SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
_________________
No. 11–864
_________________
COMCAST CORPORATION, et al., PETITIONERS
v. CAROLINE BEHREND et al.
on writ of certiorari to the united states
court of appeals for the third circuit
[March 27, 2013]
Justice Ginsburg and Justice Breyer, with whom
Justice Sotomayor and Justice Kagan join, dissenting.
Today the Court reaches out to decide a case
hardly fit for our consideration. On both procedural and
substantive grounds, we dissent.
I
This case comes to the Court infected by our
misguided reformulation of the question presented. For that reason
alone, we would dismiss the writ of certiorari as improvidently
granted.
Comcast sought review of the following question:
“[W]hether a district court may certify a class action without
resolving ‘merits arguments’ that bear on [Federal Rule of Civil
Procedure] 23’s prerequisites for certifica-tion, including whether
purportedly common issues predominate over individual ones under
Rule 23(b)(3).” Pet. for Cert. i. We granted review of a different
question: “Whether a district court may certify a class action
without resolving
whether the plaintiff class has introduced
admissible evidence, including expert testimony, to show that
the case is susceptible to awarding damages on a class-wide basis.”
567 U. S. ___ (2012) (emphasis added).
Our rephrasing shifted the focus of the dispute
from the District Court’s Rule 23(b)(3) analysis to its attention
(or lack thereof) to the admissibility of expert testimony. The
parties, responsively, devoted much of their briefing to the
question whether the standards for admissibility of expert evidence
set out in Federal Rule of Evidence 702 and
Daubert v.
Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc.,
509
U.S. 579 (1993), apply in class certification proceedings. See
Brief for Petitioners 35–49; Brief for Respondents 24–37. Indeed,
respondents confirmed at oral argument that they understood our
rewritten question to center on admissibility, not Rule 23(b)(3).
See,
e.g., Tr. of Oral Arg. 25.
As it turns out, our reformulated question was
inapt. To preserve a claim of error in the admission of evidence, a
party must timely object to or move to strike the evidence. Fed.
Rule Evid. 103(a)(1). In the months preceding the District Court’s
class certification order, Comcast did not object to the admission
of Dr. McClave’s damages model under Rule 702 or
Daubert.
Nor did Comcast move to strike his testimony and expert report.
Consequently, Comcast forfeited any objection to the admission of
Dr. McClave’s model at the certification stage. At this late date,
Comcast may no longer argue that respondents’ damages evidence was
inadmissible.
Comcast’s forfeiture of the question on which we
granted review is reason enough to dismiss the writ as
improvidently granted. See
Rogers v.
United States,
522 U.S.
252, 259 (1998) (O’Connor, J., concurring in result) (“[W]e
ought not to decide the question if it has not been cleanly
presented.”);
The Monrosa v.
Carbon Black Export,
Inc.,
359 U.S.
180, 183 (1959) (dismissal appropriate in light of
“circumstances . . . not fully apprehended at the time certiorari
was granted” (internal quotation marks omitted)). The Court,
however, elects to evaluate whether re-spondents “failed to show
that the case is susceptible to awarding damages on a class-wide
basis.”
Ante, at 5, n. 4 (internal quotation marks
omitted). To justify this second revision of the question
presented, the Court observes that Comcast “argued below, and
continue[s] to argue here, that certification was improper because
respondents had failed to establish that damages could be measured
on a classwide basis.”
Ibid. And so
Comcast did, in
addition to endeavoring to address the question on which we granted
review. By treating the first part of our reformulated question as
though it did not exist, the Court is hardly fair to
respondents.
Abandoning the question we instructed the
parties to brief does “not reflect well on the processes of the
Court.”
Redrup v.
New York,
386
U.S. 767, 772 (1967) (Harlan, J., dissenting). Taking their cue
from our order, respondents did not train their energies on
defending the District Court’s finding of predominance in their
briefing or at oral argument. The Court’s newly revised question,
focused on predominance, phrased only after briefing was done, left
respondents without an unclouded opportunity to air the issue the
Court today decides against them. And by resolving a complex and
fact-intensive question without the benefit of full briefing, the
Court invites the error into which it has fallen. See
infra,
at 5–11
.
II
While the Court’s decision to review the
merits of the District Court’s certification order is both unwise
and un-fair to respondents, the opinion breaks no new ground on the
standard for certifying a class action under Federal Rule of Civil
Procedure 23(b)(3). In particular, the decision should not be read
to require, as a prerequisite to certification, that damages
attributable to a classwide injury be measurable “ ‘on a
class-wide basis.’ ” See
ante, at 2–3 (acknowledging
Court’s dependence on the absence of contest on the matter in this
case); Tr. of Oral Arg. 41.
To gain class-action certification under Rule
23(b)(3), the named plaintiff must demonstrate, and the District
Court must find, “that the questions of law or fact common to class
members predominate over any questions affecting only individual
members.” This predominance requirement is meant to “tes[t] whether
proposed classes are sufficiently cohesive to warrant adjudication
by representation,”
Amchem Products, Inc. v.
Windsor,
521 U.S.
591, 623 (1997), but it scarcely demands commonality as to all
questions. See 7AA C. Wright, A. Miller, & M. Kane, Federal
Practice and Procedure §1778, p. 121 (3d ed. 2005) (hereinafter
Wright, Miller, & Kane). In particular, when adjudication of
questions of liability common to the class will achieve economies
of time and expense, the predominance standard is generally
satisfied even if damages are not provable in the aggregate. See
Advisory Committee’s 1966 Notes on Fed. Rule Civ. Proc. 23, 28
U. S. C. App., p. 141 (“[A] fraud perpetrated on numerous
persons by the use of similar misrepresentations may be an
appealing situation for a class action, and it may remain so
despite the need, if liability is found, for separate determination
of the damages suffered by individuals within the class.”); 7AA
Wright, Miller, & Kane §1781, at 235–237.[
1]*
Recognition that individual damages calculations
do not preclude class certification under Rule 23(b)(3) is well
nigh universal. See 2 W. Rubenstein, Newberg on Class Actions
§4:54, p. 205 (5th ed. 2012) (ordinarily, “individual damage[s]
calculations should not scuttle class certification under Rule
23(b)(3)”). Legions of appellate decisions across a range of
substantive claims are illustrative. See,
e.g.,
Tardiff v.
Knox County,
365 F.3d 1, 6 (CA1 2004) ( Fourth Amendment);
Chiang v.
Veneman,
385 F.3d 256, 273 (CA3 2004) (Equal Credit Opportunity Act);
Bertulli v.
Independent Assn. of Continental Pilots,
242 F.3d 290, 298 (CA5 2001) (Labor-Management Reporting and
Disclosure Act and Railway Labor Act);
Beattie v.
CenturyTel, Inc., 511 F.3d 554, 564–566 (CA6 2007) (Federal
Communications Act);
Arreola v.
Godinez, 546 F.3d
788, 801 (CA7 2008) ( Eighth Amendment). Antitrust cases, which
typically involve common allegations of antitrust violation,
antitrust impact, and the fact of damages, are classic examples.
See
In re Visa Check/MasterMoney Antitrust Litigation,
280 F.3d 124, 139–140 (CA2 2001). See also 2A P. Areeda, H.
Hovenkamp, R. Blair, & C. Durrance, Antitrust Law ¶331, p. 56
(3d ed. 2007) (hereinafter Areeda & Hovenkamp); 6 A. Conte
& H. Newberg, Newberg on Class Actions §18:27, p. 91 (4th ed.
2002). As this Court has rightly observed, “[p]redominance is a
test readily met” in actions alleging “violations of the antitrust
laws.”
Amchem, 521 U. S., at 625.
The oddity of this case, in which the need to
prove damages on a classwide basis through a common methodology was
never challenged by respondents, see Brief for Plaintiffs-Appellees
in No. 10–2865 (CA3), pp. 39–40, is a further reason to dismiss the
writ as improvidently granted. The Court’s ruling is good for this
day and case only. In the mine run of cases, it remains the “black
letter rule” that a class may obtain certification under Rule
23(b)(3) when liability questions common to the class predominate
over damages questions unique to class members. 2 Rubenstein,
supra, §4:54, at 208.
III
Incautiously entering the fray at this
interlocutory stage, the Court sets forth a profoundly mistaken
view of antitrust law. And in doing so, it relies on its own
version of the facts, a version inconsistent with factual findings
made by the District Court and affirmed by the Court of
Appeals.
A
To understand the antitrust problem, some
(simplified) background discussion is necessary. Plaintiffs below,
re-spondents here, alleged that Comcast violated §§1 and 2 of the
Sherman Act. See 15 U. S. C. §§1, 2. For present
purposes, the §2 claim provides the better illustration. A firm is
guilty of monopolization under §2 if the plaintiff proves
(1) “the possession of monopoly power in the relevant market”
and (2) “the willful acquisition or maintenance of that
power[,] as distinguished from growth or development as a
consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic
accident.”
United States v.
Grinnell Corp.,
384 U.S.
563, 570–571 (1966). A private plaintiff seeking damages must
also show that (3) the monopolization caused “injur[y].” 15
U. S. C. §15. We have said that antitrust injuries must
be “of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and
that flo[w] from that which makes defendants’ acts unlawful.”
Atlantic Richfield Co. v.
USA Petroleum Co.,
495 U.S.
328, 334 (1990) (quoting
Brunswick Corp. v.
Pueblo
Bowl-O-Mat, Inc.,
429 U.S.
477, 489 (1977)). See 2A Areeda & Ho-venkamp ¶391a, at 320
(To prove antitrust injury, “[a] private plaintiff must identify
the economic rationale for a business practice’s illegality under
the antitrust laws and show that its harm flows from whatever it is
that makes the practice unlawful.”).
As plaintiffs below, respondents attempted to
meet these requirements by showing that (1) Comcast obtained a 60%
or greater share of the Philadelphia market, and that its share
provides it with monopoly power; (2) Comcast acquired its share
through exclusionary conduct consisting of a series of mergers with
competitors and “swaps” of customers and locations; and
(3) Comcast consequently injured respondents by charging them
supra-competitive prices.
If, as respondents contend, Philadelphia is a
separate well-defined market, and the alleged exclusionary conduct
permitted Comcast to obtain a market share of at least 60%, then
proving the §2 violation may not be arduous. As a point of
comparison, the government considers a market shared by four firms,
each of which has 25% market share, to be “highly concentrated.”
Dept. of Justice & Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger
Guidelines §5.3, p. 19 (2010). A market, such as the one alleged by
respondents, where
one firm controls 60% is far worse. See
id., §5.3, at 18–19, and n. 9 (using a concentration
index that determines a market’s concentration level by summing the
squares of each firm’s market share, one firm with 100% yielding
10,000, five firms with 20% each yielding 2000, while a market
where one firm accounts for 60% yields an index number of
at
least 3,600). The Guidelines, and any standard antitrust
treatise, explain why firms in highly concentrated markets normally
have the power to raise prices significantly above competitive
levels. See,
e.g., 2B Areeda & Hovenkamp ¶503, at
115.
B
So far there is agreement. But consider the
last matter respondents must prove: Can they show that Comcast
injured them by charging higher prices? After all, a firm with
monopoly power will not necessarily exercise that power by charging
higher prices. It could instead act less competitively in other
ways, such as by leading the quiet life. See J. Hicks, Annual
Survey of Economic Theory: The Theory of Monopoly, 3 Econometrica
1, 8 (1935) (“The best of all monopoly profits is a quiet
life.”).
It is at this point that Dr. McClave’s model
enters the scene. His model first selects a group of comparable
outside-Philadelphia “benchmark” counties, where Comcast
enjoyed a lower market share (and where satellite broadcasting
accounted for more of the local business). Using multiple
regression analysis, McClave’s model measures the effect of the
anticompetitive conduct by comparing the class counties to the
benchmark counties. The model concludes that the prices
Philadelphia area consumers would have paid had the Philadelphia
counties shared the properties of the benchmark counties (including
a diminished Comcast market share), would have been 13.1% lower
than those they actually paid. Thus, the model provides evidence
that Comcast’s anticompetitive conduct, which led to a 60% market
share, caused the class to suffer injuriously higher prices.
C
1
The special antitrust-related difficulty
present here stems from the manner in which respondents attempted
to prove their antitrust injuries. They proffered four
“non-exclusive mechanisms” that allegedly “cause[d] the high
prices” in the Philadelphia area. App. 403a. Those four theories
posit that (1) due to Comcast’s acquisitions of competitors,
customers found it more difficult to compare prices; (2) one
set of potential competitors, namely Direct Broadcast Satellite
companies, found it more difficult to obtain access to local sports
broadcasts and consequently decided not to enter the Philadelphia
market; (3) Comcast’s ability to obtain programming material at
lower prices permitted it to raise prices; and (4) a number of
potential competitors (called “overbuilders”), whose presence in
the market would have limited Comcast’s power to raise prices, were
ready to enter some parts of the market but decided not to do so in
light of Comcast’s anticompetitive conduct. 264 F.R.D. 150, 161–162
(ED Pa. 2010).
For reasons not here relevant, the District
Court found the first three theories inapplicable and limited the
liability-phase proof to the “overbuilder” theory. See App. to Pet.
for Cert. 192a–193a. It then asked the parties to brief whether
doing so had any impact on the viability of McClave’s model as a
measure of classwide damages. See 264 F. R. D., at 190.
After considering the parties’ arguments, the District Court found
that striking the three theories “does not impeach Dr. McClave’s
damages model” because “[a]ny anticompetitive conduct is reflected
in the [higher Philadelphia] price [which Dr. McClave’s model
determines], not in the [the model’s] selection of the comparison
counties, [
i.e., the lower-price ‘benchmark counties’ with
which the Philadelphia area prices were compared].”
Id., at
190–191. The court explained that “whether or not we accepted all
[four] . . . theories . . . is inapposite to Dr. McClave’s methods
of choosing benchmarks.”
Ibid. On appeal, the Third Circuit
held that this finding was not an abuse of discretion. 655 F.3d
182, 207 (2011).
2
The Court, however, concludes that “the model
failed to measure damages resulting from the particular antitrust
injury on which petitioners’ liability in this action is premised.”
Ante, at 8. To reach this conclusion the Court must consider
fact-based matters, namely what this econometric
multiple-regression model is about, what it proves, and how it does
so. And it must overturn two lower courts’ related factual findings
to the contrary.
We are normally “reluctant to disturb findings
of fact in which two courts below have concurred.”
United
States v.
Doe,
465 U.S.
605, 614 (1984). See also
United States v.
Virginia,
518 U.S.
515, 589, n. 5 (1996) (Scalia, J., dissenting) (noting
“our well-settled rule that we will not ‘undertake to review
concurrent findings of fact by two courts below in the absence of a
very obvious and exceptional showing of error’ ” (quoting
Graver Tank & Mfg. Co. v.
Linde Air Products Co.,
336 U.S.
271, 275 (1949))). Here, the District Court found McClave’s
econometric model capable of measuring damages on a classwide
basis, even after striking three of the injury theories. 264
F. R. D., at 190–191. Contrary to the Court’s
characterization, see
ante, at 8–9, n. 5, this was not
a legal conclusion about what the model proved; it was a factual
finding about
how the model worked. Under our typical
practice, we should leave that finding alone.
In any event, as far as we can tell, the lower
courts were right. On the basis of the record as we understand it,
the District Court did not abuse its discretion in finding that
McClave’s model could measure damages suffered by the class—even if
the damages were limited to those caused by deterred overbuilding.
That is because respondents alleged that Comcast’s anticompetitive
conduct increased Comcast’s market share (and market power) by
deterring potential entrants, in particular, overbuilders, from
entering the Philadelphia area market. See App. 43a–66a. By showing
that this was so, respondents’ proof tends to show the same in
respect to other entrants. The overbuilders’ failure to enter
deprives the market of the price discipline that their entry would
have provided in other parts via threat of the overbuilders’
expansion or that of others potentially led on by their example.
Indeed, in the District Court, Comcast argued that the three other
theories,
i.e., the three rejected theories, had no impact
on prices. See 264 F. R. D., at 166, 176, 180–181. If
Comcast was right, then the damages McClave’s model found must have
stemmed exclusively from conduct that deterred new entry, say from
“overbuilders.” Not surprisingly, the Court offers no support at
all for its contrary conclusion, namely, that the District Court’s
finding was “ ‘obvious[ly] and exceptional[ly]’ erroneous.”
Ante, at 8–9, n. 5 (quoting
Virginia, 518
U. S., at 589, n. 5 (Scalia, J., dissenting)).
We are particularly concerned about the matter
because the Court, in reaching its contrary conclusion, makes broad
statements about antitrust law that it could not mean to apply in
other cases. The Court begins with what it calls an “unremarkable
premise” that respondents could be “entitled only to damages
resulting from reduced overbuilder competition.”
Ante,
at 7
. In most §2 cases, how-ever, the Court’s starting
place would seem
remarkable, not “unremarkable.”
Suppose in a different case a plaintiff were to
prove that Widget, Inc. has obtained, through anticompetitive
means, a 90% share of the California widget market. Suppose the
plaintiff also proves that the two small remaining firms—one in
Ukiah, the other in San Diego—lack the capacity to expand their
widget output to the point where that pos-sibility could deter
Widget, Inc. from raising its prices. Suppose further that the
plaintiff introduces a model that shows California widget prices
are now twice those in every other State, which, the model
concludes is (after accounting for other possible reasons) the
result of lack of competition in the California widget market. Why
would a court hearing that case restrict damages solely to
customers in the vicinity of Ukiah and San Diego?
Like the model in this example, Dr. McClave’s
model does not purport to show precisely
how Comcast’s
conduct led to higher prices in the Philadelphia area. It simply
shows
that Comcast’s conduct brought about higher prices.
And it measures the amount of subsequent harm.
* * *
Because the parties did not fully argue the
question the Court now answers, all Members of the Court may lack a
complete understanding of the model or the meaning of related
statements in the record. The need for focused argument is
particularly strong here where, as we have said, the underlying
considerations are detailed, technical, and fact-based. The Court
departs from our ordinary practice, risks inaccurate judicial
decisionmaking, and is unfair to respondents and the courts below.
For these rea-sons, we would not disturb the Court of Appeals’
judgment and, instead, would dismiss the writ as improvidently
granted.