After respondent Omni Outdoor Advertising, Inc., entered the
billboard market in petitioner Columbia, South Carolina, petitioner
Columbia Outdoor Advertising, Inc. (COA), which controlled more
than 95% of the market and enjoyed close relations with city
officials, lobbied these officials to enact zoning ordinances
restricting billboard construction. After such ordinances were
passed, Omni filed suit against petitioners under §§ 1 and 2 of the
Sherman Act and the State's Unfair Trade Practices Act, alleging,
inter alia, that the ordinances were the result of an
anticompetitive conspiracy that stripped petitioners of any
immunity to which they might otherwise be entitled. After Omni
obtained a jury verdict on all counts, the District Court granted
petitioners' motions for judgment notwithstanding the verdict on
the ground that their activities were outside the scope of the
federal antitrust laws. The Court of Appeals reversed and
reinstated the verdict.
Held:
1. The city's restriction of billboard construction is immune
from federal antitrust liability under
Parker v. Brown,
317 U. S. 341,
317 U. S. 352
-- which held that principles of federalism and state sovereignty
render the Sherman Act inapplicable to anticompetitive restraints
imposed by the States "as an act of government" -- and subsequent
decisions according
Parker immunity to municipal
restriction of competition in implementation of state policy,
see, e.g., Hallie v. Eau Claire, 471 U. S.
34,
471 U. S. 38.
Pp.
499 U. S.
370-379.
(a) The Court of Appeals correctly concluded that the city was
prima facie entitled to
Parker immunity for its
billboard restrictions. Although
Parker immunity does not
apply directly to municipalities or other political subdivisions of
the States, it does apply where a municipality's restriction of
competition is an authorized implementation of state policy. South
Carolina's zoning statutes unquestionably authorized the city to
regulate the size, location, and spacing of billboards. The
additional
Parker requirement that the city possess clear
delegated authority to suppress competition,
see, e.g., Hallie,
supra, 471 U.S. at
471 U. S. 40-42,
is also met here, since suppression of competition is, at the very
least, a foreseeable result of zoning regulations. Pp.
499 U. S.
370-373.
Page 499 U. S. 366
(b) The Court of Appeals erred, however, in applying a
"conspiracy" exception to
Parker, which is not supported
by the language of that case. Such an exception would swallow up
the
Parker rule if "conspiracy" means nothing more than
agreement to impose the regulation in question, since it is both
inevitable and desirable that public officials agree to do what one
or another group of private citizens urges upon them. It would be
similarly impractical to limit "conspiracy" to instances of
governmental "corruption," or governmental acts "not in the public
interest"; virtually all anticompetitive regulation is open to such
charges, and the risk of unfavorable
ex post facto
judicial assessment would impair the States' ability to regulate
their domestic commerce. Nor is it appropriate to limit
"conspiracy" to instances in which bribery or some other violation
of state or federal law has been established, since the exception
would then be unrelated to the purposes of the Sherman Act, which
condemns trade restraints, not political activity. With the
possible exception of the situation in which the State is acting as
a market participant, any action that qualifies as state action is
ipso facto exempt from the operation of the antitrust
laws. Pp.
499 U. S.
374-379.
2. COA is immune from liability for its activities relating to
enactment of the ordinances under
Eastern Railroad Presidents
Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U.
S. 127,
365 U. S. 141,
which states a corollary to
Parker: the federal antitrust
laws do not regulate the conduct of private individuals in seeking
anticompetitive action from the government. The Court of Appeals
erred in applying the "sham" exception to the
Noerr
doctrine. This exception encompasses situations in which persons
use the governmental process itself -- as opposed to the outcome of
that process -- as an anticompetitive weapon. That is not the
situation here.
California Motor Transport Co. v. Trucking
Unlimited, 404 U. S. 508,
404 U. S. 512,
distinguished. Omni's suggestion that this Court adopt a
"conspiracy" exception to
Noerr immunity is rejected for
largely the same reasons that prompt the Court to reject such an
exception to
Parker. Pp.
499 U. S.
379-384.
3. The Court of Appeals on remand must determine (if the theory
has been properly preserved) whether the evidence was sufficient to
sustain a verdict for Omni based solely on its assertions that COA
engaged in private anticompetitive actions, and whether COA can be
held liable to Omni on its state law claim. P.
499 U. S.
384.
891 F.2d 1127 (CA4 1989), reversed and remanded.
SCALIA, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
REHNQUIST, C.J., and BLACKMUN, O'CONNOR, KENNEDY, and SOUTER, JJ.,
joined. STEVENS, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which WHITE and
MARSHALL, JJ., joined,
post, p.
499 U. S.
385.
Page 499 U. S. 367
JUSTICE SCALIA delivered the opinion of the Court.
This case requires us to clarify the application of the Sherman
Act to municipal governments and to the citizens who seek action
from them.
Petitioner Columbia Outdoor Advertising, Inc. (COA), a South
Carolina corporation, entered the billboard business in the city of
Columbia, South Carolina (also a petitioner here), in the 1940's.
By 1981, it controlled more than 95% of what has been conceded to
be the relevant market. COA was a local business owned by a family
with deep roots in the community, and enjoyed close relations with
the city's political leaders. The mayor and other members of the
city council were personal friends of COA's majority owner, and the
company and its officers occasionally contributed funds and free
billboard space to their campaigns. According to respondent, these
beneficences were part of a "longstanding" "secret anticompetitive
agreement" whereby "the City and COA would each use their [sic]
respective power and resources to protect . . . COA's monopoly
position," in return for which "City Council members received
advantages made possible by COA's monopoly." Brief for Respondent
12, 16.
Page 499 U. S. 368
In 1981, respondent Omni Outdoor Advertising, Inc., a Georgia
corporation, began erecting billboards in and around the city. COA
responded to this competition in several ways. First, it redoubled
its own billboard construction efforts and modernized its existing
stock. Second -- according to Omni -- it took a number of
anticompetitive private actions, such as offering artificially low
rates, spreading untrue and malicious rumors about Omni, and
attempting to induce Omni's customers to break their contracts.
Finally (and this is what gives rise to the issue we address
today), COA executives met with city officials to seek the
enactment of zoning ordinances that would restrict billboard
construction. COA was not alone in urging this course; a number of
citizens concerned about the city's recent explosion of billboards
advocated restrictions, including writers of articles and
editorials in local newspapers.
In the spring of 1982, the city council passed an ordinance
requiring the council's approval for every billboard constructed in
downtown Columbia. This was later amended to impose a 180-day
moratorium on the construction of billboards throughout the city,
except as specifically authorized by the council. A state court
invalidated this ordinance on the ground that its conferral of
unconstrained discretion upon the city council violated both the
South Carolina and Federal Constitutions. The city then requested
the State's regional planning authority to conduct a comprehensive
analysis of the local billboard situation as a basis for developing
a final, constitutionally valid, ordinance. In September, 1982,
after a series of public hearings and numerous meetings involving
city officials, Omni, and COA (in all of which, according to Omni,
positions contrary to COA's were not genuinely considered), the
city council passed a new ordinance restricting the size, location,
and spacing of billboards. These restrictions, particularly those
on spacing, obviously benefited COA, which already had its
billboards in place; they severely hindered Omni's ability to
compete.
Page 499 U. S. 369
In November, 1982, Omni filed suit against COA and the city in
Federal District Court, charging that they had violated §§ 1 and 2
of the Sherman Act, 26 Stat. 209, as amended, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1, 2,
[
Footnote 1] as well as South
Carolina's Unfair Trade Practices Act, S.C.Code § 39-5-140 (1976).
Omni contended, in particular, that the city's billboard ordinances
were the result of an anticompetitive conspiracy between city
officials and COA that stripped both parties of any immunity they
might otherwise enjoy from the federal antitrust laws. In January,
1986, after more than two weeks of trial, a jury returned general
verdicts against the city and COA on both the federal and state
claims. It awarded damages, before trebling, of $600,000 on the § 1
Sherman Act claim, and $400,000 on the § 2 claim. [
Footnote 2] The jury also answered two
special interrogatories, finding specifically that the city and COA
had conspired both to restrain trade and to monopolize the market.
Petitioners moved for judgment notwithstanding the verdict,
contending among other
Page 499 U. S. 370
things that their activities were outside the scope of the
federal antitrust laws. In November, 1988, the District Court
granted the motion.
A divided panel of the United States Court of Appeals for the
Fourth Circuit reversed the judgment of the District Court and
reinstated the jury verdict on all counts. 891 F.2d 1127 (1989). We
granted certiorari, 496 U.S. 935 (1990).
II
In the landmark case of
Parker v. Brown, 317 U.
S. 341 (1943), we rejected the contention that a program
restricting the marketing of privately produced raisins, adopted
pursuant to California's Agricultural Prorate Act, violated the
Sherman Act. Relying on principles of federalism and state
sovereignty, we held that the Sherman Act did not apply to
anticompetitive restraints imposed by the States "as an act of
government." 317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
352.
Since
Parker emphasized the role of sovereign States in
a federal system, it was initially unclear whether the governmental
actions of political subdivisions enjoyed similar protection. In
recent years, we have held that
Parker immunity does not
apply directly to local governments,
see Hallie v. Eau
Claire, 471 U. S. 34,
471 U. S. 38
(1985);
Community Communications Co. v. Boulder,
455 U. S. 40,
455 U. S. 50-51
(1982);
Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light Co.,
435 U. S. 389,
435 U. S.
412-413 (1978) (plurality opinion). We have recognized,
however, that a municipality's restriction of competition may
sometimes be an authorized implementation of state policy, and have
accorded
Parker immunity where that is the case.
The South Carolina statutes under which the city acted in the
present case authorize municipalities to regulate the use of land
and the construction of buildings and other structures within their
boundaries. [
Footnote 3] It is
undisputed that, as a matter
Page 499 U. S. 371
of state law, these statutes authorize the city to regulate the
size, location, and spacing of billboards. It could be argued,
however, that a municipality acts beyond its delegated authority,
for
Parker purposes, whenever the nature of its regulation
is substantively or even procedurally defective. On such an
analysis, it could be contended, for example, that the city's
regulation in the present case was not "authorized" by S.C.Code §
5-23-10 (1976),
see n
3,
supra, if it was not, as that statute requires, adopted
"for the purpose of promoting health, safety, morals or the general
welfare of the community." As scholarly commentary has noted, such
an expansive interpretation of the
Parker defense
authorization requirement would have unacceptable consequences.
"To be sure, state law 'authorizes' only agency decisions that
are substantively and procedurally correct. Errors of fact, law, or
judgment by the agency are not 'authorized.' Erroneous acts or
decisions are subject to
Page 499 U. S. 372
reversal by superior tribunals because unauthorized. If the
antitrust court demands unqualified 'authority' in this sense, it
inevitably becomes the standard reviewer not only of federal agency
activity, but also of state and local activity whenever it is
alleged that the governmental body, though possessing the power to
engage in the challenged conduct, has actually exercised its power
in a manner not authorized by state law. We should not lightly
assume that
Lafayette's authorization requirement dictates
transformation of state administrative review into a federal
antitrust job. Yet that would be the consequence of making
antitrust liability depend on an undiscriminating and mechanical
demand for 'authority' in the full administrative law sense."
P. Areeda & H. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law � 212.3b, p. 145
(Supp.1989). We agree with that assessment, and believe that, in
order to prevent
Parker from undermining the very
interests of federalism it is designed to protect, it is necessary
to adopt a concept of authority broader than what is applied to
determine the legality of the municipality's action under state
law. We have adopted an approach that is similar in principle,
though not necessarily in precise application, elsewhere.
See
Stump v. Sparkman, 435 U. S. 349
(1978). It suffices for the present to conclude that here no more
is needed to establish, for
Parker purposes, the city's
authority to regulate than its unquestioned zoning power over the
size, location, and spacing of billboards.
Besides authority to regulate, however, the
Parker
defense also requires authority to suppress competition -- more
specifically, "clear articulation of a state policy to authorize
anticompetitive conduct" by the municipality in connection with its
regulation.
Hallie, 471 U.S. at
471 U. S. 40
(internal quotation omitted). We have rejected the contention that
this requirement can be met only if the delegating statute
explicitly permits the displacement of competition,
see
id. at
471 U. S.
41-42.
Page 499 U. S. 373
It is enough, we have held, if suppression of competition is the
"foreseeable result" of what the statute authorizes,
id.
at
471 U. S. 42.
That condition is amply met here. The very purpose of zoning
regulation is to displace unfettered business freedom in a manner
that regularly has the effect of preventing normal acts of
competition, particularly on the part of new entrants. A municipal
ordinance restricting the size, location, and spacing of billboards
(surely a common form of zoning) necessarily protects existing
billboards against some competition from newcomers. [
Footnote 4]
Page 499 U. S. 374
The Court of Appeals was therefore correct in its conclusion
that the city's restriction of billboard construction was
prima
facie entitled to
Parker immunity. The Court of
Appeals upheld the jury verdict, however, by invoking a
"conspiracy" exception to
Parker that has been recognized
by several Courts of Appeals.
See, e.g., Whitworth v.
Perkins, 559 F.2d 378 (CA5 1977),
vacated, 435 U.S.
992,
aff'd on rehearing, 576 F.2d 696 (1978),
cert.
denied, 440 U.S. 911 (1979). That exception is thought to be
supported by two of our statements in
Parker:
"[W]e have no question of the state or its municipality becoming
a
participant in a private agreement or combination by
others for restraint of trade,
cf. Union Pacific R. Co. v.
United States, 313 U. S. 450."
Parker, 317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
351-352 (emphasis added).
"The state, in adopting and enforcing the prorate program, made
no contract or agreement
and entered into no conspiracy in
restraint of trade or to establish monopoly, but, as
sovereign, imposed the restraint as an act of government which the
Sherman Act did not undertake to prohibit."
Id. at
317 U. S. 352
(emphasis added).
Parker does not apply, according to the
Fourth Circuit, "where politicians or political entities are
involved as conspirators" with private actors in the restraint of
trade. 891 F.2d at 1134.
There is no such conspiracy exception. The rationale of
Parker was that, in light of our national commitment to
federalism, the general language of the Sherman Act should not be
interpreted to prohibit anticompetitive actions by the States in
their governmental capacities as sovereign regulators. The
sentences from the opinion quoted above simply clarify that this
immunity does not necessarily obtain where the State acts not in a
regulatory capacity, but as a commercial
Page 499 U. S. 375
participant in a given market. That is evident from the citation
of
Union Pacific R. Co. v. United States, 313 U.
S. 450 (1941), which held unlawful under the Elkins Act
certain rebates and concessions made by Kansas City, Kansas, in its
capacity as the owner and operator of a wholesale produce market
that was integrated with railroad facilities. These sentences
should not be read to suggest the general proposition that even
governmental regulatory action may be deemed private -- and
therefore subject to antitrust liability -- when it is taken
pursuant to a conspiracy with private parties. The impracticality
of such a principle is evident if, for purposes of the exception,
"conspiracy" means nothing more than an agreement to impose the
regulation in question. Since it is both inevitable and desirable
that public officials often agree to do what one or another group
of private citizens urges upon them, such an exception would
virtually swallow up the
Parker rule: all anticompetitive
regulation would be vulnerable to a "conspiracy" charge.
See Areeda & Hovenkamp,
supra, � 203.3b, at
34, and n. 1; Elhauge, The Scope of Antitrust Process, 104
Harv.L.Rev. 667, 704-705 (1991). [
Footnote 5]
Page 499 U. S. 376
Omni suggests, however, that "conspiracy" might be limited to
instances of governmental "corruption," defined variously as
"abandonment of public responsibilities to private interests,"
Brief for Respondent 42, "corrupt or bad faith decisions,"
id. at 44, and "selfish or corrupt motives,"
ibid. Ultimately, Omni asks us not to define "corruption"
at all, but simply to leave that task to the jury:
"[a]t bottom, however, it was within the jury's province to
determine what constituted corruption of the governmental process
in their community."
Id. at 43. Omni's
amicus eschews this emphasis
on "corruption," instead urging us to define the conspiracy
exception as encompassing any governmental act "not in the public
interest." Brief for Associated Builders and Contractors, Inc. as
Amicus Curiae 5.
Page 499 U. S. 377
A conspiracy exception narrowed along such vague lines is
similarly impractical. Few governmental actions are immune from the
charge that they are "not in the public interest," or in some sense
"corrupt." The California marketing scheme at issue in
Parker itself, for example, can readily be viewed as the
result of a "conspiracy" to put the "private" interest of the
State's raisin growers above the "public" interest of the State's
consumers. The fact is that virtually all regulation benefits some
segments of the society and harms others; and that it is not
universally considered contrary to the public good if the net
economic loss to the losers exceeds the net economic gain to the
winners.
Parker was not written in ignorance of the
reality that determination of "the public interest" in the manifold
areas of government regulation entails not merely economic and
mathematical analysis, but value judgment, and it was not meant to
shift that judgment from elected officials to judges and juries. If
the city of Columbia's decision to regulate what one local
newspaper called "billboard jungles," Columbia Record, May 21,
1982, p. 14-A, col. l; App. in No. 88-1388 (CA4), p. 3743, is made
subject to
ex post facto judicial assessment of "the
public interest," with personal liability of city officials a
possible consequence, we will have gone far to "compromise the
States' ability to regulate their domestic commerce,"
Southern
Motor Carriers Rate Conference, Inc. v. United States,
471 U. S. 48,
471 U. S. 56
(1985). The situation would not be better, but arguably even worse,
if the courts were to apply a subjective test: not whether the
action was in the public interest, but whether the officials
involved thought it to be so. This would require the sort of
deconstruction of the governmental process and probing of the
official "intent" that we have consistently sought to avoid.
[
Footnote 6]
"[W]here the action complained
Page 499 U. S. 378
of . . . was that of the State itself, the action is exempt from
antitrust liability regardless of the State's motives in taking the
action."
Hoover v. Ronwin, 466 U. S. 558,
466 U. S.
579-580 (1984).
See also Llewellyn v. Crothers,
765 F.2d 769, 774 (CA9 1985) (Kennedy, J.).
The foregoing approach to establishing a "conspiracy" exception
at least seeks (however impractically) to draw the line of
impermissible action in a manner relevant to the purposes of the
Sherman Act and of
Parker: prohibiting the restriction of
competition for private gain but permitting the restriction of
competition in the public interest. Another approach is possible,
which has the virtue of practicality but the vice of being
unrelated to those purposes. That is the approach which would
consider
Parker inapplicable only if, in connection with
the governmental action in question, bribery or some other
violation of state or federal law has been established. Such
unlawful activity has no necessary relationship to whether the
governmental action is in the public interest. A mayor is guilty of
accepting a bribe even if he would and should have taken, in the
public interest, the same action for which the bribe was paid.
(That is frequently the defense asserted to a criminal bribery
charge -- and though it is never valid in law,
see, e.g.,
United States v. Jannotti, 673 F.2d 578, 601 (CA3) (en banc),
cert. denied, 457 U.S. 1106 (1982), it is often plausible
in fact.) When, moreover, the regulatory body is not a single
individual but a state legislature or city council, there is even
less reason to believe that violation of the law (by bribing a
minority of the decisionmakers) establishes that the regulation has
no valid public purpose.
Cf. 10 U. S. Peck,
6 Cranch 87,
10 U. S. 130
(1810). To use unlawful political influence as the test of legality
of state regulation undoubtedly vindicates (in a rather blunt way)
principles of good government. But the statute we are construing is
not directed to that end. Congress has passed other laws aimed
Page 499 U. S. 379
at combatting corruption in state and local governments.
See, e.g., 18 U.S.C. § 1951 (Hobbs Act). "Insofar as [the
Sherman Act] sets up a code of ethics at all, it is a code that
condemns trade restraints, not political activity."
Eastern
Railroad Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc.,
365 U. S. 127,
365 U. S. 140
(1961).
For these reasons, we reaffirm our rejection of any
interpretation of the Sherman Act that would allow plaintiffs to
look behind the actions of state sovereigns to base their claims on
"perceived conspiracies to restrain trade,"
Hoover, 466
U.S. at
466 U. S. 580.
We reiterate that, with the possible market participant exception,
any action that qualifies as state action is "
ipso
facto . . . exempt from the operation of the antitrust laws,"
id. at
466 U. S. 568.
This does not mean, of course, that the States may exempt
private action from the scope of the Sherman Act; we in no
way qualify the well established principle that "a state does not
give immunity to those who violate the Sherman Act by authorizing
them to violate it, or by declaring that their action is lawful."
Parker, 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 351
(citing
Northern Securities Co. v. United States,
193 U. S. 197,
193 U. S. 332,
193 U. S.
344-347 (1904)).
See also Schwegmann Brothers v.
Calvert Distillers Corp., 341 U. S. 384
(1951).
III
While
Parker recognized the States' freedom to engage
in anticompetitive regulation, it did not purport to immunize from
antitrust liability the private parties who urge them to engage in
anticompetitive regulation. However, it is obviously peculiar in a
democracy, and perhaps in derogation of the constitutional right
"to petition the Government for a redress of grievances,"
U.S.Const., Amdt. 1, to establish a category of lawful state action
that citizens are not permitted to urge. Thus, beginning with
Eastern Railroad Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight,
Inc., supra, we have developed a corollary to
Parker:
the federal antitrust laws also do not regulate the conduct of
private individuals in seeking
Page 499 U. S. 380
anticompetitive action from the government. This doctrine, like
Parker, rests ultimately upon a recognition that the
antitrust laws, "tailored as they are for the business world, are
not at all appropriate for application in the political arena."
Noerr, supra, 365 U.S. at
365 U. S. 141.
That a private party's political motives are selfish is irrelevant:
"
Noerr shields from the Sherman Act a concerted effort to
influence public officials regardless of intent or purpose."
United Mine Workers of America v. Pennington, 381 U.
S. 657,
381 U. S. 670
(1965).
Noerr recognized, however, what has come to be known as
the "sham" exception to its rule:
"There may be situations in which a publicity campaign,
ostensibly directed toward influencing governmental action, is a
mere sham to cover what is actually nothing more than an attempt to
interfere directly with the business relationships of a competitor,
and the application of the Sherman Act would be justified."
365 U.S. at
365 U. S. 144.
The Court of Appeals concluded that the jury in this case could
have found that COA's activities on behalf of the restrictive
billboard ordinances fell within this exception. In our view, that
was error.
The "sham" exception to
Noerr encompasses situations in
which persons use the governmental
process -- as opposed
to the
outcome of that process -- as an anticompetitive
weapon. A classic example is the filing of frivolous objections to
the license application of a competitor, with no expectation of
achieving denial of the license but simply in order to impose
expense and delay.
See California Motor Transport Co. v.
Trucking Unlimited, 404 U. S. 508
(1972). A "sham" situation involves a defendant whose activities
are "not genuinely aimed at procuring favorable government action"
at all,
Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head,
Inc., 486 U. S. 492,
486 U. S. 500,
n. 4 (1988), not one "who
genuinely seeks to achieve his
governmental result, but does so through improper means,'"
id. at 486 U. S. 508,
n. 10 (quoting Sessions Tank Liners, Inc. v. Joor Mfg.,
Inc., 827 F.2d 458, 465, n. 5 (CA9 1987)).
Page 499 U. S. 381
Neither of the Court of Appeals' theories for application of the
"sham" exception to the facts of the present case is sound. The
court reasoned, first, that the jury could have concluded that
COA's interaction with city officials "was
actually nothing
more than an attempt to interfere directly with the business
relations [sic] of a competitor.'" 891 F.2d at 1139 (quoting
Noerr, supra, 365 U.S. at
365 U. S.
144). This analysis relies upon language from
Noerr, but ignores the import of the critical word
"directly." Although COA indisputably set out to disrupt Omni's
business relationships, it sought to do so not through the very
process of lobbying, or of causing the city council to consider
zoning measures, but rather through the ultimate
product
of that lobbying and consideration,
viz., the zoning
ordinances. The Court of Appeals' second theory was that the jury
could have found
"that COA's purposes were to delay Omni's entry into the market,
and even to deny it a meaningful access to the appropriate city
administrative and legislative fora."
891 F.2d at 1139. But the purpose of delaying a competitor's
entry into the market does not render lobbying activity a "sham,"
unless (as no evidence suggested was true here) the delay is sought
to be achieved only by the lobbying process itself, and not by the
governmental action that the lobbying seeks. "If
Noerr
teaches anything, it is that an intent to restrain trade as a
result of government action sought . . . does not foreclose
protection." Sullivan, Developments in the
Noerr Doctrine,
56 Antitrust L.J. 361, 362 (1987). As for "deny[ing] . . .
meaningful access to the appropriate city administrative and
legislative fora," that may render the manner of lobbying improper
or even unlawful, but does not necessarily render it a "sham." We
did hold in
California Motor Transport, supra, that a
conspiracy among private parties to monopolize trade by excluding a
competitor from participation in the regulatory process did not
enjoy
Noerr protection. But
California Motor
Transport involved a context in which the conspirators'
participation in the governmental process was itself claimed to be
a
Page 499 U. S. 382
"sham," employed as a means of imposing cost and delay. ("It is
alleged that petitioners
instituted the proceedings and actions
. . . with or without probable cause, and regardless of the merits
of the cases.'" 404 U.S. at 404 U. S.
512.) The holding of the case is limited to that
situation. To extend it to a context in which the regulatory
process is being invoked genuinely, and not in a "sham" fashion,
would produce precisely that conversion of antitrust law into
regulation of the political process that we have sought to avoid.
Any lobbyist or applicant, in addition to getting himself heard,
seeks by procedural and other means to get his opponent ignored.
Policing the legitimate boundaries of such defensive strategies,
when they are conducted in the context of a genuine attempt to
influence governmental action, is not the role of the Sherman Act.
In the present case, of course, any denial to Omni of "meaningful
access to the appropriate city administrative and legislative fora"
was achieved by COA in the course of an attempt to influence
governmental action that, far from being a "sham," was, if
anything, more in earnest than it should have been. If the denial
was wrongful, there may be other remedies, but as for the Sherman
Act, the Noerr exemption applies.
Omni urges that if, as we have concluded, the "sham" exception
is inapplicable, we should use this case to recognize another
exception to
Noerr immunity -- a "conspiracy" exception,
which would apply when government officials conspire with a private
party to employ government action as a means of stifling
competition. We have left open the possibility of such an
exception,
see, e.g., Allied Tube, supra, 486 U.S. at
486 U. S. 502,
n. 7, as have a number of Courts of Appeals.
See, e.g.,
Oberndorf v. Denver, 900 F.2d 1434, 1440 (CA10 1990);
First American Title Co. of South Dakota v. South Dakota Land
Title Assn., 714 F.2d 1439, 1446, n. 6 (CA8 1983),
cert.
denied, 464 U.S. 1042 (1984). At least one Court of Appeals
has affirmed the existence of such an exception in dicta,
see
Duke & Co. v. Foerster, 521 F.2d l 277, 1282 (CA3 1975),
and
Page 499 U. S. 383
the Fifth Circuit has adopted it as holding,
see Affiliated
Capital Corp. v. Houston, 735 F.2d 1555, 1566-1568 (1984) (en
banc).
Giving full consideration to this matter for the first time, we
conclude that a "conspiracy" exception to
Noerr must be
rejected. We need not describe our reasons at length, since they
are largely the same as those set forth in
499 U.
S. above, for rejecting a "conspiracy" exception to
Parker. As we have described,
Parker and
Noerr are complementary expressions of the principle that
the antitrust laws regulate business, not politics; the former
decision protects the States' acts of governing, and the latter the
citizens' participation in government. Insofar as the
identification of an immunity-destroying "conspiracy" is concerned,
Parker and
Noerr generally present two faces of
the same coin. The
Noerr-invalidating conspiracy alleged
here is just the
Parker-invalidating conspiracy viewed
from the standpoint of the private sector participants, rather than
the governmental participants. The same factors which, as we have
described above, make it impracticable or beyond the purpose of the
antitrust laws to identify and invalidate lawmaking that has been
infected by selfishly motivated agreement with private interests
likewise make it impracticable or beyond that scope to identify and
invalidate lobbying that has produced selfishly motivated agreement
with public officials.
"It would be unlikely that any effort to influence legislative
action could succeed unless one or more members of the legislative
body became . . . 'coconspirators'"
in some sense with the private party urging such action,
Metro Cable Co. v. CATV of Rockford, Inc., 516 F.2d 220,
230 (CA7 1975). And if the invalidating "conspiracy" is limited to
one that involves some element of unlawfulness (beyond mere
anticompetitive motivation), the invalidation would have nothing to
do with the policies of the antitrust laws. In
Noerr
itself, where the private party "deliberately deceived the public
and public officials" in its successful lobbying campaign, we said
that
Page 499 U. S. 384
"deception, reprehensible as it is, can be of no consequence so
far as the Sherman Act is concerned." 365 U.S. at
365 U. S.
145.
IV
Under
Parker and
Noerr, therefore, both the
city and COA are entitled to immunity from the federal antitrust
laws for their activities relating to enactment of the ordinances.
This determination does not entirely resolve the dispute before us,
since other activities are at issue in the case with respect to
COA. Omni asserts that COA engaged in private anticompetitive
actions such as trade libel, the setting of artificially low rates,
and inducement to breach of contract. Thus, although the jury's
general verdict against COA cannot be permitted to stand (since it
was based on instructions that erroneously permitted liability for
seeking the ordinances,
see Sunkist Growers, Inc. v. Winckler
& Smith Citrus Products Co., 370 U. S.
19,
370 U. S. 29-30
(1962)) if the evidence was sufficient to sustain a verdict on the
basis of these other actions alone, and if this theory of liability
has been properly preserved, Omni would be entitled to a new
trial.
There also remains to be considered the effect of our judgment
upon Omni's claim against COA under the South Carolina Unfair Trade
Practices Act. The District Court granted judgment notwithstanding
the verdict on this claim as well as the Sherman Act claims; the
Court of Appeals reversed on the ground that "a finding of
conspiracy to restrain competition is tantamount to a finding" that
the South Carolina law had been violated, 891 F.2d at 1143. Given
our reversal of the "conspiracy" holding, that reasoning is no
longer applicable.
We leave these remaining questions for determination by the
Court of Appeals on remand. The judgment of the Court of Appeals is
reversed, and the case is remanded for further proceedings
consistent with this opinion.
It is so ordered.
Page 499 U. S. 385
[
Footnote 1]
Section I provides in pertinent part:
"Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise,
or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several
States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal."
15 U.S.C. § 1.
Section 2 provides in pertinent part:
"Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or
combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize
any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with
foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony."
15 U.S.C. § 2.
[
Footnote 2]
The monetary damages in this case were assessed entirely against
COA, the District Court having ruled that the city was immunized by
the Local Government Antitrust Act of 1984, 98 Stat. 2750, as
amended, 15 U.S.C. §§ 34-36, which exempts local governments from
paying damages for violations of the federal antitrust laws.
Although enacted in 1984, after the events a issue in this case,
the Act specifically provides that it may be applied retroactively
if
"the defendant establishes and the court determines, in light of
all the circumstances . . . that it would be inequitable not to
apply this subsection to a pending case."
15 U.S.C. § 35(b). The District Court determined that it would
be, and the Court of Appeals refused to disturb that judgment.
Respondent has not challenged that determination in this Court, and
we express no view on the matter.
[
Footnote 3]
S.C.Code § 5-23-10 (1976) ("Building and zoning regulations
authorized") provides that,
"[f]or the purpose of promoting health, safety, morals or the
general welfare of the community, the legislative body of cities
and incorporated towns may by ordinance regulate and restrict the
height, number of stories and size of buildings and other
structures."
S.C.Code § 5-23-20 (1976) ("Division of municipality into
districts") provides that,
"[f]or any or all of such purposes the local legislative body
may divide the municipality into districts of such number, shape
and area as may be deemed best suited to carry out the purposes of
this article. Within such districts it may regulate and restrict
the erection, construction, reconstruction, alteration, repair or
use of buildings, structures or land."
S.C.Code § 6-7-710 (1976) ("Grant of power for zoning") provides
that,
"[f]or the purposes of guiding development in accordance with
existing and future needs and in order to protect, promote and
improve the public health, safety, morals, convenience, order,
appearance, prosperity, and general welfare, the governing
authorities of municipalities and counties may, in accordance with
the conditions and procedures specified in this chapter, regulate
the location height, bulk, number of stories and size of buildings
and other structures. . . . The regulations shall . . . be designed
to lessen congestion in the streets; to secure safety from fire,
panic, and other dangers, to promote the public health and the
general welfare, to provide adequate light and air; to prevent the
overcrowding of land; to avoid undue concentration of population;
to protect scenic areas; to facilitate the adequate provision of
transportation, water, sewage, schools, parks, and other public
requirements."
[
Footnote 4]
The dissent contends that, in order successfully to delegate its
Parker immunity to a municipality, a State must expressly
authorize the municipality to engage (1) in specifically "economic
regulation,"
post at
499 U. S. 388,
(2) of a specific industry,
post at
499 U. S. 391.
These dual specificities are without support in our precedents, for
the good reason that they defy rational implementation.
If, by authority to engage in specifically "economic"
regulation, the dissent means authority specifically to regulate
competition, we squarely rejected that in Hallie, as discussed in
text. Seemingly, however, the dissent means only that the State
authorization must specify that sort of regulation whereunder
"decisions about prices and output are not made by individual
firms, but rather by a public body."
Post at
499 U. S. 387.
But why is not the restriction of billboards in a city a
restriction on the "output" of the local billboard industry? It
assuredly is -- and that is indeed the very gravamen of Omni's
complaint. It seems to us that the dissent's concession that "it is
often difficult to differentiate economic regulation from municipal
regulation of health, safety, and welfare,"
post at
499 U. S. 393,
is a gross understatement. Loose talk about a "regulated industry"
may suffice for what the dissent calls "antitrust parlance "
post at
499 U. S. 387,
but it is not a definition upon which the criminal liability of
public officials ought to depend.
Under the dissent's second requirement for a valid delegation of
Parker immunity -- that the authorization to regulate
pertain to a specific industry -- the problem with the South
Carolina statute is that it used the generic term "structures,"
instead of conferring its regulatory authority industry-by-industry
(presumably "billboards," "movie houses," "mobile homes," "TV
antennas," and every other conceivable object of zoning regulation
that can be the subject of a relevant "market" for purposes of
antitrust analysis). To describe this is to refute it. Our
precedents not only fail to suggest, but positively reject, such an
approach.
"The municipality need not 'be able to point to a specific,
detailed legislative authorization' in order to assert a successful
Parker defense to an antitrust suit."
Hallie, 471 U.S. at
471 U. S. 39
(quoting
Lafayefte, 435 U.S. at
435 U. S.
415).
[
Footnote 5]
The dissent is confident that a jury composed of citizens of the
vicinage will be able to tell the difference between "independent
municipal action and action taken for the sole purpose of carrying
out an anticompetitive agreement for the private party."
Post at
499 U. S.
395-396. No doubt. But those are merely the polar
extremes, which, like the geographic poles, will rarely be seen by
jurors of the vicinage. Ordinarily, the allegation will merely be
(and the dissent says this is enough) that the municipal action was
not prompted "
exclusively by a concern for the general
public interest,"
post at
499 U. S. 387
(emphasis added). Thus, the real question is whether a jury can
tell the difference -- whether Solomon can tell the difference --
between "municipal action not entirely independent because based
partly on agreement with private parties" that is
lawful
and "municipal action not entirely independent because based partly
on agreement with private parties" that is
unlawful. The
dissent does not tell us how to put this question coherently, much
less how to answer it intelligently. "
Independent
municipal action" is un-objectionable, "action taken for the
sole purpose of carrying out an anticompetitive agreement
for the private party" is un-lawful, and everything else (that is,
the known world between the two poles) is unaddressed.
The dissent contends, moreover, that
"the instructions in this case, fairly read, told the jury that
the plaintiff should not prevail
unless the ordinance was
enacted for the sole purpose of interfering with access to the
market."
Post at
499 U. S. 396,
n. 9 (emphasis added). That is not so. The sum and substance of the
jury's instructions here was that anticompetitive municipal action
is not lawful when taken as part of a conspiracy, and that a
conspiracy is "an agreement between two or more persons to violate
the law, or to accomplish an otherwise lawful result in an unlawful
manner." J.A. 79. Although the District Court explained that "[i]t
is perfectly lawful for any and all persons to petition their
government," the court immediately added, "but they may not do so
as a part or as the object of a conspiracy."
Ibid. These
instructions, then, are entirely circular: an anticompetitive
agreement becomes unlawful if it is part of a conspiracy, and a
conspiracy is an agreement to do something unlawful. The District
Court's observation, upon which the dissent places so much weight,
that
"if by the evidence you find that [COA] procured and brought
about the passage of ordinances solely for the purpose of
hindering, delaying or otherwise interfering with the access of
[Omni] to the marketing area involved in this case . . . and
thereby conspired, then, of course, their conduct would not be
excused under the antitrust laws"
is in no way tantamount to an instruction that this was the only
theory upon which the jury could find an immunity-destroying
"conspiracy."
[
Footnote 6]
We have proceeded otherwise only in the "very limited and
well-defined class of cases where the very nature of the
constitutional question requires [this] inquiry."
United States
v. O'Brien, 391 U. S. 367,
391 U. S. 383,
n. 30 (1968) (bill of attainder).
See also Arlington Heights v.
Metropolitan Housing Development Corp., 429 U.
S. 252,
429 U. S. 268,
n. 18 (1977) (race-based motivation).
JUSTICE STEVENS, with whom JUSTICE WHITE and JUSTICE MARSHALL
join, dissenting.
Section 1 of the Sherman Act provides in part:
"
Every contract, combination in the form of trust or
otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among
the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be
illegal."
15 U.S.C. § 1 (emphasis added). Although we have previously
recognized that a completely literal interpretation of the word
"every" cannot have been intended by Congress, [
Footnote 2/1] the Court today carries this
recognition to an extreme by deciding that agreements between
municipalities, or their officials, and private parties to use the
zoning power to confer exclusive privileges in a particular line of
commerce are beyond the reach of § 1. History, tradition, and the
facts of this case all demonstrate that the Court's attempt to
create a "better" and less inclusive Sherman Act,
cf. West
Virginia
Page 499 U. S. 386
University Hospitals, Inc. v. Casey, 499 U. S.
83,
499 U. S. 101
(1991) is ill-advised.
I
As a preface to a consideration of the "state action" and
so-called "
Noerr-Pennington" exemptions to the Sherman
Act, it is appropriate to remind the Court that one of the classic
common law examples of a prohibited contract in restraint of trade
involved an agreement between a public official and a private
party. The public official -- the Queen of England -- had granted
one of her subjects a monopoly in the making, importation, and sale
of playing cards in order to generate revenues for the crown. A
competitor challenged the grant in
The Case of Monopolies,
11 Co.Rep. 84, 77 Eng.Rep. 1260 (Q.B.1602), and prevailed. Chief
Justice Popham explained on behalf of the bench:
"The Queen was . . . deceived in her grant; for the Queen . . .
intended it to be for the weal public, and it will be employed for
the private gain of the patentee, and for the prejudice of the weal
public; moreover the Queen meant that the abuse should be taken
away, which shall never be by this patent, but
potius the
abuse will be increased for the private benefit of the patentee,
and therefore . . . this grant is void
jure Regio."
Id. at 87a; 77 Eng.Rep. at 1264.
In the case before us today, respondent alleges that the city of
Columbia, South Carolina, has entered into a comparable agreement
to give respondent a monopoly in the sale of billboard advertising.
After a three-week trial, a jury composed of citizens of the
vicinage found that, despite the city fathers' denials, there was
indeed such an agreement, presumably motivated in part by past
favors in the form of political advertising, in part by friendship,
and in part by the expectation of a beneficial future relationship
-- and in any case, not
Page 499 U. S. 387
exclusively by a concern for the general public interest.
[
Footnote 2/2] Today the Court
acknowledges the anticompetitive consequences of this and similar
agreements, but decides that they should be exempted from the
coverage of the Sherman Act because it fears that enunciating a
rule that allows the motivations of public officials to be probed
may mean that innocent municipal officials may be harassed with
baseless charges. The holding evidences an unfortunate lack of
confidence in our judicial system and will foster the evils the
Sherman Act was designed to eradicate.
II
There is a distinction between economic regulation, on the one
hand, and regulation designed to protect the public health, safety,
and environment. In antitrust parlance, a "regulated industry" is
one in which decisions about prices and output are made not by
individual firms, but rather by a public body or a collective
process subject to governmental approval. Economic regulation of
the motor carrier and airline industries was imposed by the Federal
Government in the 1930s; the "deregulation" of those industries did
not eliminate all the other types of regulation that continue to
protect our safety and environmental concerns.
Page 499 U. S. 388
The antitrust laws reflect a basic national policy favoring free
markets over regulated markets. [
Footnote 2/3] In essence, the Sherman Act prohibits
private unsupervised regulation of the prices and output of goods
in the marketplace. That prohibition is inapplicable to specific
industries which Congress has exempted from the antitrust laws and
subjected to regulatory supervision over price and output
decisions. Moreover, the so-called "state action" exemption from
the Sherman Act reflects the Court's understanding that Congress
did not intend the statute to preempt a State's economic regulation
of commerce within its own borders.
The contours of the state action exemption are relatively
well-defined in our cases. Ever since our decision in
Olsen v.
Smith, 195 U. S. 332
(1904), which upheld a Texas statute fixing the rates charged by
pilots operating in the Port of Galveston, it has been clear that a
State's decision to displace competition with economic regulation
is not prohibited by the Sherman Act.
Parker v. Brown,
317 U. S. 341
(1943), the case most frequently identified with the state action
exemption, involved a decision by California to substitute sales
quotas and price control -- the purest form of economic regulation
-- for competition in the market for California raisins.
In
Olsen, the State itself had made the relevant
pricing decision. In
Parker, the regulation of the
marketing of California's
Page 499 U. S. 389
1940 crop of raisins was administered by state officials. Thus,
when a state agency, or the State itself, engages in economic
regulation, the Sherman Act is inapplicable.
Hoover v.
Ronwin, 466 U. S. 558,
466 U. S.
568-569 (1984);
Bates v. State Bar of Arizona,
433 U. S. 350,
433 U. S. 360
(1977).
Underlying the Court's recognition of this state action
exemption has been respect for the fundamental principle of
federalism. As we stated in
Parker, 317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
351,
"In a dual system of government in which, under the
Constitution, the states are sovereign, save only as Congress may
constitutionally subtract from their authority, an unexpressed
purpose to nullify a state's control over its officers and agents
is not lightly to be attributed to Congress."
However, this Court recognized long ago that the deference due
States within our federal system does not extend fully to conduct
undertaken by municipalities. Rather, all sovereign authority
"within the geographical limits of the United States" resides
with
"the Government of the United States, or [with] the States of
the Union. There exist within the broad domain of sovereignty but
these two. There may be cities, counties, and other organized
bodies with limited legislative functions, but they are all derived
from, or exist in, subordination to one or the other of these."
United States v. Kagama, 118 U.
S. 375,
118 U. S. 379
(1886).
Unlike States, municipalities do not constitute bedrocks within
our system of federalism. And also unlike States, municipalities
are more apt to promote their narrow parochial interests "without
regard to extraterritorial impact and regional efficiency."
Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light Co., 435 U.
S. 389,
435 U. S. 404
(1978);
see also The Federalist No. 10 (J. Madison)
(describing the greater tendency of smaller societies to promote
oppressive and narrow interests above the common good).
"If municipalities were free to make economic choices counseled
solely by their own parochial interests
Page 499 U. S. 390
and without regard to their anticompetitive effects, a serious
chink in the armor of antitrust protection would be introduced at
odds with the comprehensive national policy Congress
established."
Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light Co., 435 U.S.
at
435 U. S. 408.
Indeed,
"[i]n light of the serious economic dislocation which could
result if cities were free to place their own parochial interests
above the Nation's economic goals reflected in the antitrust laws,
. . . we are especially unwilling to presume that Congress intended
to exclude anticompetitive municipal action from their reach."
Id. at
435 U. S.
412-413. [
Footnote
2/4]
Nevertheless, insofar as municipalities may serve to implement
state policies, we have held that economic regulation administered
by a municipality may also be exempt from Sherman Act coverage if
it is enacted pursuant to a clearly articulated and affirmatively
expressed state directive "to replace competition with regulation."
Hoover, 466 U.S. at
466 U. S. 569.
However, the mere fact that a municipality acts within its
delegated authority is not sufficient to exclude its
anticompetitive behavior from the reach of the Sherman Act.
Page 499 U. S. 391
"Acceptance of such a proposition -- that the general grant of
power to enact ordinances necessarily implies state authorization
to enact specific anticompetitive ordinances -- would wholly
eviscerate the concepts of 'clear articulation and affirmative
expression' that our precedents require."
Community Communications Co. v. Boulder, 455 U. S.
40,
455 U. S. 56
(1982).
Accordingly, we have held that the critical decision to
substitute economic regulation for competition is one that must be
made by the State. That decision must be articulated with
sufficient clarity to identify the industry in which the State
intends that economic regulation shall replace competition. The
terse statement of the reason why the municipality's actions in
Hallie v. Eau Claire, 471 U. S. 34
(1985), was exempt from the Sherman Act illustrates the point:
"They were taken pursuant to a clearly articulated state policy
to replace competition in the provision of sewage services with
regulation."
Id. at
471 U. S. 47.
[
Footnote 2/5]
Page 499 U. S. 392
III
Today the Court adopts a significant enlargement of the state
action exemption. The South Carolina statutes that confer zoning
authority on municipalities in the State do not articulate any
state policy to displace competition with economic regulation in
any line of commerce or in any specific industry. As the Court
notes, the state statutes were expressly adopted to promote the
"
health, safety, morals or the general welfare of the
community,'" see ante at 499 U. S. 370,
n. 3. Like Colorado's grant of "home rule" powers to the city of
Boulder, they are simply neutral on the question whether the
municipality should displace competition with economic regulation
in any industry. There is not even an arguable basis for concluding
that the State authorized the city of Columbia to enter into
exclusive agreements with any person, or to use the zoning power to
protect favored citizens from competition. [Footnote 2/6] Nevertheless, under the guise of
acting
Page 499 U. S. 393
pursuant to a state legislative grant to regulate health,
safety, and welfare, the city of Columbia in this case enacted an
ordinance that amounted to economic regulation of the billboard
market; as the Court recognizes, the ordinance "obviously benefited
COA, which already had its billboards in place . . . [and] severely
hindered Omni's ability to compete."
Ante at
499 U. S.
368.
Concededly, it is often difficult to differentiate economic
regulation from municipal regulation of health, safety, and
welfare. "Social and safety regulation have economic impacts, and
economic regulation has social and safety effects." D. Hjelmfelt,
Antitrust and Regulated Industries 3 (1985). It is nevertheless
important to determine when purported general welfare regulation in
fact constitutes economic regulation by its purpose and effect of
displacing competition.
"An example of economic regulation which is disguised by another
stated purpose is the limitation of advertising by lawyers for the
stated purpose of protecting the public from incompetent lawyers.
Also, economic regulation posing as safety regulation is often
encountered in the health care industry."
Id. at 3-4.
In this case, the jury found that the city's ordinance --
ostensibly one promoting health, safety, and welfare -- was in fact
enacted pursuant to an agreement between city officials and a
private party to restrict competition. In my opinion, such a
finding necessarily leads to the conclusion that the city's
ordinance was fundamentally a form of economic regulation of the
billboard market, rather than a general welfare regulation having
incidental anticompetitive effects. Because I believe our cases
have wisely held that the decision to embark upon economic
regulation is a nondelegable one that must expressly be made by the
State in the context of a specific industry in order to qualify for
state action immunity,
see, e.g., Olsen v. Smith,
195 U. S. 332
(1904) (Texas pilotage
Page 499 U. S. 394
statutes expressly regulated both entry and rates in the Port of
Galveston);
Parker v. Brown, 317 U.
S. 341 (1943) (California statute expressly authorized
the raisin market regulatory program), I would hold that the city
of Columbia's economic regulation of the billboard market pursuant
to a general state grant of zoning power is not exempt from
antitrust scrutiny. [
Footnote
2/7]
Underlying the Court's reluctance to find the city of Columbia's
enactment of the billboard ordinance pursuant to a private
agreement to constitute unauthorized economic regulation is the
Court's fear that subjecting the motivations and effects of
municipal action to antitrust scrutiny will result in public
decisionmaking being "made subject to
ex post facto
judicial assessment of
the public interest.'" Ante at
499 U. S. 377.
That fear, in turn, rests on the assumption that "it is both
inevitable and desirable that public officials often agree to do
what one or another group of private citizens urges upon them."
Ante at 499 U. S.
375.
The Court's assumption that an agreement between private parties
and public officials is an "inevitable" precondition for official
action, however, is simply wrong. [
Footnote 2/8] Indeed, I am
Page 499 U. S. 395
persuaded that such agreements are the exception, rather than
the rule, and that they are, and should be, disfavored. The mere
fact that an official body adopts a position that is advocated by a
private lobbyist is plainly not sufficient to establish an
agreement to do so.
See Fisher v. Berkeley, 475 U.
S. 260,
475 U. S.
266-267 (1986);
cf. Theatre Enterprises, Inc. v.
Paramount Film Distributing Corp., 346 U.
S. 537,
346 U. S. 541
(1954). Nevertheless, in many circumstances, it would seem
reasonable to infer -- as the jury did in this case -- that the
official action is the product of an agreement intended to elevate
particular private interests over the general good.
In this case, the city took two separate actions that protected
the local monopolist from threatened competition. It first declared
a moratorium on any new billboard construction, despite the city
attorney's advice that the city had no power to do so. When the
moratorium was invalidated in state court litigation, it was
replaced with an apparently valid ordinance that clearly had the
effect of creating formidable barriers to entry in the billboard
market. Throughout the city's decisionmaking process in enacting
the various ordinances, undisputed evidence demonstrated that
Columbia Outdoor Advertising had met with city officials privately
as well as publicly. As the Court of Appeals noted:
"Implicit in the jury verdict was a finding that the city was
not acting pursuant to the direction or purposes of the South
Carolina statutes, but conspired solely to further COA's commercial
purposes to the detriment of competition in the billboard
industry."
891 F.2d 1127, 1133 (CA4 1989).
Judges who are closer to the trial process than we are do not
share the Court's fear that juries are not capable of recognizing
the difference between independent municipal action and action
taken for the sole purpose of carrying out an
Page 499 U. S. 396
anticompetitive agreement for the private party. [
Footnote 2/9]
See, e.g., In re Japanese
Electronic Products Antitrust Litigation, 631 F.2d 1069, 1079
(CA3 1980) ("The law presumes that a jury will find facts and reach
a verdict by rational means. It does not contemplate scientific
precision, but does contemplate a resolution of each issue on the
basis of a fair and reasonable assessment of the evidence and a
fair and reasonable application of the relevant legal rules").
Indeed, the problems inherent in determining whether the actions of
municipal officials are the product of an illegal agreement are
substantially the same as those arising in cases in which the
actions of business executives are subjected to antitrust scrutiny.
[
Footnote 2/10]
Page 499 U. S. 397
The difficulty of proving whether an agreement motivated a
course of conduct should not, in itself, intimidate this Court into
exempting those illegal agreements that are proven by convincing
evidence. Rather, the Court should, if it must, attempt to deal
with these problems of proof as it has in the past -- through
heightened evidentiary standards, rather than through judicial
expansion of exemptions from the Sherman Act.
See, e.g.,
Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp.,
475 U. S. 574
(1986) (allowing summary judgment where evidence of a predatory
pricing conspiracy in violation of the Sherman Act was founded
largely upon circumstantial evidence);
Monsanto Co. v.
Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U. S. 752,
465 U. S. 768
(1984) (holding that a plaintiff in a vertical price-fixing case
must produce evidence which "tends to exclude the possibility of
independent action").
Unfortunately, the Court's decision today converts what should
be nothing more than an anticompetitive agreement undertaken by a
municipality that enjoys no special status in our federalist system
into a lawful exercise of public decisionmaking. Although the Court
correctly applies principles of federalism in refusing to find a
"conspiracy exception" to the
Parker state action doctrine
when a State acts in a nonproprietary capacity, it errs in
extending the state action exemption to municipalities that enter
into private anticompetitive agreements under the guise of acting
pursuant to a general state grant of authority to regulate health,
safety, and welfare. Unlike the previous limitations this Court has
imposed on Congress' sweeping mandate in § 1, which found support
in our common law traditions or our system of federalism,
see 499
U.S. 365fn2/1|>n. 1,
supra, the Court's wholesale
exemption of municipal action from antitrust scrutiny amounts to
little more than a bold and disturbing act of judicial
legislation
Page 499 U. S. 398
which dramatically curtails the statutory prohibition against
"every" contract in restraint of trade. [
Footnote 2/11]
IV
Just as I am convinced that municipal "lawmaking that has been
infected by selfishly motivated agreement with private interests,"
ante at
499 U. S. 383,
is not authorized by a grant of zoning authority, and therefore not
within the state action exemption, so am I persuaded that a private
party's agreement with selfishly motivated public officials is
sufficient to remove the antitrust immunity that protects private
lobbying under
Eastern Railroad Presidents Conference v. Noerr
Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U. S. 127
(1961), and
Mine Workers v. Pennington, 381 U.
S. 657 (1965). Although I agree that the "sham"
exception to the
Noerr-Pennington rule exempting lobbying
activities from the antitrust laws does not apply to the private
petitioner's conduct in this case for the reasons stated by the
Court in
499 U. S. I am
satisfied that the evidence in the record is sufficient to support
the jury's finding that a conspiracy existed between the private
party and the municipal officials in this case, so as to remove the
private petitioner's conduct from the scope of
Noerr-Pennington antitrust immunity. Accordingly, I would
affirm
Page 499 U. S. 399
the judgment of the Court of Appeals as to both the city of
Columbia and Columbia Outdoor Advertising.
I respectfully dissent.
[
Footnote 2/1]
Construing the statute in the light of the common law concerning
contracts in restraint of trade, we have concluded that only
unreasonable restraints are prohibited.
"One problem presented by the language of § 1 of the Sherman Act
is that it cannot mean what it says. The statute says that 'every'
contract that restrains trade is unlawful. But, as Mr. Justice
Brandeis perceptively noted, restraint is the very essence of every
contract; read literally, § 1 would outlaw the entire body of
private contract law. Yet it is that body of law that establishes
the enforceability of commercial agreements and enables competitive
markets -- indeed, a competitive economy -- to function
effectively."
"Congress, however, did not intend the text of the Sherman Act
to delineate the full meaning of the statute or its application in
concrete situations. The legislative history makes it perfectly
clear that it expected the courts to give shape to the statute's
broad mandate by drawing on common law tradition. The Rule of
Reason, with its origins in common law precedents long antedating
the Sherman Act, has served that purpose. . . [The Rule of Reason]
focuses directly on the challenged restraint's impact on
competitive conditions."
National Society of Professional Engineers v. United
States, 435 U. S. 679,
435 U. S.
687-688 (1978) (footnotes omitted). We have also
confined the Sherman Act's mandate by holding that the independent
actions of the sovereign States and their officials are not covered
by the language of the Act.
Parker v. Brown, 317 U.
S. 341 (1943).
[
Footnote 2/2]
The jury returned its verdict pursuant to the following
instructions given by the District Court:
"So if, by the evidence, you find that that person involved in
this case procured and brought about the passage of ordinances
solely for the purpose of hindering, delaying or otherwise
interfering with the access of the Plaintiff to the marketing area
involved in this case, and thereby conspired, then, of course,
their conduct would not be excused under the antitrust laws."
"So once again, an entity may engage in . . . legitimate
lobbying . . . to procure legislati[on] even if the motive behind
the lobbying is anticompetitive."
"If you find Defendants conspired together with the intent to
foreclose the Plaintiff from meaningful access to a legitimate
decisionmaking process with regard to the ordinances in question,
then your verdict would be for the Plaintiff on that issue."
App. 81.
[
Footnote 2/3]
"The Sherman Act reflects a legislative judgment that,
ultimately, competition will produce not only lower prices but also
better goods and services. 'The heart of our national economic
policy long has been faith in the value of competition.'
Standard Oil Co. v. FTC, 340 U. S. 231,
340 U. S.
248 (1951). The assumption that competition is the best
method of allocating resources in a free market recognizes that all
elements of a bargain -- quality, service, safety, and durability
-- and not just the immediate cost, are favorably affected by the
free opportunity to select among alternative offers. Even assuming
occasional exceptions to the presumed consequences of competition,
the statutory policy precludes inquiry into the question whether
competition is good or bad."
National Society of Professional Engineers, 435 U.S. at
435 U. S.
695.
[
Footnote 2/4]
In
Owen v. City of Independence, 445 U.
S. 622 (1980), this Court recognized that
"notwithstanding [42 U.S.C.] § 1983's expansive language and
absence of any express incorporation of common law immunities, we
have, on several occasions, found that a tradition of immunity was
so firmly rooted in the common law and was supported by such strong
policy reasons that 'Congress would have specifically so provided
had it wished to abolish the doctrine.'
Pierson v. Ray,
386 U. S.
547,
386 U. S. 555 (1967)."
Id. at
445 U. S. 637.
Nevertheless, the Court refused to find a firmly established
immunity enjoyed by municipal corporations at common law for the
torts of their agents.
"Where the immunity claimed by the defendant was well
established at common law at the time [42 U.S.C.] § 1983 was
enacted, and where its rationale was compatible with the purposes
of the Civil Rights Act, we have construed the statute to
incorporate that immunity. But there is no tradition of immunity
for municipal corporations, and neither history nor policy supports
a construction of § 1983 that would justify"
according them such immunity.
Id. at
445 U. S. 638.
See also Will v. Michigan Dept. of State Police,
491 U. S. 58,
491 U. S. 70
(1989) ("States are protected by the Eleventh Amendment, while
municipalities are not . . .").
[
Footnote 2/5]
Contrary to the Court's reading of
Hallie, our opinion
in that case emphasized the industry-specific character of the
Wisconsin legislation in explaining why the delegation satisfied
the "clear articulation" requirement. At issue in
Hallie
was the town's independent decision to refuse to provide sewage
treatment services to nearby towns -- a decision that had been
expressly authorized by the Wisconsin legislation. 471 U.S. at
471 U. S. 41. We
wrote:
"Applying the analysis of
Lafayette v. Louisiana Power &
Light Co., 435 U. S. 389 (1978), it is
sufficient that the statutes authorized the City to provide sewage
services and also to determine the areas to be served."
Id. 471 U.S. at
471 U. S.
42.
"Nor do we agree with the Towns' contention that the statutes at
issue here are neutral on state policy. The Towns' attempt to liken
the Wisconsin statutes to the Home Rule Amendment involved in
Boulder, arguing that the Wisconsin statutes are neutral
because they leave the City free to pursue either anticompetitive
conduct or free-market competition in the field of sewage services.
The analogy to the Home Rule Amendment involved in
Boulder
is inapposite. That Amendment to the Colorado Constitution
allocated only the most general authority to municipalities to
govern local affairs. We held that it was neutral, and did not
satisfy the 'clear articulation' component of the state action
test. The Amendment simply did not address the regulation of cable
television. Under home rule, the municipality was to be free to
decide every aspect of policy relating to cable television, as well
as policy relating to any other field of regulation of local
concern. Here, in contrast, the State has specifically authorized
Wisconsin cities to provide sewage services, and has delegated to
the cities the express authority to take action that foreseeably
will result in anticompetitive effects. No reasonable argument can
be made that these statutes are neutral in the same way that
Colorado's Home Rule Amendment was."
Id. 471 U.S. at
471 U. S.
43.
We rejected the argument that the delegation was insufficient
because it did not expressly mention the foreseeable
anticompetitive consequences of the city of Eau Claire's conduct,
but we surely did not hold that the mere fact that incidental
anticompetitive consequences are foreseeable is sufficient to
immunize otherwise unauthorized restrictive agreements between
cities and private parties.
[
Footnote 2/6]
The authority to regulate the "
location, height, bulk,
number of stories and size of buildings and other structures,'"
see ante at 499 U. S. 371,
n. 3 (citation omitted), may of course have an indirect effect on
the total output in the billboard industry, see ante at
499 U. S.
373-374, n. 4, as well as on a number of other
industries, but the Court surely misreads our cases when it implies
that a general grant of zoning power represents a clearly
articulated decision to authorize municipalities to enter into
agreements to displace competition in every industry that is
affected by zoning regulation.
[
Footnote 2/7]
A number of Courts of Appeals have held that a municipality
which exercises its zoning power to further a private agreement to
restrain trade is not entitled to state action immunity.
See,
e.g., Westborough Mall, Inc. v. Cape Girardeau, 693 F.2d 733,
746 (CA8 1982) ("Even if zoning in general can be characterized as
state action,' . . . a conspiracy to thwart normal zoning
procedures and to directly injure the plaintiffs by illegally
depriving them of their property is not in furtherance of any
clearly articulated state policy"); Whitworth v. Perkins,
559 F.2d 378, 379 (CA5 1977) ("The mere presence of the zoning
ordinance does not necessarily insulate the defendants from
antitrust liability where, as here, the plaintiff asserts that the
enactment of the ordinance was itself a part of the alleged
conspiracy to restrain trade").
[
Footnote 2/8]
No such agreement was involved in
Hallie v. Eau Claire,
471 U. S. 34
(1985). In that case, the plaintiffs challenged independent action
-- the determination of the service area of the city's sewage
system -- that had been expressly authorized by Wisconsin
legislation. The absence of any such agreement provided the basis
for our decision in
Fisher v. Berkeley, 475 U.
S. 260,
475 U. S.
266-267 (1986) ("[t]he distinction between unilateral
and concerted action is critical here . . . [t]hus, if the Berkeley
Ordinance stabilizes rents without this element of concerted
action, the program it establishes cannot run afoul of § 1").
[
Footnote 2/9]
The instructions in this case, fairly read, told the jury that
the plaintiff should not prevail unless the ordinance was enacted
for the sole purpose of interfering with access to the market.
See 499
U.S. 365fn2/2|>n. 2,
supra. Thus, this case is an
example of one of the "polar extremes,"
see ante at
499 U. S. 375,
n. 5, that juries -- as well as Solomon -- can readily identify.
The mixed motive cases that concern the Court should present no
problem if juries are given instructions comparable to those given
below. When the Court describes my position as assuming that
municipal action that was not prompted "exclusively by a concern
for the general public interest" is enough to create antitrust
liability,
ibid. it simply ignores the requirement that
the plaintiff must prove that the municipal action is the product
of an anticompetitive agreement with private parties. Contrary to
our square holding in
Fisher v. Berkeley, 475 U.
S. 260 (1986), today the Court seems to assume that
municipal action which is not entirely immune from antitrust
scrutiny will automatically violate the antitrust laws.
[
Footnote 2/10]
"There are many obstacles to discovering conspiracies, but the
most frequent difficulties are three. First, price-fixers and
similar miscreants seldom admit their conspiracy or agree in the
open. Often, we can infer the agreement only from their behavior.
Second, behavior can sometimes be coordinated without any
communication or other observable and reprehensible behavior.
Third, the causal connection between an observable, controllable
act -- such as a solicitation or meeting -- and subsequent parallel
action may be obscure."
6 P. Areeda, Antitrust Law � 1400, at 3-4 (1986).
See
also Turner, The Definition of Agreement under the Sherman
Act: Conscious Parallelism and Refusals to Deal, 75 Harv.L.Rev. 655
(1962) (discussing difficulties of condemning parallel
anticompetitive action absent explicit agreement among the
parties).
[
Footnote 2/11]
As the Court previously has noted:
"In 1972, there were 62,437 different units of local government
in this country. Of this number 23,885 were special districts which
had a defined goal or goals for the provision of one or several
services, while the remaining 38,552 represented the number of
counties, municipalities, and townships, most of which have broad
authority for general governance subject to limitations in one way
or another imposed by the State. These units may, and do,
participate in and affect the economic life of this Nation in a
great number and variety of ways. When these bodies act as owners
and providers of services, they are fully capable of aggrandizing
other economic units with which they interrelate, with the
potential of serious distortion of the rational and efficient
allocation of resources, and the efficiency of free markets which
the regime of competition embodied in the antitrust laws is thought
to engender."
Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light Co.,
435 U. S. 389,
435 U. S.
407-408 (1978) (footnotes omitted).