an objective,
ex ante inquiry into
nonsovereign actors’ structure and incentives,
Omni made
clear that recipients of immunity will not lose it on the basis of
ad hoc and
ex post questioning of their motives
for making particular decisions.
Omni’s holding makes it all the more necessary to ensure
the conditions for granting immunity are met in the first place.
The Court’s two state-action immunity cases decided after
Omni reinforce this point. In
Ticor the Court
affirmed that
Midcal’s limits on delegation must ensure that
“[a]ctual state involvement, not deference to private price-fixing
arrangements under the general auspices of state law, is the
precondition for immunity from federal law.” 504 U. S., at
633. And in
Phoebe Putney the Court observed that
Midcal’s active supervision requirement, in particular, is
an essential condition of state-action immunity when a nonsovereign
actor has “an incentive to pursue [its] own self-interest under the
guise of implementing state policies.” 568 U. S., at ___ (slip
op., at 8) (quoting
Hallie,
supra, at 46–47). The
lesson is clear:
Midcal’s active supervision test is an
essential prerequisite of
Parker immunity for any
nonsovereign entity—public or private—controlled by active market
participants.
C
The Board argues entities designated by the States as agencies
are exempt from
Midcal’s second requirement. That premise,
however, cannot be reconciled with the Court’s repeated conclusion
that the need for supervision turns not on the formal designation
given by States to regulators but on the risk that active market
participants will pursue private interests in restraining
trade.
State agencies controlled by active market participants, who
possess singularly strong private interests, pose the very risk of
self-dealing
Midcal’s supervision requirement was created to
address. See Areeda & Hovencamp ¶227, at 226. This conclusion
does not question the good faith of state officers but rather is an
assessment of the structural risk of market participants’ confusing
their own interests with the State’s policy goals. See
Patrick, 486 U. S., at 100–101.
The Court applied this reasoning to a state agency in
Goldfarb. There the Court denied immunity to a state agency
(the Virginia State Bar) controlled by market participants
(lawyers) because the agency had “joined in what is essentially a
private anticompetitive activity” for “the benefit of its members.”
421 U. S., at 791, 792. This emphasis on the Bar’s private
interests explains why
Goldfarb, though it predates
Midcal, considered the lack of supervision by the Virginia
Supreme Court to be a principal reason for denying immunity. See
421 U. S., at 791; see also
Hoover, 466 U. S., at
569 (emphasizing lack of active supervision in
Goldfarb);
Bates v.
State Bar of Ariz.,433 U. S. 350–362
(1977) (granting the Arizona Bar state-action immunity partly
because its “rules are subject to pointed re-examination by the
policymaker”).
While
Hallie stated “it is likely that active state
supervision would also not be required” for agencies, 471
U. S., at 46, n. 10, the entity there, as was later the
case in
Omni, was an electorally accountable municipality
with general regulatory powers and no private price-fixing agenda.
In that and other respects the municipality was more like
prototypical state agencies, not specialized boards dominated by
active market participants. In important regards, agencies
controlled by market participants are more similar to private trade
associations vested by States with regulatory authority than to the
agencies
Hallie considered. And as the Court observed three
years after
Hallie, “[t]here is no doubt that the members of
such associations often have economic incentives to restrain
competition and that the product standards set by such associations
have a serious potential for anticompetitive harm.”
Allied
Tube, 486 U. S., at 500. For that reason, those
associations must satisfy
Midcal’s active supervision
standard. See
Midcal, 445 U. S., at 105–106.
The similarities between agencies controlled by active market
participants and private trade associations are not eliminated
simply because the former are given a formal designation by the
State, vested with a measure of government power, and required to
follow some procedural rules. See
Hallie,
supra, at
39 (rejecting “purely formalistic” analysis).
Parker
immunity does not derive from nomenclature alone. When a State
empowers a group of active market participants to decide who can
participate in its market, and on what terms, the need for
supervision is manifest. See Areeda & Hovencamp ¶227, at 226.
The Court holds today that a state board on which a controlling
number of decisionmakers are active market participants in the
occupation the board regulates must satisfy
Midcal’s active
supervision requirement in order to invoke state-action antitrust
immunity.
D
The State argues that allowing this FTC order to stand will
discourage dedicated citizens from serving on state agencies that
regulate their own occupation. If this were so—and, for reasons to
be noted, it need not be so—there would be some cause for concern.
The States have a sovereign interest in structuring their
governments, see
Gregory v.
Ashcroft,501 U. S.
452,460 (1991), and may conclude there are substantial benefits to
staffing their agencies with experts in complex and technical
subjects, see
Southern Motor Carriers Rate Conference, Inc.
v.
United States,471 U. S. 48,64 (1985). There is,
moreover, a long tradition of citizens esteemed by their
professional colleagues devoting time, energy, and talent to
enhancing the dignity of their calling.
Adherence to the idea that those who pursue a calling must
embrace ethical standards that derive from a duty separate from the
dictates of the State reaches back at least to the Hippocratic
Oath. See generally S. Miles, The Hippocratic Oath and the Ethics
of Medicine (2004). In the United States, there is a strong
tradition of professional self-regulation, particularly with
respect to the development of ethical rules. See generally R.
Rotunda & J. Dzienkowski, Legal Ethics: The Lawyer’s Deskbook
on Professional Responsibility (2014); R. Baker, Before Bioethics:
A History of American Medical Ethics From the Colonial Period to
the Bioethics Revolution (2013). Dentists are no exception. The
American Dental Association, for example, in an exercise of “the
privilege and obligation of self-government,” has “call[ed] upon
dentists to follow high ethical standards,” including “honesty,
compassion, kindness, integrity, fairness and charity.” American
Dental Association, Principles of Ethics and Code of Professional
Conduct 3–4 (2012). State laws and institutions are sustained by
this tradition when they draw upon the expertise and commitment of
professionals.
Today’s holding is not inconsistent with that idea. The Board
argues, however, that the potential for money damages will
discourage members of regulated occupations from participating in
state government. Cf.
Filarsky v.
Delia, 566
U. S. ___, ___ (2012) (slip op., at 12) (warning in the
context of civil rights suits that the “the most talented
candidates will decline public engagements if they do not receive
the same immunity enjoyed by their public employee counterparts”).
But this case, which does not present a claim for money damages,
does not offer occasion to address the question whether agency
officials, including board members, may, under some circumstances,
enjoy immunity from damages liability. See
Goldfarb, 421
U. S., at 792, n. 22; see also Brief for Respondent 56. And,
of course, the States may provide for the defense and
indemnification of agency members in the event of litigation.
States, furthermore, can ensure
Parker immunity is
available to agencies by adopting clear policies to displace
competition; and, if agencies controlled by active market
participants interpret or enforce those policies, the States may
provide active supervision. Precedent confirms this principle. The
Court has rejected the argument that it would be unwise to apply
the antitrust laws to professional regulation absent compliance
with the prerequisites for invoking
Parker immunity:
“[Respondents] contend that effective peer review is essential
to the provision of quality medical care and that any threat of
antitrust liability will prevent physicians from participating
openly and actively in peer-review proceedings. This argument,
however, essentially challenges the wisdom of applying the
antitrust laws to the sphere of medical care, and as such is
properly directed to the legislative branch. To the extent that
Congress has declined to exempt medical peer review from the reach
of the antitrust laws, peer review is immune from antitrust
scrutiny only if the State effectively has made this conduct its
own.”
Patrick, 486 U. S. at 105–106 (footnote
omitted).
The reasoning of
Patrick v.
Burget applies to this
case with full force, particularly in light of the risks licensing
boards dominated by market participants may pose to the free
market. See generally Edlin & Haw, Cartels by Another Name:
Should Licensed Occupations Face Antitrust Scrutiny? 162
U. Pa. L. Rev. 1093 (2014).
E
The Board does not contend in this Court that its
anticompetitive conduct was actively supervised by the State or
that it should receive
Parker immunity on that basis.
By statute, North Carolina delegates control over the practice
of dentistry to the Board. The Act, however, says nothing about
teeth whitening, a practice that did not exist when it was passed.
After receiving complaints from other dentists about the
nondentists’ cheaper services, the Board’s dentist members—some of
whom offered whitening services—acted to expel the dentists’
competitors from the market. In so doing the Board relied upon
cease-and-desist letters threatening criminal liability, rather
than any of the powers at its disposal that would invoke oversight
by a politically accountable official. With no active supervision
by the State, North Carolina officials may well have been unaware
that the Board had decided teeth whitening constitutes “the
practice of dentistry” and sought to prohibit those who competed
against dentists from participating in the teeth whitening market.
Whether or not the Board exceeded its powers under North Carolina
law, cf.
Omni, 499 U. S., at 371–372, there is no
evidence here of any decision by the State to initiate or concur
with the Board’s actions against the nondentists.
IV
The Board does not claim that the State exercised active, or
indeed any, supervision over its conduct regarding nondentist teeth
whiteners; and, as a result, no specific supervisory systems can be
reviewed here. It suffices to note that the inquiry regarding
active supervision is flexible and context-dependent. Active
supervision need not entail day-to-day involvement in an agency’s
operations or micromanagement of its every decision. Rather, the
question is whether the State’s review mechanisms provide
“realistic assurance” that a nonsovereign actor’s anticompetitive
conduct “promotes state policy, rather than merely the party’s
individual interests.”
Patrick,
supra, at 100–101;
see also
Ticor, 504 U. S., at 639–640.
The Court has identified only a few constant requirements of
active supervision: The supervisor must review the substance of the
anticompetitive decision, not merely the procedures followed to
produce it, see
Patrick, 486 U. S., at 102–103; the
supervisor must have the power to veto or modify particular
decisions to ensure they accord with state policy, see
ibid.; and the “mere potential for state supervision is not
an adequate substitute for a decision by the State,”
Ticor,
supra, at 638. Further, the state supervisor may not itself
be an active market participant. In general, however, the adequacy
of supervision otherwise will depend on all the circumstances of a
case.
* * *
The Sherman Act protects competition while also respecting
federalism. It does not authorize the States to abandon markets to
the unsupervised control of active market participants, whether
trade associations or hybrid agencies. If a State wants to rely on
active market participants as regulators, it must provide active
supervision if state-action immunity under
Parker is to be
invoked.
The judgment of the Court of Appeals for the Fourth Circuit is
affirmed.
It is so ordered.