The fourth paragraph of § 8 of the Clayton Act provides that
"[n]o person at the same time shall be a director in any two or
more corporations, any one of which has capital, surplus, and
undivided profits aggregating more than $1,000,000, engaged in
whole or in part in commerce, other than banks, banking
associations, trust companies, and common carriers,"
if such corporations are competitors. The United States brought
test cases, consolidated in Federal District Court, against
petitioners, certain banks, bank holding companies, mutual life
insurance companies, and individuals who each served on the board
of directors of one of the banks or bank holding companies and one
of the insurance companies. It was stipulated that the interlocked
banks and insurance companies compete in the interstate market for
mortgage and real estate loans. The Government asserted that the
interlocking directorates violated the fourth paragraph of § 8,
arguing that the "other than banks" clause simply prevented
overlapping regulation of interlocks between banks, which are
separately regulated in the first three paragraphs of § 8. The
District Court entered summary judgment for petitioners, holding
that the statutory proscription applies only to two corporations,
neither of which is a bank. The Court of Appeals reversed.
Held: The fourth paragraph of § 8 does not bar
interlocking directorates between a bank and a competing insurance
company. Pp.
462 U. S.
126-140.
(a) The most natural reading of the language of the statute is
that the interlocked corporations must all be corporations "other
than banks," and that thus the fourth paragraph of § 8 does not, by
its express terms, prohibit interlocking directorates between a
bank and a competing nonbanking corporation. This reading of the
statute is reinforced both by the structure of the Clayton Act and
by the structure of the fourth paragraph of § 8. Pp.
462 U. S.
128-130.
(b) Great weight is to be given to the contemporaneous
interpretation of a challenged statute by an agency charged with
its enforcement, but, for over 60 years prior to its present
interpretation of § 8, the Government made no attempt to apply the
statute to interlocks between banks and insurance companies, even
though such interlocks were widespread and a matter of public
record throughout the period. Mere failure of administrative
agencies to act is in no sense a binding administrative
Page 462 U. S. 123
interpretation that the Government lacks the authority to act,
but, in the circumstances of this case, the Government's failure
for over 60 years to exercise the power it now claims strongly
suggests that it did not read § 8 as granting such power. Moreover,
the business community directly affected, the enforcing agencies,
and the Congress all have read the statute the same way for 60
years, thus strongly supporting the conclusion that Congress
intended § 8 to be interpreted according to its plain meaning. Pp.
462 U. S.
130-133.
(c) If any doubt remains as to the meaning of the statute, that
doubt is removed by the legislative history. The evolution of the
bill, along with the remarks in committee and on the floor, rebuts
the Government's claim that Congress intended to reach bank-nonbank
interlocks in the fourth paragraph of § 8. Pp.
462 U. S.
133-140.
656 F.2d 428, reversed.
BURGER, C.J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
BLACKMUN, REHNQUIST, STEVENS, and O'CONNOR, JJ., joined. WHITE, J.,
filed a dissenting opinion, in which BRENNAN and MARSHALL, JJ.,
joined,
post, p.
462 U. S. 140.
POWELL, J., took no part in the decision of the case.
CHIEF JUSTICE BURGER delivered the opinion of the Court:
The question presented is whether § 8 of the Clayton Act bars
interlocking directorates between a bank and a competing insurance
company.
Page 462 U. S. 124
I
In 1975, the United States brought these companion test cases
(now consolidated) against 10 corporations and 5 individuals. The
corporations were three banks and their three respective holding
companies, and four mutual life insurance companies. The five
individuals each served on the board of directors of one of the
banks or bank holding companies and one of the insurance companies.
It was stipulated that the interlocked banks and insurance
companies compete in the interstate market for mortgage and real
estate loans.
The Government asserts that interlocking directorates between
banks and insurance companies violate § 8 of the Clayton Act, 38
Stat. 732, as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 19. The fourth paragraph of § 8,
on which the Government relies, provides:
"No person at the same time shall be a director in
any two
or more corporations, any one of which has capital, surplus,
and undivided profits aggregating more than $1,000,000, engaged in
whole or in part in commerce,
other than banks, banking
associations, trust companies, and common carriers subject to
the Act to regulate commerce, approved February fourth, eighteen
hundred and eighty-seven, if such corporations are or shall have
been theretofore, by virtue of their business and location of
operation, competitors, so that the elimination of competition by
agreement between them would constitute a violation of any of the
provisions of any of the antitrust laws."
(Emphasis added.) In short, this statute forbids a person to
serve simultaneously on the boards of directors of two or more
corporations that meet certain specifications, namely, that the
corporations be engaged in commerce, at least one of them having
capital, surplus, and undivided profits worth more than $1 million,
that they be competitors, and that they be
Page 462 U. S. 125
"other than banks, banking associations, trust companies, and
common carriers. . . ."
According to the Government, the language "[n]o person at the
same time shall be a director in any two or more corporations . . .
other than banks" prohibits interlocking directorates between any
two or more competing corporations, but excludes from this general
prohibition interlocking directorates between banks. The Government
argues that the purpose of the "other than banks" clause was simply
to prevent overlapping regulation of interlocks between banks,
which are separately regulated in the first three paragraphs of §
8. Thus, it interprets the fourth paragraph of § 8 to reach
interlocks between banks and nonbanks, which interlocks are
otherwise unregulated. Petitioners respond that the "other than
banks" clause expressly excludes interlocking directorates
involving banks from the scope of the fourth paragraph of § 8.
On cross-motions for summary judgment, the United States
District Court for the Northern District of California granted
summary judgment for petitioners and dismissed the Government's
suits.
United States v. Crocker National
Corp., 422 F.
Supp. 686 (1976). The District Court held:
"[A] normal reading of the statutory language 'two . . .
corporations . . . other than banks' compels the conclusion that
the statute applies only to two corporations, neither of which is a
bank."
* * * *
"[A]n ordinary reading of the statutory prohibition '[n]o person
. . . shall [serve as] a director in any two or more corporations .
. . other than banks' means that banks were not to be subject to
this prohibition."
Id. at 689-690. Although the District Court saw no need
for further factual inquiry in light of the "clear statutory
language,"
id. at 690, it observed that this
interpretation of the statute was
"confirmed by 60 years of administrative and Congressional
interpretation,
Page 462 U. S. 126
as well as by the legislative history underlying section 8."
Id. at 703.
A divided Court of Appeals reversed.
United States v.
Crocker National Corp., 656 F.2d 428 (CA9 1981). Unlike the
District Court, the majority viewed the statutory language as
ambiguous. It stated that the "other than banks" clause could be
interpreted equally plausibly to mean either "two or more
corporations [none of which are] banks," or "two or more
corporations [not all of which are] banks."
Id. at 434
(emphasis deleted). Relying chiefly on its view of the underlying
policy of the Clayton Act, the Court of Appeals held that the
fourth paragraph of § 8 should be interpreted to bar all
interlocking directorates between banks and competing nonbanking
corporations.
In the view of the Court of Appeals, petitioners' position left
a "gap" in the coverage of § 8. Discerning nothing in the
legislative history directly bearing on the applicability of § 8 to
interlocking directorates between banks and nonbanking
corporations, the Court of Appeals relied on the broad purpose of
Congress to condemn "interlocking directorates between large
competing corporations,"
id. at 439, as support for an
interpretation of § 8 leaving no "loopholes." It thus interpreted
the "other than banks" language to refer back to the interlocks
between banks regulated in the preceding paragraphs of § 8; this
interpretation left interlocking directorates between banks and
nonbanks subject to the general bar of the fourth paragraph of § 8.
[
Footnote 1]
We granted certiorari, 456 U.S. 1005 (1982), and we reverse.
II
The Clayton Act of 1914 was passed in a period when Congress was
focusing on the perceived evils of corporate
Page 462 U. S. 127
bigness and monopoly. President Wilson, for example, had made
the "trusts" a core issue of his 1912 campaign; Congress followed
up with the Pujo Committee investigation into the investment
banking trust.
See generally Travers, Interlocks in
Corporate Management and the Antitrust Laws, 46 Texas L.Rev. 819,
824-829 (1968). Interlocks between large corporations were seen in
the public debate as
per se antagonistic to the public
interest; many, including President Wilson, called for legislation
that would, among other things, ban all kinds of interlocks.
Interlocks were condemned regardless of whether the relationship
between the corporations was horizontal or vertical; whether it was
accomplished through the sharing of personnel, including directors
and officers; or whether it was achieved through interlocking stock
holdings or other indirect forms of domination.
See, e.g.,
S.Rep. No. 698, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., 15 (1914); Hearings on Trust
Legislation before the House Committee on the Judiciary, 63d Cong.,
2d Sess., 816, 818-820, 823, 925 (1914) (hereafter Trust Hearings).
Plainly, these were policy matters appropriate for Congress to
resolve.
However, when the Clayton Act was enacted, its scope was
considerably less comprehensive than many of the proposals pressed
upon Congress. Rather than enacting a broad scheme to ban all
interlocks between potential competitors, Congress approached the
problem of interlocks selectively, limiting both the classes of
corporations and the kinds of interlocks subject to regulation.
Three classes of business organizations are regulated by the
Clayton Act's provisions concerning corporate interlocks, and each
class is subject to different restraints. Clayton Act §§ 8 and 10,
15 U.S.C. §§ 19 and 20. Section 10 regulates, but does not
prohibit, certain types of interlocks between common carriers and
various other corporations with which the carrier has a supplier or
customer relationship; it does not regulate horizontal interlocks
between competing common carriers. The first three paragraphs of §
8 regulate interlocks
Page 462 U. S. 128
between banks and trust companies that meet certain geographic
and other requirements. These provisions bar a wide range of
personnel interlocks, including common directors, officers, and
employees. The fourth paragraph of § 8 concerns the class of
competing corporations "other than banks, banking associations,
trust companies, and common carriers"; it prohibits only shared
directors between competing corporations, and does not bar any
other kind of personnel interlock or any kind of vertical
interlock. It is against this pattern of specific and limited
regulation of corporate interlocks that we approach the narrow
statutory question presented.
The starting point, as always, is the language of the statute.
The narrow question here is whether the fourth paragraph of § 8 of
the Clayton Act bars interlocking directorates involving a bank and
a nonbanking corporation with which it competes. The language of
the statute is unambiguous in prohibiting interlocking directorates
between "two or more corporations . . . other than banks." The most
natural reading of this language is that the interlocked
corporations must all be corporations "other than banks." It is
self-evident that a bank and a nonbanking corporation are not both
corporations "other than banks." Thus, the fourth paragraph of § 8,
by its express terms, does not prohibit interlocking directorates
between a bank and a competing nonbanking corporation. This reading
of the statute is reinforced both by the structure of the Clayton
Act and by the structure of the fourth paragraph of § 8.
The Clayton Act selectively regulates interlocks with respect to
three different classes of business organizations: those interlocks
between banks are covered in the first three paragraphs of § 8 and
those interlocks involving common carriers are covered by § 10.
Viewed in this framework, the purpose of the "other than" clause in
the fourth paragraph of § 8 was to exclude altogether interlocking
directorates involving either banks or common carriers. Moreover,
this interpretation
Page 462 U. S. 129
is the only one consistent with the treatment of "common
carriers" in the "other than" clause.
The Government does not dispute that the language "two or more
corporations . . . other than banks [or] common carriers"
completely excludes from the fourth paragraph any interlocking
directorates in which any of the corporations involved is a common
carrier; it should follow, logically, that it also excludes
interlocking directorates involving banks. Put another way, the
language "two or more corporations . . . other than banks [or]
common carriers" means "two or more corporations
none of which
is a common carrier." To be consistent, that language must
also be interpreted to mean "two or more corporations
none of
which is a bank."
In our view, it strains the meaning of ordinary words to read
"two or more corporations other than
common carriers" to
mean something completely different from "two or more corporations
other than
banks," as the Court of Appeals did. 656 F.2d
at 442-443. In
Mohasco Corp. v. Silver, 447 U.
S. 807,
447 U. S. 826
(1980), for example, we rejected as unreasonable the claim that the
word "filed" could have two different meanings in two separate
subsections of the same statute. Similarly, we reject as
unreasonable the contention that Congress intended the phrase
"other than" to mean one thing when applied to "banks" and another
thing as applied to "common carriers," where the phrase "other
than" modifies both words in the same clause.
The language of the fourth paragraph of § 8 supports this
interpretation. The fourth paragraph begins with a general bar
against interlocking directorates: "No person at the same time
shall be a director in any two or more corporations." This general
bar is limited by four separate clauses, each of which modifies the
phrase "two or more corporations." That is, the statute applies
only to "two or more corporations" which satisfy these four
additional requirements. Clearly, the first clause need be
satisfied by only one of the interlocked corporations. By its own
terms, it applies to "any
Page 462 U. S. 130
one" of the "two or more corporations." None of the other
clauses contain similar language. Rather, they are all written in
general language that applies to all the interlocked corporations.
Had Congress wished the "other than banks" clause to apply to only
one of the interlocked corporations, it would not have presented
any difficulty to have said so explicitly as in the first
clause.
In rejecting the Government's present interpretation of § 8, we
by no means depart from our long-held policy of giving great weight
to the contemporaneous interpretation of a challenged statute by an
agency charged with its enforcement,
e.g., 25 U.
S. Darby, 12 Wheat. 206,
25 U. S. 210
(1827). But the Government does not come to this case with a
consistent history of enforcing or attempting to enforce § 8 in
accord with what it urges now. On the contrary, for over 60 years,
the Government made no attempt, either by filing suit or by seeking
voluntary resignations, to apply § 8 to interlocks between banks
and nonbanking corporations, even though interlocking directorates
between banks and insurance companies were widespread and a matter
of public record throughout the period. [
Footnote 2] We find it difficult to believe that the
Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, which share
authority for enforcement of the Clayton Act, and the Congress,
which oversees those agencies, would have overlooked or ignored the
pervasive and open
Page 462 U. S. 131
practice of interlocking directorates between banks and
insurance companies had it been thought contrary to the law.
[
Footnote 3]
It is true, of course, that "[a]uthority actually granted by
Congress . . . cannot evaporate through lack of administrative
exercise,"
FTC v. Bunte Brothers, Inc., 312 U.
S. 349,
312 U. S. 352
(1941); the mere failure of administrative agencies to act is in no
sense "a binding administrative interpretation" that the Government
lacks the authority to act.
United States v. E. I. du Pont de
Nemours & Co., 353 U. S. 586,
353 U. S. 590
(1957). However,
"just as established practice may shed light on the extent of
power conveyed by general statutory language, so the want of
assertion of power by those who presumably would be alert to
exercise it is equally significant in determining whether such
power was actually conferred."
FTC v. Bunte Brothers, Inc., supra, at
312 U. S. 352.
Similarly, in
FPC v. Panhandle Eastern Pipe Line Co.,
337 U. S. 498,
337 U. S. 513
(1949), this Court held that "[f]ailure to use such an important
power for so long a time indicates to us that the Commission did
not believe the power existed." In the circumstances of this case,
the Government's failure for over 60 years to exercise the power it
now claims under § 8 strongly suggests that it did not read the
statute as granting such power.
When a court reaches the same reading of the statute as the
practical construction given it by the enforcing agencies
Page 462 U. S. 132
over a 60-year span, that is a powerful weight supporting such
reading. Here, moreover, the business community directly affected
and the enforcing agencies
and the Congress have
read this statute the same way for 60 years. It is not wholly
without significance that Members of Congress and their staffs who
have written about this issue have stated that § 8
"does not apply to interlocks between commercial banks and
competing financial institutions, such as mutual savings banks,
insurance companies, and small loan companies."
Letter from Rep. Wright Patman to Hon. Arthur F. Burns, Chairman
of the Federal Reserve Board (June 1, 1970), reprinted in The
Banking Reform Act of 1971: Hearings on H.R. 5700 before the House
Committee on Banking and Currency, 92d Cong., 1st Sess., 271
(1971). [
Footnote 4] While
these views are not binding on this Court, the weight of informed
opinion [
Footnote 5] over the
years strongly supports the District Court holding that Congress
intended the statute to be interpreted according to its plain
meaning.
It is not surprising that, for more than a half century,
literally thousands of citizens in the business world have served
as directors of both banks and insurance companies in reliance
Page 462 U. S. 133
on what was universally perceived as plain statutory language.
These citizens were reassured that the Government's reading of that
language indicated that their conduct was lawful. The Government
brushes this aside, saying in effect that it will not bring suits
against those directors who resign within a reasonable time. Tr. of
Oral Arg. 30-31. However, those who elect to resign under this
"amnesty" would nonetheless carry a stigma of sorts as violators of
federal laws. Equally, and perhaps more, important, such persons
face possible civil liability in unknown amounts, liability against
which the Government cannot, and does not purport to, render them
immune.
See id. at 30. While it is arguable that wise
antitrust policy counsels against permitting interlocking
directorates between banks and competing insurance companies, that
policy must be implemented by Congress, and not by a crabbed
interpretation of the words of a statute which so many in authority
have interpreted in accordance with its plain meaning for so long.
If changes in economic factors or considerations of public policy
counsel the extension of the Clayton Act to the categories of
interlocking directorates implicated here, it is a simple matter
for Congress to say so clearly.
If any doubt remains as to the meaning of the statute, that
doubt is removed by the legislative history. The relevant
provisions of the Clayton Act went through four legislative stages:
(1) the initial "tentative bill," (2) the House bill introduced by
Representative Clayton, (3) the Senate amendments, and (4) the
final bill of the Joint Conference Committee which was enacted into
law as the Clayton Act. The evolution of the bill, along with the
remarks in Committee and on the floor, rebuts the Government's
claim that Congress intended to reach bank-nonbank interlocks in
the fourth paragraph of § 8.
The tentative bill proposed by Representative Clayton had three
sections dealing with director interlocks. Reprinted in Trust
Hearings, at 1577-1579. Section 1 prohibited certain
Page 462 U. S. 134
director and officer interlocks between railroads and specified
other corporations, including banks. Section 2 prohibited certain
interlocks between banks. Section 4, the precursor to the current
paragraph 4 of § 8, presumed a violation of the Sherman Act from
the existence of a director interlock. It provided, in pertinent
part:
"That if . . . any two or more corporations, engaged in whole or
in part in interstate or foreign commerce, have a common director
or directors, the fact of such common director or directors shall
be conclusive evidence that there exists no real competition
between such corporations; and if such corporations shall have been
theretofore, or are, or shall have been . . . natural competitors,
such elimination of competition thus conclusively presumed shall
constitute a combination between the said corporations in restraint
of interstate or foreign commerce. . . ."
Id. at 1579.
Extensive hearings were held on this "tentative bill." Louis D.
Brandeis, then an adviser to President Wilson, testified that the
tentative bill was inadequate to meet what he saw as the need for a
broad prohibition against vertical as well as horizontal
interlocks.
See generally id. at 681-688. Representative
Carlin objected:
"We attempted to do that by section 4 of the bill. Section 1
deals with the railroads, section 2 with the banks, and section 4
with industrials."
Id. at 681. Brandeis responded that "as you have
section 4 there, your clause is limited to a linking together of
two industrial corporations who are competitors. . . ."
Ibid.
Brandeis also testified to the need to prohibit interlocking
directorates between all large banks.
Id. at 921-925. He
argued that Congress had the power to do this, since "banking is
interstate commerce."
Id. at 923-924. He then turned from
the banks to the "other financial concern doing business
Page 462 U. S. 135
in the same place" with which the interlocking directorates
should be, but were not under the tentative bill, prohibited:
"Mr. BRANDEIS: . . . Now what is a financial concern as I have
used that term? I should say that term 'financial concern' includes
not only a bank which is a member of a national reserve system but
any other bank."
"Mr. VOLSTEAD: Would you include an insurance company?"
"Mr. BRANDEIS: And an insurance company also. It seems to me
that
both banks and insurance companies, which have a usual
place of business in the same place, . . . ought to be included in
that prohibition."
Id. at 925 (emphasis added). Two facts emerge from this
exchange. First, the tentative bill dealt with the different
classes of corporations (banks, railroads, and industrials)
separately and in different ways. Section 2 dealt exclusively with
banks, and § 4 exclusively with industrial corporations. Second,
the tentative bill was not understood as prohibiting interlocking
directorates between banks and "other financial concern[s] doing
business in the same place" such as insurance companies.
At the conclusion of the hearings, Representative Clayton
introduced H.R. 15657, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. (May 2, 1914), reprinted
in Trust Hearings, at 1931-1952, which eventually was enacted as
the Clayton Act. Section 9 of that bill generally paralleled the
structure of the current § 8. The third paragraph of § 9 (which
became the fourth paragraph of the present § 8) provided in
pertinent part:
"[N]o person at the same time shall be a director in any two or
more corporations, either of which has capital, surplus, and
undivided profits aggregating more than $1,000,000, engaged in
whole or in part in commerce,
other than common carriers
subject to [the Interstate Commerce Act]. . . ."
(Emphasis added.)
Page 462 U. S. 136
The Committee Report on this bill stated that
"[t]his section is divided into three paragraphs, each of which
relates to the particular class of corporations described, and the
provisions of each paragraph are limited in their application to
the corporations belonging to the class named herein."
H.R.Rep. No. 627, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., 18 (1914), reprinted in
Trust Hearings at 1970. The first paragraph related solely to the
"eligibility of directors in interstate railroad corporations,"
ibid.; the second paragraph dealt with the "eligibility of
directors, officers, and employees of banks, banking associations,
and trust companies,"
id. at 1971; and the third,
"industrial corporations" paragraph concerned "the eligibility of
directors in industrial corporations engaged in commerce,"
ibid. Nothing in this Report suggests that the third
paragraph was intended to deal with directors in banks who also
serve as directors in industrial corporations.
The House debates on § 9 of H.R. 15657 confirm that Congress
intended to deal separately with banks, railroads, and industrial
corporations, and did not intend the third paragraph of § 9 to
regulate or prohibit interlocks between these different classes of
corporations. During a debate over the banking provisions of § 9,
Representative Cullop explained the relationship of the industrial
corporations paragraph to the banking paragraphs:
"That [industrial corporations paragraph] refers to some other
corporation than a bank. That does not apply to a bank."
* * * *
"This has no reference to the banking business."
"Mr. CARLIN: That relates to industrial commerce."
"Mr. CULLOP: Yes. That does not relate to banking. That relates
to industrial and commercial corporations, or institutions of that
kind, but
has no reference whatsoever to the banking
business."
51 Cong.Rec. 9604 (1914) (emphasis added).
The House passed H.R. 15657 with changes not relevant here and
sent the bill to the Senate. There, the provisions
Page 462 U. S. 137
regulating bank interlocks met with considerable opposition and
were ultimately eliminated by the Senate Committee on the
Judiciary. The Senate Report explained:
"A Senate amendment to this section strikes out the entire
paragraph which relates to interlocking directorates of banks and
trust companies [the first three paragraphs of the current § 8]. In
proposing this amendment, a majority of the Committee believed that
such legislation as this more properly belongs to the domain of
banking, rather than of commerce, and such additional regulation of
bank directorates as may be wise and just should be made by
amendments to the national bank acts, and the enforcement of it
given to the Comptroller of the Currency and the Federal Reserve
Board."
S.Rep. No. 698, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., 48 (1914). However, the
Senate Committee did not change the industrial corporations
paragraph at all:
"The House provision in this section relating to interlocking
directorates of industrial corporations is not proposed to be
changed or amended in any respect."
Ibid. The Senate passed the bill as reported out by the
Senate Committee.
Given the Senate's expressed intent not to regulate bank
interlocks, it is not reasonable to believe that the Senate
understood the third paragraph of § 9, which it left untouched, to
bar interlocking directorates involving banks. When the Conference
Committee met to iron out differences between the House and Senate
bills, it restored the banking provisions but added the words
"other than banks, banking associations, trust companies" to the
"other than common carriers" clause in the industrial corporations
paragraph (which became the fourth paragraph of the current § 8).
The most reasonable explanation for this addition is that it
clarified what the Senate already understood to be the case: the
industrial corporations paragraph did not reach interlocking
directorates involving banks.
This interpretation is supported by the floor debate in the
House on the Conference bill. Of those who spoke on the
Page 462 U. S. 138
House floor, only Representative Mann thought that the original
House version of the industrial corporations paragraph (§ 9,
paragraph 3, of H.R. 15657) applied to interlocking directorates
with banks. He objected that the amendment adding "banks" to the
"other than common carriers" clause therefore materially changed
the meaning of the fourth paragraph:
"I know of nothing more vital which was before the House than
the power and the right to prevent interlocking directorates of
banks. . . . That was one of the basic things that the committee
made findings on, and when this bill was prepared, it provided a
prohibition against interlocking directorates of banks. The House
passed it in that shape. The Senate passed it in that shape. But
the House conferees, without authority . . . have provided that
banks shall no longer be controlled by this prohibition of
interlocking directorates where banks are in competition."
51 Cong.Rec. 16270 (1914).
In response, Representatives Sherley and Webb both argued that
Representative Mann had misconstrued the bill as it had originally
been passed by the House. Representative Webb explained:
"[T]he third paragraph of section 9 as the bill passed the House
was never intended to apply to banks, because we had an express
paragraph in section 9 which took care of interlocking directorates
in banks."
". . . Now it would be idiotic to say that we included also
banks and banking associations in the paragraph referring to
industrial corporations; and in order to make the paragraph
perfectly plain, we inserted 'other than banks and banks
[
sic] associations' and common carriers, which had no
effect upon the meaning of that section."
Id. at 16271. Representative Sherley echoed
Representative Webb's argument that at no time in its evolution did
the industrial corporations
Page 462 U. S. 139
paragraph ever prohibit interlocking directorates involving
banks.
Id. at 16271-16272. He concluded:
"To say that it was not within the province of the conference to
make it clear that only certain banks should be within the
provision touching certain interlocking directorates, and that the
provision touching industrial corporations [the present fourth
paragraph of § 8] was confined to such industrial corporations, and
should not by any stretch of construction be held to include banks,
is to say what seems to be contrary . . . to the plain common sense
of the situation."
Id. at 16272.
In reviewing this colloquy, it should be remembered that
Representatives Webb and Sherley voted for the Clayton Act as it
originally passed the House, while Representative Mann voted
against it.
Id. at 9911. Thus, greater weight is to be
accorded the views of Representatives Webb and Sherley concerning
the proper interpretation of the original bill than to the views of
Representative Mann.
See NLRB v. Fruit & Vegetable
Packers, 377 U. S. 58,
377 U. S. 66
(1964). Moreover, the fact that the Speaker of the House overruled
Representative Mann's point of order suggests that he accepted
Representatives Webb's and Sherley's interpretation. Finally,
regardless of which Member correctly interpreted the original House
bill, the fact remains that they all agreed that, under the
Conference bill, interlocking directorates involving banks were not
covered by the industrial corporations paragraph.
The dissent argues that the
"sole purpose of the ['other than banks' amendment] was to make
clear that bank-bank interlocks would be governed exclusively by
the preceding paragraphs, rather than by the competing corporations
paragraph."
Post at
462 U. S. 145.
This interpretation ignores the fact that the minimum size
requirements in the banking and industrial corporations provisions
were not comparable. As the Clayton Act was originally enacted, the
banking provisions measured size on the basis of "deposits,
capital, surplus, and undivided profits" aggregating $5 million or
more; the industrial corporations paragraph measured size on
the
Page 462 U. S. 140
basis of "capital, surplus, and undivided profits" aggregating
$1 million or more without regard to "deposits." Clayton Antitrust
Act of 1914, § 8, 38 Stat. 732-733. There is no reason to assume
that a bank with "deposits, capital, surplus, and undivided
profits" of $5 million is comparable to a bank with "capital,
surplus, and undivided profits" of $1 million. Thus, the provisions
do not dovetail in the manner suggested by the dissent.
It may well be, as the dissent speculates,
post at
462 U. S.
146-147, that a number of Congressmen mistakenly thought
that banking was not interstate commerce. Nonetheless, Congress
chose to deal with the problems of industrial and financial
concentration according to the class of corporations involved. It
chose to regulate banks in what are now the first three paragraphs
of § 8; to regulate common carriers in what is now § 10; and to
regulate industrial and commercial corporations in the fourth
paragraph of § 8. We are bound to respect that choice; we are not
to rewrite the statute based on our notions of appropriate
policy.
The judgment of the Court of Appeals is
Reversed.
JUSTICE POWELL took no part in the decision of this case.
[
Footnote 1]
The Court of Appeals also rejected petitioners' claim that the
interlocked insurance companies and bank holding companies were not
"competitors" within the meaning of § 8. 656 F.2d at 450-451. In
light of our disposition of the case, we need not reach this
issue.
[
Footnote 2]
The District Court found that, at present, "approximately 40% of
the insurance company directors in America are also bank
directors."
United States v. Crocker National
Corp., 422 F.
Supp. 686, 691 (1976). According to the American Council of
Life Insurance, 79% of its 550 members report having directors who
are also directors of banks; of that 79%, bank directors
constituted an average 33% of the insurance companies' boards.
Brief for American Council of Life Insurance as
Amicus
Curiae 3. It is likely that a substantial number of these
interlocking directorates are between insurance companies and banks
that compete in the credit markets, and hence, under the
Government's interpretation, violate § 8.
[
Footnote 3]
Another indication of the Government's longstanding position is
a 1950 Federal Trade Commission Report which specifically
interpreted § 8 not to apply to interlocking directorates between
banks and nonbanking corporations. Federal Trade Commission, Report
on Interlocking Directorates 10 (1951). The Federal Trade
Commission's later decision,
In re Perpetual Federal Savings
& Loan Assn., 90 F.T.C. 608 (1977),
vacated on other
grounds, 94 F.T.C. 401 (1979), that such interlocking
directorates violate § 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 15
U.S.C. § 45 (1976 ed. and Supp. V), does not undermine the
Commission's earlier analysis of § 8 of the Clayton Act.
[
Footnote 4]
Accord, Subcommittee on Domestic Finance of the House
Committee on Banking and Currency, Control of Commercial Banks and
Interlocks Among Financial Institutions, 90th Cong., 1st Sess.
(Subcomm. Print 1967), reprinted in 1 Subcommittee on Domestic
Finance of the House Committee on Banking and Currency, Commercial
Banks and Their Trust Activities: Emerging Influence on the
American Economy, 90th Cong., 2d Sess., 881, 925-926 (Subcomm.
Print 1968) (the Clayton Act "does not apply to interlocks between
commercial banks and competing financial institutions, such as
mutual savings banks, insurance companies, and small loan
companies"); Subcommittee on Antitrust of the House Committee on
the Judiciary, Interlocks in Corporate Management, 89th Cong., 1st
Sess., 25-26 (Comm. Print 1965) (the fourth paragraph of § 8 "does
[not] apply to interlocks with banks").
[
Footnote 5]
See also e.g., Advisory Committee on Banking to the
Comptroller of the Currency, National Banks and the Future 94
(1962); 1982 Duke L.J. 938, 939, 949.
JUSTICE WHITE, with whom JUSTICE BRENNAN and JUSTICE MARSHALL
join, dissenting.
The primary issue in this case is whether 7 4 of § 8 of the
Clayton Act (the "competing corporations provision"), 15 U.S.C. §
19, prohibits interlocking directorates between banks and nonbanks.
The Court holds that it does not, thereby exempting this entire
species of interlocks from any regulation whatsoever, even though
such interlocks undisputably may have serious anticompetitive
consequences directly contrary to the policies of our antitrust
laws. I am quite sure that Congress intended no such result, and I
therefore dissent.
Page 462 U. S. 141
I
Subject to certain other exemptions not presently relevant, � 4
of § 8 prohibits interlocking directorates between two or more
corporations engaged in whole or part in commerce, "other than
banks, banking associations, trust companies, and common carriers.
. . ." The question here is whether this "other than banks"
exemption is applicable to interlocks where any single one of the
interlocked corporations is a bank, as petitioners contend, or
whether it applies only when all of the interlocked corporations
are banks, as the Government asserts. Both sides argue, with
straight faces, that the plain statutory language supports their
respective constructions of § 8. The Court, with an equally
straight face, agrees with the petitioners and solemnly proclaims,
ante at
462 U. S. 128,
that the self-evident, unambiguous language of the statute requires
the conclusion that § 8 does not prohibit bank-nonbank interlocking
directorates. With deference, I must say that it escapes me how
either the Court or the litigants can seriously maintain that the
meaning of § 8 is unambiguous, or even that one side's reading is
significantly "more natural" than the other's.
In my view, the literal wording is far from conclusive, and
should not be dispositive. Consider the following analogy: a
statute states that "no person shall own two or more automobiles,
other than Fords." According to the Court, such a provision plainly
would not prohibit a person from owning one Chevrolet and one Ford.
Although such an interpretation is possible, it is equally
plausible to interpret the "other than" clause as exempting only
the ownership of two Fords from the reach of the statute.
Similarly, � 4 of § 8 can easily be read as exempting only an
interlock between two banks. The naked statutory wording provides
insufficient guidance as to Congress' true intent. It is therefore
necessary to consider the legislative history.
Page 462 U. S. 142
II
In considering the legislative materials, it is important to
keep in mind the structure of § 8 and the changes that were made in
this provision as it passed through each stage of the enactment
process. The first three paragraphs of § 8 proscribe a wide variety
of bank-bank interlocks, that is, interlocks between two or more
banks. The fourth paragraph bans interlocks between two or more
competing corporations engaged in whole or part in commerce "other
than" banks or common carriers.
See 15 U.S.C. § 19.
As originally passed by the House, the competing corporations
paragraph contained the "other than common carriers" proviso, but
it did
not provide any exemption for banks. [
Footnote 2/1] After the House approved the
bill, the legislation went to the Senate, which deleted the
paragraphs relating to bank-bank interlocks, but kept the competing
corporations provision in the same form passed by the House.
[
Footnote 2/2] Thus, as originally
adopted by both the Senate and the House, the competing
corporations provision did not contain the "other than banks"
language upon which petitioners rely.
The House was unwilling to accept the Senate's deletion of the
provisions relating to bank-bank interlocks, so the matter went to
a Conference Committee. The conferees agreed to reinclude the
provisions banning bank-bank interlocks, with a few minor
modifications. The conferees also inserted, for the first time, the
"other than banks" proviso into the competing corporations
provision. [
Footnote 2/3] The
Senate accepted this change without discussion, but, in the House,
there was a
Page 462 U. S. 143
brief but highly significant debate upon which both sides in the
present case heavily rely.
The House controversy arose when Representative Mann raised a
point of order alleging that the addition of the phrase "other than
banks" violated the rule that conferees may not change text to
which both Houses have agreed. Representative Mann argued that the
addition of the new phrase drastically limited the scope of the
competing corporations provision by excluding banks from its
purview:
"[W]hen this bill was prepared, it provided a prohibition
against interlocking directorates of banks. The House passed it in
that shape. The Senate passed it in that shape. But the House
conferees, without authority and over and beyond any jurisdiction
granted to them, have provided that banks shall no longer be
controlled by this prohibition of interlocking directorates where
banks are in competition."
51 Cong.Rec. 16270 (1914).
Representative Webb, one of the conferees, and Representative
Sherley then took the floor to defend the conference action.
Representative Webb asserted that the addition of the "other than
banks" language did not work a material or substantial change in
the provision, because,
"without question, . . . the third paragraph of Section 9 [the
present � 4 of § 8] as the bill passed the House was never intended
to apply to banks, because we had an express paragraph in Section 9
[the present first three paragraphs of § 8] which took care of
interlocking directorates in banks."
Id. at 16271. He described how the Senate had deleted
the House's bank-bank provisions, and how the conferees had
restored them. He continued:
"The conference did put in [the 'other than banks' proviso] in
order to make perfectly clear what in my opinion is already clear;
because in the preceding paragraph we had passed a section with
reference to interlocking directorates of banks. . . . Now, it
would be idiotic to say
Page 462 U. S. 144
that we included also banks and banking associations in the
paragraph referring to industrial corporations [the present � 4 of
§ 8]; and in order to make the paragraph perfectly plain, we
inserted 'other than banks and banks [
sic] associations'
and common carriers,
which had no effect upon the meaning of
that section."
Ibid. (emphasis added). Representative Sherley
concurred in Representative Webb's assessment.
Id. at
16272. [
Footnote 2/4]
Representative Mann was not satisfied by this explanation. He
noted that Representatives Webb and Sherley had conceded that the
conferees could not make substantive changes in the provision. He
remarked, however, that they did not appreciate the import of the
original version of the competing corporations paragraph, even
though "they should know more about it than I do."
Ibid.
Then, in the only express discussion of bank-nonbank interlocks in
all of the legislative debates on the Clayton Act, Representative
Mann indicated that the original version would have prohibited
interlocks between a bank and the "Sugar Trust" company, a bank and
United States Steel Corp., a bank and a hat company, or a bank and
any other company that competed with the bank. He implied, although
he did not state directly, that the conferees' version of the bill
would not reach such interlocks.
Ibid. .
Then, before Representatives Webb and Sherley had an opportunity
to respond to Representative Mann's remarks about bank-nonbank
interlocks, the Speaker overruled the point of order and held that,
although the conferees could not "drag in new subjects of
legislation," the subject matter in question was properly before
the conferees, because the Senate
Page 462 U. S. 145
had struck out the House bill provisions regulating bank-bank
interlocks. The conferees thus did not exceed their authority, and
if any Member did not like the Conference Report, he could simply
vote against it.
Id. at 16273.
Petitioners now strenuously argue, and the Court agrees,
ante at
462 U. S.
137-139, that this exchange supports their
interpretation of § 8. It shows, they say, that both Representative
Mann and the conferees agreed that, whether by material change or
by mere confirmation of what was already implicit in the bill, the
"other than banks" clause requires the conclusion that banks are
not within the scope of the competing corporations paragraph. I am
convinced, however, that this exchange strongly supports the
Government's view of § 8. Although Representative Mann apparently
believed that the final version of § 8 would have to be interpreted
in the manner suggested by petitioners, the characterization of a
bill by one of its opponents has never been deemed persuasive
evidence of legislative intent.
NLRB v. Fruit & Vegetable
Packers, 377 U. S. 58,
377 U. S. 66
(1964). The critical point is that the bill's supporters
characterized the addition of the "other than banks" proviso as
making no substantive alteration in the scope of coverage of the
original version of § 8. Rather, the sole purpose of the addition
was to make clear that bank-bank interlocks would be governed
exclusively by the preceding paragraphs, rather than by the
competing corporations paragraph. The "other than banks" language
thus apparently was not intended to touch upon the question of
bank-nonbank interlocks.
In light of the statements of the men most familiar with the
circumstances surrounding the addition of the "other than banks"
language, we should construe this language as not making a
substantive change from the original version of § 8. Thus,
petitioners are left with the argument that, even without the
"other than banks" clause, the provision still does not reach
bank-nonbank interlocks. Some Members of the enacting Congress may
well have assumed such to be the case,
Page 462 U. S. 146
because it was far from clear at that time that a bank could be
a competitor of a corporation "engaged in whole or part in
commerce." For example, under the then-prevailing doctrine of
Paul v.
Virginia, 8 Wall. 168 (1869), insurance companies
were not considered to be engaged in interstate commerce.
Furthermore, it was uncertain whether a bank was itself a
corporation engaged in commerce.
Cf. 49 U.
S. Louisiana, 8 How. 73,
49 U. S. 81
(1850) (an "individual who uses his money and credit in buying and
selling bills of exchange, and who thereby realizes a profit, . . .
is not engaged in commerce"). [
Footnote
2/5]
But this Court's more recent cases have made it clear that both
banking and insurance corporations are engaged in commerce, and
that the antitrust laws apply to them even though some Members of
Congress may not have anticipated such a result.
See United
States v. South-Eastern Underwriters Assn., 322 U.
S. 533,
322 U. S.
556-559 (1944);
United States v. Philadelphia
National Bank, 374 U. S. 321,
374 U. S. 336,
n. 12 (1963). Thus, because the legislative history does not
show
"a clear and unequivocal desire of Congress to legislate only
within that area previously declared by this Court to be within the
federal power,"
South-Eastern Underwriters, supra, at
322 U. S.
556-557, there would be no merit to an argument that,
even without the "other than banks" proviso, the competing
corporations provision does not prohibit bank-nonbank
interlocks.
The remaining bulk of the legislative history cited by both
parties and the Court is, in my opinion, of little relevance. The
Government cites numerous statements by Congressmen
Page 462 U. S. 147
and President Wilson denouncing interlocking directorates in
general, and interlocks between competitors in the banking industry
in particular. However, all of these statements are far too general
to provide the Government with any really substantial support. None
was made explicitly in connection with the provision at issue.
Petitioners and the Court counter with statements of witnesses
and Congressmen during Committee hearings and floor debates that
supposedly indicate that § 8 does not include bank-nonbank
interlocks. [
Footnote 2/6] Although
these statements seem very helpful to petitioners, close inspection
shows that such is not the case. First, all of these statements
were made prior to the addition of the "other than banks" proviso.
Thus, for the reasons mentioned above, they only support the
untenable argument that even the original version of § 8 did not
cover bank-nonbank interlocks. Some Congressmen and witnesses
apparently thought that only "industrial" corporations engaged "in
commerce," but this fact is of no import. Second, it appears that
all of these early statements cited by petitioners are taken out of
context. They were made in the context of discussions of vertical
interlocks or bank-bank interlocks. [
Footnote 2/7]
Accordingly, the only truly relevant legislative history
demonstrates that Congress did not intend to exempt bank-nonbank
interlocks from coverage. This conclusion seems
Page 462 U. S. 148
inescapable when we add into the equation the rule that
exemptions from the antitrust laws must be construed narrowly,
see Union Labor Life Ins. Co. v. Pireno, 458 U.
S. 119,
458 U. S. 126
(1982);
FMC v. Seatrain Lines, Inc., 411 U.
S. 726,
411 U. S. 733
(1973), and the fact that bank-nonbank interlocks have strong
anticompetitive effects that run counter to at least the spirit of
the Clayton Act. Indeed, neither the Court nor petitioners have
identified any logical policy reasons why Congress would have
wanted bank-nonbank interlocks, unlike every other species of
interlocks between competing corporations, to be totally exempt
from any form of regulation. Hence, I am convinced that the Court's
holding creates "a loophole in the statute that Congress simply did
not intend to create."
United States v. Naftalin,
441 U. S. 768,
441 U. S. 777
(1979). [
Footnote 2/8]
III
The most appealing argument in favor of the Court's holding
comes not from the statutory language or the legislative
Page 462 U. S. 149
history, but from the fact that, for over 60 years, the
Government took no action to apply § 8 against bank-nonbank
interlocks. The Court correctly notes,
ante at
462 U. S. 131,
that the Government's failure to exercise its authority for such a
long time suggests that it did not read the statute as granting
such authority. However, as the Court concedes,
ibid., the
mere failure of an agency to act is in no sense a binding
administrative interpretation that the Government lacks power to
act. And even if the Justice Department and/or the Federal Trade
Commission had in the past expressly adopted petitioners'
interpretation of § 8 (and in fact, neither agency ever did so),
this fact would hardly be dispositive. At most, it would mean that
their present interpretation would not be entitled to the usual
degree of deference, since it was inconsistent with their previous
view. [
Footnote 2/9]
There is, of course, no rule of administrative
stare
decisis. Agencies frequently adopt one interpretation of a
statute and then, years later, adopt a different view. This and
other courts have approved such administrative "changes in course,"
as long as the new interpretation is consistent with congressional
intent. [
Footnote 2/10] Here, the
concerned agencies until recently never formally expressed a view
one way or the other, and the legislative history reveals that the
Government's
Page 462 U. S. 150
present course is the correct one. The Government's past failure
to adhere to the proper course should not be used as an excuse for
ignoring the true congressional intent. I therefore would affirm
the judgment of the Court of Appeals. [
Footnote 2/11]
[
Footnote 2/1]
See 2 E. Kintner, The Legislative History of the
Federal Antitrust Laws and Related Statutes 1733 (1978) (reprinting
H.R. 15657, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., as agreed upon in the Committee of
the Whole House on June 2, 1914).
[
Footnote 2/2]
See 3 Kintner,
supra, at 2429 (reprinting H.R.
15657, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., as amended and passed by the Senate on
Sept. 2, 1914).
[
Footnote 2/3]
See Report of the Conference Committee, H.R.Conf.Rep.
No. 1168, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., 4 (1914), reprinted in 3 Kintner,
supra, at 2458-2459.
[
Footnote 2/4]
Representative Sherley commented that, even without the new
language,
"any court would hold that the inclusion by name of banks and
trust companies in one instance excluded them from the general
provisions in the other, and, in addition, banks and trust
companies are not [competitors of] industrial corporations."
51 Cong.Rec. 16272 (1914).
[
Footnote 2/5]
The Court correctly notes,
ante at
462 U. S. 134,
that Louis Brandeis "argued" that banking is interstate commerce.
Hearings on Trust Legislation before the House Committee on the
Judiciary, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., 924 (1914). However, Brandeis
conceded that this was only a "possible theory," one that had "not
yet been sustained by the Supreme Court."
Id. at 923.
Representative Graham expressly disagreed with Brandeis' argument.
Id. at 924.
[
Footnote 2/6]
E.g.,
"I think there is a grave question as to whether a director in a
great life insurance company should be a director in a bank. You
have failed to cover that feature."
Id. at 823 (S. Untermyer).
See also id. at
921-925 (L. Brandeis); 51 Cong.Rec. 9604 (1914) (Rep. Cullop)
(competing corporations provision "relates to industrial and
commercial corporations, or institutions of that kind, but has no
reference whatever to the banking business").
See generally
ante at
462 U. S.
134-137.
[
Footnote 2/7]
The Court does not expressly indicate whether its holding would
be the same in the absence of the "other than banks" proviso, but
none of the legislative history that it cites,
ante at
462 U. S.
133-139, advances its textual argument in the
slightest.
[
Footnote 2/8]
The Court states,
ante at
462 U. S. 129,
that the Government does not dispute that the "other than common
carriers" language of § 8 exempts carrier-noncarrier interlocks,
and that, to be consistent, the "other than banks" exemption should
be interpreted in the same manner. In the first place, the
Government has not in this Court taken a position one way or the
other on the question whether § 8 applies to carrier-noncarrier
interlocks. This issue may be largely academic, for it is difficult
to think of examples of situations in which, within the meaning of
§ 8, a carrier would be a "competitor" of a noncarrier. In any
event, a strong argument can be made that § 8 does apply to
carrier-noncarrier interlocks. On the same day the House originally
passed the Clayton Act, it also passed an amendment to the
Interstate Commerce Act (ICA) that would have prohibited
carrier-carrier interlocks not approved by the Interstate Commerce
Commission. 51 Cong.Rec. 9881, 9910-9912 (1914). A similar bill
became law in 1920.
See 49 U.S.C. § 11322 (1976 ed., Supp.
V). Thus, just as the "other than banks" language was added simply
to make clear that the provisions regulating bank-bank interlocks
were exclusive, it would seem that the "other than carriers"
language was inserted just to clarify that the ICA amendment
provided the exclusive means for regulating carrier-carrier
interlocks.
[
Footnote 2/9]
See, e.g., Bowsher v. Merck & Co., 460 U.
S. 824,
460 U. S. 838,
n. 13 (1983) (WHITE, J., concurring in part and dissenting in
part);
General Electric Co. v. Gilbert, 429 U.
S. 125,
429 U. S.
142-143 (1976);
Morton v. Ruiz, 415 U.
S. 199,
415 U. S.
236-237 (1974).
[
Footnote 2/10]
See, e.g., United States v. Generix Drug Corp.,
460 U. S. 453
(1983) (approving new agency statutory interpretation despite many
years of contrary interpretation);
NLRB v. J. Weingarten,
Inc., 420 U. S. 251
(1975) (same);
NLRB v. Seven-Up Bottling Co., 344 U.
S. 344 (1953) (same);
United States v. City and
County of San Francisco, 310 U. S. 16,
310 U. S. 31-32
(1940) (same). The rule that an agency can change the manner in
which it interprets a statute is often said to be subject to the
qualification that, if it makes a change, the reasons for doing so
must be set forth so that meaningful judicial review will be
possible.
See Atchison, T. & S. F. R. Co. v. Wichita Bd. of
Trade, 412 U. S. 800,
412 U. S. 808
(1973) (plurality opinion); 4 K. Davis, Administrative Law § 20:11
(2d ed.1983).
[
Footnote 2/11]
Under my view of § 8, it is necessary to reach petitioners'
alternative argument that the interlocked insurance companies and
bank holding companies are not "competitors" within the meaning of
§ 8. But in light of the Court's holding, I see no point in
addressing this issue at length. Suffice it to say that I am
inclined to agree with the Court of Appeals that bank holding
companies and their subsidiary banks are so closely related that
they should be treated as one entity for § 8 purposes.
See
United States v. Crocker National Corp., 656 F.2d 428, 450-451
(CA9 1981).