While exempting periodic publications from its general sales and
use tax, Minnesota imposes a "use tax" on the cost of paper and ink
products consumed in the production of such a publication, but
exempts the first $100,000 worth of paper and ink consumed in any
calendar year. Appellant newspaper publisher brought an action
seeking a refund of the ink and paper use taxes it had paid during
certain years, contending that the tax violates,
inter
alia, the guarantee of the freedom of the press in the First
Amendment. The Minnesota Supreme Court upheld the tax.
Held: The tax in question violates the First Amendment.
Pp.
460 U. S.
579-593.
(a) There is no legislative history, and no indication, apart
from the structure of the tax itself, of any impermissible or
censorial motive on the part of the Minnesota Legislature in
enacting the tax.
Grosjean v. American Press Co.,
297 U. S. 233,
distinguished. Pp. 579-580.
(b) But by creating the special use tax, which is without
parallel in the State's tax scheme, Minnesota has singled out the
press for special treatment. When a State so singles out the press,
the political constraints that prevent a legislature from imposing
crippling taxes of general applicability are weakened, and the
threat of burdensome taxes becomes acute. That threat can operate
as effectively as a censor to check critical comment by the press,
thus undercutting the basic assumption of our political system that
the press will often serve as an important restraint on government.
Moreover, differential treatment, unless justified by some special
characteristic of the press, suggests that the goal of the
regulation is not unrelated to suppression of expression, and such
goal is presumptively unconstitutional. Differential treatment of
the press, then, places such a burden on the interests protected by
the First Amendment that such treatment cannot be countenanced
unless the State asserts a counterbalancing interest of compelling
importance that it cannot achieve without differential taxation.
Pp.
460 U. S.
581-585.
(c) Minnesota has offered no adequate justification for the
special treatment of newspapers. Its interest in raising revenue,
standing alone, cannot justify such treatment, for the alternative
means of taxing businesses generally is clearly available. And the
State has offered no explanation of why it chose to use a
substitute for the sales tax, rather
Page 460 U. S. 576
than the sales tax itself. A rule that would automatically allow
the State to single out the press for a different method of
taxation as long as the effective burden is no different from that
on other taxpayers or, as Minnesota asserts here, is lighter than
that on other businesses, is to be avoided. The possibility of
error inherent in such a rule poses too great a threat to concerns
at the heart of the First Amendment. Pp.
460 U. S.
586-590.
(d) Minnesota's ink and paper tax violates the First Amendment
not only because it singles out the press, but also because it
targets a small group of newspapers. The effect of the $100,000
exemption is that only a handful of publishers in the State pay any
tax at all, and even fewer pay any significant amount of tax. To
recognize a power in the State not only to single out the press,
but also to tailor the tax so that it singles out a few members of
the press, presents such a potential for abuse that no interest
suggested by Minnesota can justify the scheme. Pp.
460 U. S.
591-592.
314 N.W.2d
201, reversed.
O'CONNOR, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
BURGER, C.J., and BRENNAN, MARSHALL, POWELL, and STEVENS, JJ.,
joined, in Part V of which WHITE, J., joined, and in all but
footnote 12 of which BLACKMUN, J., joined. WHITE, J., filed an
opinion concurring in part and dissenting in part,
post,
p.
460 U. S. 593.
REHNQUIST, J., filed a dissenting opinion,
post, p.
460 U. S.
596.
JUSTICE O'CONNOR delivered the opinion of the Court.
*
This case presents the question of a State's power to impose a
special tax on the press and, by enacting exemptions, to limit its
effect to only a few newspapers.
Page 460 U. S. 577
I
Since 1967, Minnesota has imposed a sales tax on most sales of
goods for a price in excess of a nominal sum. [
Footnote 1] Act of June 1, 1967, ch. 32, Art.
XIII, § 2, 1967 Minn. Laws 2143, 2179, codified at Minn.Stat. § 297
A. 02 (1982). In general, the tax applies only to retail sales.
Ibid. An exemption for industrial and agricultural users
shields from the tax sales of components to be used in the
production of goods that will themselves be sold at retail. §
297A.25(1)(h). As part of this general system of taxation and in
support of the sales tax,
see Minn.Code of Agency Rules,
Tax S & U 300 (1979), Minnesota also enacted a tax on the
"privilege of using, storing or consuming in Minnesota tangible
personal property." This use tax applies to any nonexempt tangible
personal property unless the sales tax was paid on the sales price.
Minn.Stat. § 297 A. 14 (1982). Like the classic use tax, this use
tax protects the State's sales tax by eliminating the residents'
incentive to travel to States with lower sales taxes to buy goods,
rather than buying them in Minnesota. §§ 297 A. 14, 297 A. 24.
The appellant, Minneapolis Star & Tribune Co., "Star
Tribune," is the publisher of a morning newspaper and an evening
newspaper (until 1982) in Minneapolis. From 1967 until 1971, it
enjoyed an exemption from the sales and use tax provided by
Minnesota for periodic publications. 1967 Minn. Laws 2187, codified
at Minn.Stat. § 297A.25(1)(i) (1982). In 1971, however, while
leaving the exemption from the sales tax in place, the legislature
amended the scheme to impose a "use tax" on the cost of paper and
ink products consumed in the production of a publication. Act of
Oct. 31, 1971, ch. 31, Art. I, § 5, 1971 Minn. Laws 2561, 2565,
codified
Page 460 U. S. 578
with modifications at Minn.Stat. §§ 297 A. 14, 297A.25(1)(i)
(1982). Ink and paper used in publications became the only items
subject to the use tax that were components of goods to be sold at
retail. In 1974, the legislature again amended the statute, this
time to exempt the first $100,000 worth of ink and paper consumed
by a publication in any calendar year, in effect giving each
publication an annual tax credit of $4,000. Act of May 24, 1973,
ch. 650, Art. XIII, § 1, 1973 Minn.Laws 1606, 1637, codified at
Minn.Stat. § 297 A. 14 (1982). [
Footnote 2] Publications remained exempt from the sales
tax, § 2, 1973 Minn. Laws 1639.
After the enactment of the $100,000 exemption, 11 publishers,
producing 14 of the 388 paid circulation newspapers in the State,
incurred a tax liability in 1974. Star Tribune was one of the 11,
and, of the $893,355 collected, it paid $608,634, or roughly
two-thirds of the total revenue raised by the tax.
Page 460 U. S. 579
See 314 N.W.2d
201, 203, and n. 4 (1981). In 1975, 13 publishers, producing 16
out of 374 paid circulation papers, paid a tax. That year, Star
Tribune again bore roughly two-thirds of the total receipts from
the use tax on ink and paper.
Id. at 204, and n. 5.
Star Tribune instituted this action to seek a refund of the use
taxes it paid from January 1, 1974, to May 31, 1975. It challenged
the imposition of the use tax on ink and paper used in publications
as a violation of the guarantees of freedom of the press and equal
protection in the First and Fourteenth Amendments. The Minnesota
Supreme Court upheld the tax against the federal constitutional
challenge.
314 N.W.2d
201 (1981). We noted probable jurisdiction, 457 U.S. 1130
(1982), and we now reverse.
II
Star Tribune argues that we must strike this tax on the
authority of
Grosjean v. American Press Co., 297 U.
S. 233 (1936). Although there are similarities between
the two cases, we agree with the State that
Grosjean is
not controlling.
In
Grosjean, the State of Louisiana imposed a license
tax of 2% of the gross receipts from the sale of advertising on all
newspapers with a weekly circulation above 20,000. Out of at least
124 publishers in the State, only 13 were subject to the tax. After
noting that the tax was "single in kind" and that keying the tax to
circulation curtailed the flow of information,
id. at
297 U. S.
250-251, this Court held the tax invalid as an
abridgment of the freedom of the press. Both the brief and the
argument of the publishers in this Court emphasized the events
leading up to the tax and the contemporary political climate in
Louisiana.
See Argument for Appellees,
id. at 238
[omitted from electronic version]; Brief for Appellees, O.T. 1936,
No. 303, pp. 8-9, 30. All but one of the large papers subject to
the tax had "ganged up" on Senator Huey Long, and a circular
distributed by Long and the Governor to each member of the state
legislature
Page 460 U. S. 580
described "lying newspapers" as conducting "a vicious campaign"
and the tax as "a tax on lying, 2 cent [
sic] a lie."
Id. at 9. Although the Court's opinion did not describe
this history, it stated
"[the tax] is bad because, in the light of its history and of
its present setting, it is seen to be a deliberate and calculated
device in the guise of a tax to limit the circulation of
information,"
297 U.S. at
297 U. S. 250,
an explanation that suggests that the motivation of the legislature
may have been significant.
Our subsequent cases have not been consistent in their reading
of
Grosjean on this point.
Compare United States v.
O'Brien, 391 U. S. 367,
391 U. S.
384-385 (1968) (stating that legislative purpose was
irrelevant in
Grosjean),
with Houchins v. KQED,
Inc., 438 U. S. 1,
438 U. S. 9-10
(1978) (plurality opinion) (suggesting that purpose was relevant in
Grosjean);
Pittsburgh Press Co. v. Pittsburgh Comm'n
on Human Relations, 413 U. S. 376,
413 U. S. 383
(1973) (same). Commentators have generally viewed
Grosjean
as dependent on the improper censorial goals of the legislature.
See T. Emerson, The System of Freedom of Expression 419
(1970); L. Tribe, American Constitutional Law 592, n. 8, 724, n. 10
(1978). We think that the result in
Grosjean may have been
attributable in part to the perception on the part of the Court
that the State imposed the tax with an intent to penalize a
selected group of newspapers. In the case currently before us,
however, there is no legislative history [
Footnote 3] and no indication, apart from the structure
of the tax itself, of any impermissible or censorial motive on the
part of the legislature. We cannot resolve the case by simple
citation to
Grosjean. Instead, we must analyze the problem
anew under the general principles of the First Amendment.
Page 460 U. S. 581
III
Clearly, the First Amendment does not prohibit all regulation of
the press. It is beyond dispute that the States and the Federal
Government can subject newspapers to generally applicable economic
regulations without creating constitutional problems.
See,
e.g., Citizen Publishing Co. v. United States, 394 U.
S. 131,
394 U. S. 139
(1969) (antitrust laws);
Lorain Journal Co. v. United
States, 342 U. S. 143,
342 U. S.
155-156 (1951) (same);
Breard v. Alexandria,
341 U. S. 622
(1951) (prohibition of door-to-door solicitation);
Oklahoma
Press Publishing Co. v. Walling, 327 U.
S. 186,
327 U. S.
192-193 (1946) (Fair Labor Standards Act);
Mabee v.
White Plains Publishing Co., 327 U. S. 178
(1946) (same);
Associated Press v. United States,
326 U. S. 1,
326 U. S. 6-7,
326 U. S. 19-20
(1945) (antitrust laws);
Associated Press v. NLRB,
301 U. S. 103,
301 U. S.
132-133 (1937) (National Labor Relations Act);
see
also Branzburg v. Hayes, 408 U. S. 665
(1972) (enforcement of subpoenas). Minnesota, however, has not
chosen to apply its general sales and use tax to newspapers.
Instead, it has created a special tax that applies only to certain
publications protected by the First Amendment. Although the State
argues now that the tax on paper and ink is part of the general
scheme of taxation, the use tax provision, quoted in
n 2,
supra, is facially
discriminatory, singling out publications for treatment that is, to
our knowledge, unique in Minnesota tax law.
Minnesota's treatment of publications differs from that of other
enterprises in at least two important respects: [
Footnote 4] it imposes a use tax that does
not serve the function of protecting the sales tax, and it taxes an
intermediate transaction, rather than the ultimate retail sale. A
use tax ordinarily serves to complement the sales tax by
eliminating the incentive to make major purchases in States with
lower sales taxes; it requires
Page 460 U. S. 582
the resident who shops out-of-state to pay a use tax equal to
the sales tax savings.
E.g., National Geographic Society v.
California Board of Equalization, 430 U.
S. 551,
430 U. S. 555
(1977); P. Hartman, Federal Limitations on State and Local Taxation
§§ 10:1, 10:5 (1981); Warren & Schlesinger, Sales and Use
Taxes: Interstate Commerce Pays Its Way, 38 Colum.L.Rev. 49, 63
(1938). Minnesota designed its overall use tax scheme to serve this
function. As the regulations state, "[t]he
use tax' is a
compensating or complementary tax." Minn.Code of Agency Rules, Tax
S & U 300 (1979); see Minn.Stat. § 297 A. 24 (1982).
Thus, in general, items exempt from the sales tax are not subject
to the use tax, for, in the event of a sales tax exemption, there
is no "complementary function" for a use tax to serve. See
DeLuxe Check Printers, Inc. v. Commissioner of Tax, 295 Minn.
76, 203 N.W.2d 341, 343 (1972). But the use tax on ink and paper
serves no such complementary function; it applies to all uses,
whether or not the taxpayer purchased the ink and paper in-state,
and it applies to items exempt from the sales tax.
Further, the ordinary rule in Minnesota, as discussed above, is
to tax only the ultimate, or retail, sale rather than the use of
components like ink and paper.
"The statutory scheme is to devise a unitary tax which exempts
intermediate transactions and imposes it only on sales when the
finished product is purchased by the ultimate user."
Standard Packaging Corp. v. Commissioner of
Revenue, 288 N.W.2d
234,
239
(Minn.1979). Publishers, however, are taxed on their purchase of
components, even though they will eventually sell their
publications at retail.
By creating this special use tax, which, to our knowledge, is
without parallel in the State's tax scheme, Minnesota has singled
out the press for special treatment. We then must determine whether
the First Amendment permits such special taxation. A tax that
burdens rights protected by the First Amendment cannot stand unless
the burden is necessary to achieve an overriding governmental
interest.
See,
Page 460 U. S. 583
e.g., United States v. Lee, 455 U.
S. 252 (1982). Any tax that the press must pay, of
course, imposes some "burden." But, as we have observed,
see
supra at
460 U. S. 581,
this Court has long upheld economic regulation of the press. The
cases approving such economic regulation, however, emphasized the
general applicability of the challenged regulation to all
businesses,
e.g., Oklahoma Press Publishing Co. v. Walling,
supra, at
327 U. S. 194;
Mabee v. White Plains Publishing Co., supra, at
327 U. S. 184;
Associated Press v. NLRB, supra, at
326 U. S.
132-133, [
Footnote
5] suggesting that a regulation that singled out the press
might place a heavier burden of justification on the State, and we
now conclude that the special problems created by differential
treatment do indeed impose such a burden.
There is substantial evidence that differential taxation of the
press would have troubled the Framers of the First Amendment.
[
Footnote 6] The role of the
press in mobilizing sentiment
Page 460 U. S. 584
in favor of independence was critical to the Revolution. When
the Constitution was proposed without an explicit guarantee of
freedom of the press, the Antifederalists objected. Proponents of
the Constitution, relying on the principle of enumerated powers,
responded that such a guarantee was unnecessary, because the
Constitution granted Congress no power to control the press. The
remarks of Richard Henry Lee are typical of the rejoinders of the
Antifederalists:
"I confess I do not see in what cases the congress can, with any
pretence of right, make a law to suppress the freedom of the press,
though I am not clear that congress is restrained from laying any
duties whatever on printing, and from laying duties particularly
heavy on certain pieces printed. . . ."
R. Lee, Observation Leading to a Fair Examination of the System
of Government, Letter IV, reprinted in 1 B. Schwartz, The Bill of
Rights: A Documentary History 466, 474 (1971).
See also A
Review of the Constitution Proposed by the Late Convention by a
Federal Republican, reprinted in 3 H. Storing, The Complete
Anti-Federalist 65, 81-82 (1981); M. Smith, Address to the People
of New York on the Necessity of Amendments to the Constitution,
reprinted in 1 B. Schwartz,
supra, at 566, 575-576;
cf. The Federalist No. 84, p. 440, and n. 1 (A. Hamilton)
(M. Beloff ed.1948) (recognizing and attempting to refute the
argument). The concerns voiced by the Antifederalists led to the
adoption of the Bill of Rights.
See 1 B. Schwartz,
supra, at 527.
Page 460 U. S. 585
The fears of the Antifederalists were well-founded. A power to
tax differentially, as opposed to a power to tax generally, gives a
government a powerful weapon against the taxpayer selected. When
the State imposes a generally applicable tax, there is little cause
for concern. We need not fear that a government will destroy a
selected group of taxpayers by burdensome taxation if it must
impose the same burden on the rest of its constituency.
See
Railway Express Agency, Inc. v. New York, 336 U.
S. 106,
336 U. S.
112-113 (1949) (Jackson, J., concurring). When the State
singles out the press, though, the political constraints that
prevent a legislature from passing crippling taxes of general
applicability are weakened, and the threat of burdensome taxes
becomes acute. That threat can operate as effectively as a censor
to check critical comment by the press, undercutting the basic
assumption of our political system that the press will often serve
as an important restraint on government.
See generally
Stewart, "Or of the Press," 26 Hastings L.J. 631, 634 (1975). "[A]n
untrammeled press [is] a vital source of public information,"
Grosjean, 297 U.S. at
297 U. S. 250,
and an informed public is the essence of working democracy.
Further, differential treatment, unless justified by some
special characteristic of the press, suggests that the goal of the
regulation is not unrelated to suppression of expression, and such
a goal is presumptively unconstitutional.
See, e.g., Police
Department of Chicago v. Mosley, 408 U. S.
92,
408 U. S. 95-96
(1972);
cf. Brown v. Hartlage, 456 U. S.
45 (1982) (First Amendment has its "fullest and most
urgent" application in the case of regulation of the content of
political speech). Differential taxation of the press, then, places
such a burden on the interests protected by the First Amendment
that we cannot countenance such treatment unless the State asserts
a counterbalancing interest of compelling importance that it cannot
achieve without differential taxation. [
Footnote 7]
Page 460 U. S. 586
IV
The main interest asserted by Minnesota in this case is the
raising of revenue. Of course that interest is critical to any
government. Standing alone, however, it cannot justify the special
treatment of the press, for an alternative means of achieving the
same interest without raising concerns under the First Amendment is
clearly available: the State could raise the revenue by taxing
businesses generally, [
Footnote
8] avoiding the censorial threat implicit in a tax that singles
out the press.
Addressing the concern with differential treatment, Minnesota
invites us to look beyond the form of the tax to its substance. The
tax is, according to the State, merely a substitute for the sales
tax, which, as a generally applicable tax, would be constitutional
as applied to the press. [
Footnote
9] There are
Page 460 U. S. 587
two fatal flaws in this reasoning. First, the State has offered
no explanation of why it chose to use a substitute for the sales
tax, rather than the sales tax itself. The court below speculated
that the State might have been concerned that collection of a tax
on such small transactions would be impractical. 314 N.W.2d at 207.
That suggestion is unpersuasive, for sales of other low-priced
goods are not exempt,
see n 1,
supra. [
Footnote 10] If the real goal of this tax is to
duplicate
Page 460 U. S. 588
the sales tax, it is difficult to see why the State did not
achieve that goal by the obvious and effective expedient of
applying the sales tax.
Further, even assuming that the legislature did have valid
reasons for substituting another tax for the sales tax, we are not
persuaded that this tax does serve as a substitute. The State
asserts that this scheme actually
favors the press over
other businesses, because the same rate of tax is applied, but, for
the press, the rate applies to the cost of components, rather than
to the sales price. We would be hesitant to fashion a rule that
automatically allowed the State to single out the press for a
different method of taxation as long as the effective burden was no
different from that on other taxpayers or the burden on the press
was lighter than that on other businesses. One reason for this
reluctance is that the very selection of the press for special
treatment threatens the press not only with the current
differential treatment, but also with the possibility of
subsequent differentially
more burdensome treatment. Thus,
even without actually imposing an extra burden on the press, the
government might be able to achieve censorial effects, for "[t]he
threat of sanctions may deter [the] exercise [of First Amendment
rights] almost as potently as the actual application of sanctions."
NAACP v. Button, 371 U. S. 415,
371 U. S. 433
(1963). [
Footnote 11]
Page 460 U. S. 589
A second reason to avoid the proposed rule is that courts, as
institutions, are poorly equipped to evaluate with precision the
relative burdens of various methods of taxation. [
Footnote 12] The
Page 460 U. S. 590
Complexities of factual economic proof always present a certain
potential for error, and courts have little familiarity with the
process of evaluating the relative economic burden of taxes. In
sum, the possibility of error inherent in the proposed rule poses
too great a threat to concerns at the hart of the First Amendment,
and we cannot tolerate that possibility. [
Footnote 13] Minnesota, therefore, has offered no
adequate justification for the special treatment of newspapers.
[
Footnote 14]
Page 460 U. S. 591
V
Minnesota's ink and paper tax violates the First Amendment not
only because it singles out the press, but also because it targets
a small group of newspapers. The effect of the $100,000 exemption
enacted in 1974 is that only a handful of publishers pay any tax at
all, and even fewer pay any significant amount of tax. [
Footnote 15] The State explains this
exemption as part of a policy favoring an "equitable" tax system,
although there are no comparable exemptions for small enterprises
outside the press. Again, there is no legislative history
supporting the State's view of the purpose of the amendment.
Whatever the motive of the legislature in this
Page 460 U. S. 592
case, we think that recognizing a power in the State not only to
single out the press, but also to tailor the tax so that it singles
out a few members of the press presents such a potential for abuse
that no interest suggested by Minnesota can justify the scheme. It
has asserted no interest other than its desire to have an
"equitable" tax system. The current system, it explains, promotes
equity because it places the burden on large publications that
impose more social costs than do smaller publications, and that are
more likely to be able to bear the burden of the tax. Even if we
were willing to accept the premise that large businesses are more
profitable, and therefore better able to bear the burden of the
tax, the State's commitment to this "equity" is questionable, for
the concern has not led the State to grant benefits to small
businesses in general. [
Footnote
16] And when the exemption selects such a narrowly defined
group to bear the full burden of the tax, the tax begins to
resemble more a penalty for a few of the largest newspapers than an
attempt to favor struggling smaller enterprises.
VI
We need not and do not impugn the motives of the Minnesota
Legislature in passing the ink and paper tax. Illicit legislative
intent is not the
sine qua non of a violation of the First
Amendment.
See NAACP v. Button, 371 U.S. at
371 U. S. 439;
NAACP v. Alabama ex rel. Patterson, 357 U.
S. 449,
357 U. S. 461
(1958);
Lovell v. Griffin, 303 U.
S. 444,
303 U. S. 451
(1938). We have long recognized that even regulations aimed at
proper governmental concerns can restrict unduly the exercise of
rights protected by the First Amendment.
E.g., Schneider v.
State, 308 U. S. 147
(1939). A tax that singles out the press, or that targets
individual publications within the press, places a
Page 460 U. S. 593
heavy burden on the State to justify its action. Since Minnesota
has offered no satisfactory justification for its tax on the use of
ink and paper, the tax violates the First Amendment, [
Footnote 17] and the judgment below
is
Reversed.
* JUSTICE BLACKMUN joins this opinion except
footnote 12
[
Footnote 1]
Currently, the tax applies to sales of items for more than 9
cents. Minn.Stat. § 297A.03(2) (1982). When first enacted, the
threshold amount was 16 cents. Act of June 1, 1967, ch. 32, Art.
XIII, § 3(2), 1967 Minn. Laws 2143, 2180.
[
Footnote 2]
After the 1974 amendment, the use tax provision read in
full:
"For the privilege of using, storing or consuming in Minnesota
tangible personal property, tickets or admissions to places of
amusement and athletic events, electricity, gas, and local exchange
telephone service purchased for use, storage or consumption in this
state, there is hereby imposed on every person in this state a use
tax at the rate of four percent of the sales price of sales at
retail of any of the aforementioned items made to such person after
October 31, 1971, unless the tax imposed by section 297 A. 02 [the
sales tax] was paid on said sales price."
"Motor vehicles subject to tax under this section shall be taxed
at the fair market value at the time of transport into Minnesota if
such motor vehicles were acquired more than three months prior to
its [
sic] transport into this state."
"Notwithstanding any other provisions of section 297 A. 01 to
297 A. 44 to the contrary, the cost of paper and ink products
exceeding $100,000 in any calendar year, used or consumed in
producing a publication as defined in section 297 A. 25,
subdivision 1, clause (i) is subject to the tax imposed by this
section."
1973 Minn. Laws 1637, codified at Minn.Stat. § 297 A. 14 (1982).
The final paragraph was the only addition of the 1974 amendment.
The provision has since been amended to increase the rate of the
tax, Act of June 6, 1981, ch. 1, Art. IV, § 5, 1981 Minn. Laws
2396, but has not been changed in any way relevant to this
litigation.
[
Footnote 3]
Although the Minnesota Legislature records some proceedings and
preserves the recordings, it has specifically provided that those
recordings are not to be considered as evidence of legislative
intent.
See Minnesota Legislative Manual, Rule 1.18, Rules
of the Minn. House of Representatives; Rule 65, Permanent Rules of
the Senate (1981-1982). There is no evidence of legislative intent
on the record in this litigation.
[
Footnote 4]
A third difference is worth noting, though it may have little
economic effect. The use tax is not visible to consumers, while the
sales tax must, by law, be stated separately as an addition to the
price.
See Minn.Stat. § 297A.03(1) (1982).
[
Footnote 5]
The Court recognized in
Oklahoma Press that the FLSA
excluded seamen and farmworkers.
See 327 U.S. at
327 U. S. 193.
It rejected, however, the publisher's argument that the exclusion
of these workers precluded application of the law to the employees
of newspapers. The State here argues that
Oklahoma Press
establishes that the press cannot successfully challenge
regulations on the basis of the exemption of other enterprises. We
disagree. The exempt enterprises in
Oklahoma Press were
isolated exceptions, and not the rule. Here, everything is exempt
from the use tax on ink and paper, except the press.
[
Footnote 6]
It is true that our opinions rarely speculate on precisely how
the Framers would have analyzed a given regulation of expression.
In general, though, we have only limited evidence of exactly how
the Framers intended the First Amendment to apply. There are no
recorded debates in the Senate or in the States, and the discussion
in the House of Representatives was couched in general terms,
perhaps in response to Madison's suggestion that the
Representatives not stray from simple acknowledged principles.
See Constitution of the United States: Analysis and
Interpretation, S. Doc. No. 92-82, p. 936, and n. 5 (1973);
see
also Z. Chafee, Free Speech in the United States 16 (1941).
Consequently, we ordinarily simply apply those general principles,
requiring the government to justify any burdens on First Amendment
rights by showing that they are necessary to achieve a legitimate
overriding governmental interest,
see n 7,
infra. But when we do have evidence
that a particular law would have offended the Framers, we have not
hesitated to invalidate it on that ground alone. Prior restraints,
for instance, clearly strike to the core of the Framers' concerns,
leading this Court to treat them as particularly suspect.
Near
v. Minnesota ex rel. Olson, 283 U. S. 697,
283 U. S. 713,
283 U. S.
716-718 (1931);
cf. Grosjean v. American Press
Co., 297 U. S. 233
(1936) (relying on the role of the "taxes on knowledge" in
inspiring the First Amendment to strike down a contemporary tax on
knowledge).
[
Footnote 7]
JUSTICE REHNQUIST's dissent analyzes this case solely as a
problem of equal protection, applying the familiar tiers of
scrutiny.
Post at
460 U. S. 599-600. We, however, view the problem as one
arising directly under the First Amendment, for, as our discussion
shows, the Framers perceived singling out the press for taxation as
a means of abridging the freedom of the press,
see
n 6,
supra. The
appropriate method of analysis thus is to balance the burden
implicit in singling out the press against the interest asserted by
the State. Under a long line of precedents, the regulation can
survive only if the governmental interest outweighs the burden and
cannot be achieved by means that do not infringe First Amendment
rights as significantly.
See, e.g., United States v. Lee,
455 U. S. 252,
455 U. S.
257-258,
455 U. S. 259
(1982);
United States v. O'Brien, 391 U.
S. 367,
391 U. S.
376-377;
NAACP v. Alabama ex rel. Patterson,
357 U. S. 449
(1958).
[
Footnote 8]
Cf. United States v. Lee, supra, (generally applicable
tax may be applied to those with religious objections).
[
Footnote 9]
Star Tribune insists that the premise of the State's argument --
that a generally applicable sales tax would be constitutional -- is
incorrect, citing
Follett v. McCormick, 321 U.
S. 573 (1944),
Murdock v. Pennsylvania,
319 U. S. 105
(1943), and
Jones v. Opelika, 319 U.
S. 103 (1943). We think that
Breard v.
Alexandria, 341 U. S. 622
(1951), is more relevant, and rebuts Star Tribune's argument.
There, we upheld an ordinance prohibiting door-to-door solicitation
even though it applied to prevent the door-to-door sale of
subscriptions to magazines, an activity covered by the First
Amendment. Although
Martin v. Struthers, 319 U.
S. 141 (1943), had struck down a similar ordinance as
applied to the distribution of free religious literature, the
Breard Court explained that case as emphasizing that the
information distributed was religious in nature, and that the
distribution was noncommercial. 341 U.S. at
341 U. S.
642-643. As the dissent in
Breard recognized,
the majority opinion substantially undercut both
Martin
and the cases now relied upon by Star Tribune, in which the Court
had invalidated ordinances imposing a flat license tax on the sale
of religious literature.
See 341 U.S. at
341 U. S.
649-650 (Black, J., dissenting) ("Since this decision
cannot be reconciled with the
Jones, Murdock and
Martin v. Struthers cases, it seems to me that good
judicial practice calls for their forthright overruling"). Whatever
the value of those cases as authority after
Breard, we
think them distinguishable from a generally applicable sales tax.
In each of those cases, the local government imposed a flat tax,
unrelated to the receipts or income of the speaker or to the
expenses of administering a valid regulatory scheme, as a
condition of the right to speak. By imposing the tax as a
condition of engaging in protected activity, the defendants in
those cases imposed a form of prior restraint on speech, rendering
the tax highly susceptible to constitutional challenge.
Follett, supra, at
321 U. S.
576-578;
Murdock, supra, at
319 U. S. 112,
319 U. S.
113-114;
Jones v. Opelika, 316 U.
S. 584,
316 U. S. 609,
316 U. S. 611
(1942) (Stone, C.J., dissenting), reasoning approved on rehearing
in
319 U. S. 103
(1943);
see Grosjean v. American Press Co., 297 U.S. at
297 U. S. 249;
see generally Near v. Minnesota ex rel. Olson,
283 U. S. 697
(1931). In that regard, the cases cited by Star Tribune do not
resemble a generally applicable sales tax. Indeed, our cases have
consistently recognized that nondiscriminatory taxes on the
receipts or income of newspapers would be permissible,
Branzburg v. Hayes, 408 U. S. 665,
408 U. S. 683
(1972) (dictum);
Grosjean v. American Press Co., supra, at
297 U. S. 250
(dictum);
cf. Follett, supra, at
321 U. S. 578
(preacher subject to taxes on income or property) (dictum);
Murdock, supra, at
319 U. S. 112
(same) (dictum).
[
Footnote 10]
JUSTICE REHNQUIST's dissent explains that collecting sales taxes
on newspapers entails special problems because of the unusual
marketing practices for newspapers -- sales from vending machines
and at newsstands, for instance.
Post at
460 U. S. 602.
The dissent does not, however, explain why the State cannot resolve
these problems by using the same methods used for items like
chewing gum and candy, marketed in these same unusual ways and
subject to the sales tax,
see Minn.Stat. §§ 297 A. 01
(3)(c)(vi), (viii) (1982) (defining the sale of food from vending
machines as a sale);
see also § 297 A. 04 (dealing with
vending machine operators).
Further, JUSTICE REHNQUIST fears that the imposition of a sales
tax will mean that vending machine prices will be 26 cents instead
of 25 cents; or prices will be 30 cents, with publishers retaining
an extra 4 cents per paper; or the price will be 25 cents, with
publishers absorbing the tax.
Post at
460 U. S. 602.
It is difficult to see how the use tax rectifies this problem, for
it increases publishers' costs. If the increase is a penny, the use
taxes forces publishers to choose to pass the exact increment along
to consumers by raising the price of the finished product to 26
cents; or to increase the price by a nickel and retain an extra 4
cents per paper; or to leave the price at 25 cents and absorb the
tax.
[
Footnote 11]
JUSTICE REHNQUIST's dissent deprecates this concern, asserting
that there is no threat, because this Court will invalidate any
differentially more burdensome tax.
Post at
460 U. S. 601.
That assertion would provide more security if we could be certain
that courts will always prove able to identify differentially more
burdensome taxes, a question we explore further
infra.
[
Footnote 12]
We have not always avoided evaluating the relative burdens of
different methods of taxation in certain cases involving state
taxation of the Federal Government and those with whom it does
business.
See Washington v. United States, ante, p.
460 U. S. 536;
United States v. County of Fresno, 429 U.
S. 452 (1977). Since
McCulloch
v. Maryland, 4 Wheat. 316 (1819), the Supremacy
Clause has prohibited not only state taxation that discriminates
against the Federal Government, but also any direct taxation of the
Federal Government.
See generally United States v. New
Mexico, 455 U. S. 720,
455 U. S.
730-734 (1982). In spite of the rule against direct
taxation of the Federal Government, States remain free to impose
the
economic incidence of a tax on the Federal Government,
as long as that tax is not discriminatory.
E.g., id. at
455 U. S.
734-735, and n. 11;
United States v. County of
Fresno, supra, at
429 U. S. 460.
In that situation, then, the valid state interest in requiring
federal enterprises to bear their share of the tax burden will
often justify the use of differential methods of taxation. As we
explained in
Washington v. United States, "[Washington]
has merely accommodated for the fact that it may not impose a tax
directly on the United States. . . ."
Ante at
460 U. S. 546.
The special rule prohibiting direct taxation of the Federal
Government but permitting the imposition of an equivalent economic
burden on the Government may not only justify the State's use of
different methods of taxation, but may also force us, within
limits,
see Washington, ante at
460 U. S. 546,
n. 11, to compare the burdens of two different taxes. Nothing,
however, prevents the State from taxing the press in the same
manner that it taxes other enterprises. It can achieve its interest
in requiring the press to bear its share of the burden by taxing
the press as it taxes others, so differential taxation is not
necessary to achieve its goals.
JUSTICE WHITE insists that the Court regularly inquires into the
economic effect of taxes, relying on a number of cases arising
under the Due Process Clause and the Commerce Clause. In the cases
cited, the Court has struck down state taxes only when "[t]he
inequality of the . . . tax burden between in-state and
out-of-state manufacturer-users [was] admitted,"
Halliburton
Oil Well Cementing Co. v. Reily, 373 U. S.
64,
373 U. S. 70
(1963), and when the Court was able to see that the tax produced a
"
grossly distorted result,"
Norfolk & Western R.
Co. v. Missouri State Tax Comm'n, 390 U.
S. 317,
390 U. S. 326
(1968) (emphasis added). In these cases, the Court required the
taxpayer to show "gross overreaching," recognizing "the vastness of
the State's taxing power and the latitude that the exercise of that
power must be given before it encounters constitutional
restraints."
Ibid.; see Alaska v. Arctic Maid,
366 U. S. 199,
366 U. S. 205
(1961). When delicate and cherished First Amendment rights are at
stake, however, the constitutional tolerance for error diminishes
drastically, and the risk increases that courts will prove unable
to apply accurately the more finely tuned standards.
[
Footnote 13]
If a State employed the same
method of taxation, but
applied a lower
rate to the press, so that there could be
no doubt that the legislature was not singling out the press to
bear a more burdensome tax, we would, of course, be in a position
to evaluate the relative burdens. And, given the clarity of the
relative burdens, as well as the rule that differential methods of
taxation are not automatically permissible if less burdensome, a
lower tax rate for the press would not raise the threat that the
legislature might later impose an extra burden that would escape
detection by the courts,
see supra at
460 U. S. 588,
and n. 11. Thus, our decision does not, as the dissent suggests,
require Minnesota to impose a greater tax burden on
publications.
[
Footnote 14]
Disparaging our concern with the complexities of economic proof,
JUSTICE REHNQUIST's dissent undertakes to calculate a hypothetical
sales tax liability for Star Tribune for the years 1974 and 1975.
Post at
460 U. S.
597-598. That undertaking, we think, illustrates some of
the problems that inhere in any such inquiry,
see
generally R. Musgrave & P. Musgrave, Public Finance in
Theory and Practice 461 (2d ed. 1976) (detailing some of the
complexities of calculating the burden of a tax);
cf. id.
at 475 (in evaluating excess burden of taxes, "qualitative evidence
is sketchy and underlying procedures are necessarily crude").
First, the calculation for 1974 and 1975 for this newspaper tells
us nothing about the relative impact of the tax on other newspapers
or in other years. Since newspapers receive a substantial portion
of their revenues from advertising,
see generally
Newsprint Information Committee, Newspaper and Newsprint Facts at a
Glance 12 (24th ed.1982), it is not necessarily true even for
profitable newspapers that the price of the finished product will
exceed the cost of inputs. Consequently, it is not necessary that a
tax imposed on components is less burdensome than a tax at the same
rate imposed on the price of the product. Although the relationship
of Star Tribune's revenues from circulation and its revenues from
advertising may result in a lower tax burden under the use tax in
1974 and 1975, that relationship need not hold for all newspapers
or for all time.
Second, if, as the dissent assumes elsewhere,
post at
460 U. S. 602,
the sales tax increases the price, that price increase presumably
will cause a decrease in demand. The decrease in demand may lead to
lower total revenues and, therefore, to a lower total sales tax
burden than that calculated by the dissent.
See generally
P. Samuelson, Economics 381-383, 389-390 (10th ed.1976); R.
Musgrave & P. Musgrave, Public Finance in Theory and Practice
21 (3d ed.1980) ("[I]t is necessary, in designing fiscal policies,
to allow for how the private sector will respond"). The dissent's
calculations, then, can only be characterized as hypothetical.
Taking the chance that these calculations or others like them are
erroneous is a risk that the First Amendment forbids.
[
Footnote 15]
In 1974, 11 publishers paid the tax. Three paid less than
$1,000, and another three paid less than $8,000. Star Tribune, one
of only two publishers paying more than $100,000, paid $608,634. In
1975, 13 publishers paid the tax. Again, three paid less than
$1,000, and four more paid less than $3,000. For that year, Star
Tribune paid $636,113 and was again one of only two publishers
incurring a liability greater than $100,000.
See 314
N.W.2d at 203-204, and nn. 4, 5.
[
Footnote 16]
Cf. Mabee v. White Plains Publishing Co., 327 U.
S. 178,
327 U. S. 183,
327 U. S. 184
(1946) (upholding exemption from Fair Labor Standards Act of small
weekly and semiweekly newspapers where the purpose of the exemption
was "to put those papers more on a parity with other small town
enterprises").
[
Footnote 17]
This conclusion renders it unnecessary to address Star Tribune's
arguments that the $100,000 exemption violates the principles of
Buckley v. Valeo, 424 U. S. 1 (1976),
and
Stewart Dry Goods Co. v. Lewis, 294 U.
S. 550 (1935).
JUSTICE WHITE, concurring in part and dissenting in part.
This case is not difficult. The exemption for the first $100,000
of paper and ink limits the burden of the Minnesota tax to only a
few papers. This feature alone is sufficient reason to invalidate
the Minnesota tax and reverse the judgment of the Minnesota Supreme
Court. The Court recognizes that Minnesota's tax violates the First
Amendment for this reason, and I subscribe to
460 U.
S.
Having found fully sufficient grounds for decision, the Court
need go no further. The question whether Minnesota or another State
may impose a use tax on paper and ink that is not targeted on a
small group of newspapers could be left for another day.
The Court, however, undertakes the task today. The crux of the
issue is whether Minnesota has justified imposing a use tax on
paper and ink in lieu of applying its general sales tax to
publications. The Court concludes that the State has offered no
satisfactory explanation for selecting a substitute for a sales
tax.
Ante at
460 U. S. 587.
If this is so, that could be the end of the matter, and the
Minnesota tax would be invalid for a second reason.
The Court nevertheless moves on to opine that the State could
not impose such a tax even if "the effective burden was no
different from that on other taxpayers or the burden on the press
was lighter than that on other businesses."
Page 460 U. S. 594
Ante at
460 U. S. 588.
The fear is that the government might use the tax as a threatened
sanction to achieve a censorial purpose. As JUSTICE REHNQUIST
demonstrates,
post at
460 U. S.
601-602, the proposition that the government threatens
the First Amendment by favoring the press is most questionable, but
for the sake of argument, I let it pass.
Despite having struck down the tax for three separate reasons,
the Court is still not finished. "A second reason" to eschew
inquiry into the relative burden of taxation is presented. The
Court submits that "courts as institutions are poorly equipped to
evaluate with precision the relative burdens of various methods of
taxation,"
ante at
460 U. S. 589,
except, it seems, in cases involving the sovereign immunity of the
United States. Why this is so is not made clear, and I do not agree
that the courts are so incompetent to evaluate the burdens of
taxation that we must decline the task in this case.
The Court acknowledges that, in cases involving state taxation
of the Federal Government and those with whom it does business, the
Court has compared the burden of two different taxes.
Ante
at
460 U. S. 589,
n. 12.
See, e.g., United States v. County of Fresno,
429 U. S. 452
(1977);
United States v. City of Detroit, 355 U.
S. 466 (1958). It is not apparent to me why we are able
to determine whether a State has imposed the economic incidence of
a tax in a discriminatory fashion upon the Federal Government, but
incompetent to determine whether a tax imposes discriminatory
treatment upon the press. The Court's rationale that these are a
unique set of cases which nevertheless "force us" to assume a duty
we are incompetent to perform is wholly unsatisfactory. If
convinced of its inherent incapacity for tax analysis, the Court
could have taken the path chosen today and simply prohibited the
States from imposing a compensatory "equivalent" economic burden on
those who deal with the Federal Government. It has not done so.
Moreover, the Court frequently has examined -- without complaint
-- the actual effect of a tax in determining whether the State has
imposed an impermissible burden on interstate
Page 460 U. S. 595
commerce or run afoul of the Due Process Clause. [
Footnote 2/1] In a number of cases
concerning railroad taxes, for example, the Court considered the
tax burden to decide whether it was the equivalent of a property
tax or an invalid tax on interstate commerce. [
Footnote 2/2] The Court has compared the burden of
use taxes on competing products from sister States with that of
sales taxes on products sold in-state to decide whether the former
constituted discrimination against interstate commerce.
Henneford v. Silas Mason Co., 300 U.
S. 577 (1937). [
Footnote
2/3] We have also measured tax burdens in our cases considering
whether state tax formulas are so out of proportion
Page 460 U. S. 596
to the amount of in-state business as to violate due process.
See, e.g., Moorman Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437 U.
S. 267 (1978);
Hans Rees' Sons, Inc. v. North
Carolina, 283 U. S. 123
(1931). In sum, the Court's professed inability to determine when a
tax poses an actual threat to constitutional principles is a novel
concept, and one belied by the lessons of our experience.
There may be cases, I recognize, where the Court cannot
confidently ascertain whether a differential method of taxation
imposes a greater burden upon the press than a generally applicable
tax. In these circumstances, I too may be unwilling to entrust
freedom of the press to uncertain economic proof. But, as JUSTICE
REHNQUIST clearly shows,
post at
460 U. S.
597-598, this is not such a case. Since it is plainly
evident that Minneapolis Star is not disadvantaged and is almost
certainly benefited by a use tax
vis-a-vis a sales tax, I
cannot agree that the First Amendment forbids a State to choose one
method of taxation over another.
[
Footnote 2/1]
See, e.g., Alaska v. Arctic Maid, 366 U.
S. 199 (1961) (Alaska occupational tax collected from
freezer ships at rate of 4% of value of salmon not discriminatory
because Alaskan canneries pay a 6% tax on the value of salmon
obtained for canning).
[
Footnote 2/2]
See Norfolk & Western R. Co. v. Missouri State Tax
Comm'n, 390 U. S. 317,
390 U. S. 329
(1968) (holding property tax on rolling stock based on a mileage
formula violated due process) ("[W]hen a taxpayer comes forward
with strong evidence tending to prove that the mileage formula will
yield a grossly distorted result in a particular case, the State is
obliged to counter that evidence . . .");
Great Northern R. Co.
v. Minnesota, 278 U. S. 503,
278 U. S. 509
(1929) ("We find nothing in the record to indicate that the tax
under consideration, plus that already collected, exceeds
what
would be legitimate as an ordinary tax on the property valued as
part of a going concern, [or is] relatively higher than the taxes
on other kinds of property.' Pullman Co. v. Richardson,
261 U. S. 330,
261 U. S.
339"). See also Pullman Co. v. Richardson,
261 U. S. 330,
261 U. S. 339
(1923); Cudahy Packing Co. v. Minnesota, 246 U.
S. 450, 246 U. S.
453-455 (1918); United States Express Co. v.
Minnesota, 223 U. S. 335
(1912); Galveston, H. & S. A. R. Co. v. Texas,
210 U. S. 217
(1908).
[
Footnote 2/3]
In
Henneford, a 2% tax was imposed on the privilege of
using products coming from other States. Excepted from the tax was
any property, the sale or use of which had already been subjected
to an equal or greater tax. The Court, speaking through Justice
Cardozo, upheld the use tax, noting that,
"[w]hen the account is made up, the stranger from afar is
subject to no greater burdens as a consequence of ownership than
the dweller within the gates."
300 U.S. at
300 U. S.
583-584.
See also Halliburton Oil Well Cementing Co.
v. Reily, 373 U. S. 64 (1963)
(holding use tax burden went beyond sales tax and constituted
invalid discriminatory burden on commerce);
Scripto v.
Carson, 362 U. S. 207
(1960) (upholding use tax as complement to sales tax).
JUSTICE REHNQUIST, dissenting.
Today we learn from the Court that a State runs afoul of the
First Amendment proscription of laws "abridging the freedom of
speech, or of the press" where the State structures its taxing
system to the advantage of newspapers. This seems very much akin to
protecting something so overzealously that, in the end, it is
smothered. While the Court purports to rely on the intent of the
"Framers of the First Amendment," I believe it safe to assume that,
in 1791, "abridge" meant the same thing it means today: to diminish
or curtail. Not until the Court's decision in this case, nearly two
centuries after adoption of the First Amendment, has it been read
to prohibit activities which in no way diminish or curtail the
freedoms it protects.
I agree with the Court that the First Amendment does not
per
se prevent the State of Minnesota from regulating the press
even though such regulation imposes an economic burden. It is
evident from the numerous cases relied on by the
Page 460 U. S. 597
Court, which I need not repeat here, that this principle has
been long settled.
Ante at
460 U. S. 581.
I further agree with the Court that application of general sales
and use taxes to the press would be sanctioned under this line of
cases.
Ante at
460 U. S.
586-587, n. 9. Therefore, I also agree with the Court to
the extent it holds that any constitutional attack on the Minnesota
scheme must be aimed at the classifications used in that taxing
scheme.
Ante at
460 U. S. 583.
But it is at this point that I part company with my colleagues.
The Court recognizes in several parts of its opinion that the
State of Minnesota could avoid constitutional problems by imposing
on newspapers the 4-cent sales tax that it imposes on other
retailers.
Ante at
460 U. S.
586-590, and nn. 9, 13. Rather than impose such a tax,
however, the Minnesota Legislature decided to provide newspapers
with an exemption from the sales tax and impose a 4% use tax on ink
and paper; thus, while both taxes are part of one "system of sales
and use taxes,"
314 N.W.2d
201, 203 (1981), newspapers are classified differently within
that system.* The problem the Court finds too difficult to deal
with is whether this difference in treatment results in a
significant burden on newspapers.
The record reveals that, in 1974, the Minneapolis Star &
Tribune had an average daily circulation of 489,345 copies.
Id. at 203-204, nn. 4 and 5. Using the price we were
informed of at argument of 25 cents per copy,
see Tr. of
Oral Arg. 46, gross sales revenue for the year would be
$38,168,910. The Sunday circulation for 1974 was 640,756; even
assuming that it did not sell for more than the daily paper, gross
sales revenue for the year would be at least $8,329,828. Thus,
total sales revenues in 1974 would be $46,498,738. Had a 4% sales
tax
Page 460 U. S. 598
been imposed, the Minneapolis Star & Tribune would have been
liable for $1,859,950 in 1974. The same "complexities of factual
economic proof" can be analyzed for 1975. Daily circulation was
481,789; at 25 cents per copy, gross sales revenue for the year
would be $37,579,542. The Sunday circulation for 1975 was 619,154;
at 25 cents per copy, gross sales revenue for the year would be
$8,049,002. Total sales revenues in 1975 would be $45,628,544; at a
4% rate, the sales tax for 1975 would be $1,825,142. Therefore, had
the sales tax been imposed, as the Court agrees would have been
permissible, the Minneapolis Star & Tribune's liability for
1974 and 1975 would have been $3,685,092.
The record further indicates that the Minneapolis Star &
Tribune paid $608,634 in use taxes in 1974 and $636,113 in 1975 --
a total liability of $1,244,747.
See 314 N.W.2d at
203-204, nn. 4 and 5. We need no expert testimony from modern day
Euclids or Einsteins to determine that the $1,224,747 paid in use
taxes is significantly less burdensome than the $3,685,092 that
could have been levied by a sales tax.
A fortiori, the
Minnesota taxing scheme which singles out newspapers for
"differential treatment" has benefited, not burdened, the "freedom
of speech, [and] of the press."
Ignoring these calculations, the Court concludes that
"differential treatment" alone in Minnesota's sales and use tax
scheme requires that the statutes be found "presumptively
unconstitutional" and declared invalid "unless the State asserts a
counterbalancing interest of compelling importance that it cannot
achieve without differential taxation."
Ante at
460 U. S. 585.
The "differential treatment" standard that the Court has conjured
up is unprecedented and unwarranted. To my knowledge, this Court
has never subjected governmental action to the most stringent
constitutional review solely on the basis of "differential
treatment" of particular groups. The case relied on by the Court,
Police Department of Chicago v. Mosley, 408 U. S.
92,
408 U. S. 95-96
(1972), certainly does not stand for this proposition. In
Mosley, all picketing except "peaceful picketing" was
prohibited within a particular public area.
Page 460 U. S. 599
Thus, "differential treatment" was not the key to the Court's
decision; rather the essential fact was that, unless a person was
considered a "peaceful picketer," his speech through this form of
expression would be totally abridged within the area.
Of course, all governmentally created classifications must have
some "rational basis."
See Williamson v. Lee Optical Co.,
348 U. S. 483
(1955);
Railway Express Agency, Inc. v. New York,
336 U. S. 106
(1949). The fact that they have been enacted by a presumptively
rational legislature, however, arms them with a presumption of
rationality. We have shown the greatest deference to state
legislatures in devising their taxing schemes. As we said in
Allied Stores of Ohio, Inc. v. Bowers, 358 U.
S. 522 (1959):
"The States have a very wide discretion in the laying of their
taxes. When dealing with their proper domestic concerns, and not
trenching upon the prerogatives of the National Government or
violating the guaranties of the Federal Constitution, the States
have the attribute of sovereign powers in devising their fiscal
systems to ensure revenue and foster their local interests. . . .
The State may impose different specific taxes upon different trades
and professions, and may vary the rate of excise upon various
products. It is not required to resort to close distinctions or to
maintain a precise, scientific uniformity with reference to
composition, use or value. [Citations omitted.] 'To hold otherwise
would be to subject the essential taxing power of the State to an
intolerable supervision, hostile to the basic principles of our
Government. . . .'"
Id. at
358 U. S.
526-527 (quoting
Ohio Oil Co. v. Conway,
281 U. S. 146,
281 U. S. 159
(1930)).
See also Kahn v. Shevin, 416 U.
S. 351 (1974);
Independent Warehouses, Inc. v.
Scheele, 331 U. S. 70
(1947);
Madden v. Kentucky, 309 U. S.
83 (1940);
Fox v. Standard Oil Co. of New
Jersey, 294 U. S. 87
(1935);
New York Rapid Transit Corp. v. City of New York,
303 U. S. 573
(1938).
Page 460 U. S. 600
Where the State devises classifications that infringe on the
fundamental guarantees protected by the Constitution the Court has
demanded more of the State in justifying its action. But there is
no
infringement, and thus the Court has never required
more, unless the State's classifications
significantly
burden these specially protected rights. As we said in
Massachusetts Board of Retirement v. Murgia, 427 U.
S. 307,
427 U. S. 312
(1976) (per curiam) (emphasis added),
"equal protection analysis requires strict scrutiny of a
legislative classification only when the classification
impermissibly interferes with the exercise of a
fundamental right. . . ."
See also California Medical Assn. v. FEC, 453 U.
S. 182 (1981);
Maher v. Roe, 432 U.
S. 464 (1977);
Storer v. Brown, 415 U.
S. 724 (1974);
American Party of Texas v.
White, 415 U. S. 767
(1974);
San Antonio Independent School District v.
Rodriguez, 411 U. S. 1 (1973).
To state it in terms of the freedoms at issue here, no First
Amendment issue is raised unless First Amendment rights have been
infringed; for if there has been no infringement, then there has
been no "abridgment" of those guarantees.
See Branzburg v.
Hayes, 408 U. S. 665
(1972).
Today, the Court departs from this rule, refusing to look at the
record and determine whether the classifications in the Minnesota
use and sales tax statutes significantly burden the First Amendment
rights of appellant and its fellow newspapers. The Court offers as
an explanation for this failure the self-reproaching conclusion
that
"courts as institutions are poorly equipped to evaluate with
precision the relative burdens of various methods of taxation. The
complexities of factual economic proof always present a certain
potential for error, and courts have little familiarity with the
process of evaluating the relative economic burden of taxes. In
sum, the possibility of error inherent in the proposed rule poses
too great a threat to concerns at the heart of the First Amendment,
and we cannot tolerate that possibility. Minnesota,
Page 460 U. S. 601
therefore, has offered no adequate justification for the special
treatment of newspapers."
Ante at
460 U. S.
589-590 (footnotes omitted). Considering the complexity
of issues this Court resolves each Term, this admonition as a
general rule is difficult to understand. Considering the specifics
of this case, this confession of inability is incomprehensible.
Wisely not relying solely on its inability to weigh the burdens
of the Minnesota tax scheme, the Court also says that, even if the
resultant burden on the press is lighter than on others,
"the very selection of the press for special treatment threatens
the press not only with the current
differential
treatment, but also with the possibility of subsequent
differentially
more burdensome treatment. Thus, even
without actually imposing an extra burden on the press, the
government might be able to achieve censorial effects, for '[t]he
threat of sanctions may deter [the] exercise [of First Amendment
rights] almost as potently as the actual application of
sanctions.'"
Ante at
460 U. S. 588.
Surely the Court does not mean what it seems to say. The Court
should be well aware from its discussion of
Grosjean v.
American Press Co., 297 U. S. 233
(1936), that this Court is quite capable of dealing with changes in
state taxing laws which are intended to penalize newspapers. As
Justice Holmes aptly put it:
"[T]his Court, which so often has defeated the attempt to tax in
certain ways, can defeat an attempt to discriminate or otherwise go
too far without wholly abolishing the power to tax. The power to
tax is not the power to destroy while this Court sits."
Panhandle Oil Co. v. Knox, 277 U.
S. 218,
277 U. S. 223
(1928) (dissenting opinion). Furthermore, the Court itself
intimates that, if the State had employed
"the same
method of taxation, but applied a lower
rate to the press, so that there could be no doubt that
the legislature was not singling out the press to bear a more
burdensome
Page 460 U. S. 602
tax,"
the taxing scheme would be constitutionally permissible.
Ante at
460 U. S. 590,
n. 13. This obviously has the same potential for "the threat of
sanctions," because the legislature could at any time raise the
taxes to the higher rate. Likewise, the newspapers' absolute
exemption from the sales tax, which the Court acknowledges is used
by many other States, would be subject to the same attack; the
exemption could be taken away.
The State is required to show that its taxing scheme is
rational. But in this case, that showing can be made easily. The
Court states that
"[t]he court below speculated that the State might have been
concerned that collection of a [sales] tax on such small
transactions would be impractical."
Ante at
460 U. S. 587.
But the Court finds this argument "unpersuasive," because "sales of
other low-priced goods" are subject to the sales tax.
Ibid. I disagree. There must be few such inexpensive items
sold in Minnesota in the volume of newspaper sales. Minneapolis
Star & Tribune alone, as noted above, sold approximately
489,345 papers every weekday in 1974, and sold another 640,756
papers every Sunday. In 1975, it had a daily circulation of 481,789
and a Sunday circulation of 619,154. Further, newspapers are
commonly sold in a different way than other goods. The legislature
could have concluded that paperboys, corner newsstands, and vending
machines provide an unreliable and unsuitable means for collection
of a sales tax. Must everyone buying a paper put 26 cents in the
vending machine, rather than 25 cents; or should the price of a
paper be raised to 30 cents, giving the paper 4-cent more profit;
or should the price be kept at 25 cents, with the paper absorbing
the tax? In summary, so long as the State can find another way to
collect revenue from the newspapers, imposing a sales tax on
newspapers would be to no one's advantage; not the newspaper and
its distributors, who would have to collect the tax, not the State,
who would have to enforce collection, and not the consumer, who
would have to pay for the paper in odd amounts. The reasonable
alternative Minnesota chose was to impose the use tax on ink and
paper.
"There is no reason
Page 460 U. S. 603
to believe that this legislative choice is insufficiently
tailored to achieve the goal of raising revenue or that it burdens
the first amendment in any way whatsoever."
314 N.W.2d at 207.
Cf. Minnesota v. Clover Leaf Creamery
Co., 449 U. S. 456
(1981).
The Court finds in very summary fashion that the exemption
newspapers receive for the first $100,000 of ink and paper used
also violates the First Amendment because the result is that only a
few of the newspapers actually pay a use tax. I cannot agree. As
explained by the Minnesota Supreme Court, the exemption is, in
effect, a $4,000 credit which benefits all newspapers. 314 N.W.2d
at 203. Minneapolis Star & Tribune was benefited to the amount
of $16,000 in the two years in question; $4,000 each year for its
morning paper and $4,000 each year for its evening paper.
Ibid. Absent any improper motive on the part of the
Minnesota Legislature in drawing the limits of this exemption, it
cannot be construed as violating the First Amendment.
See
Oklahoma Press Publishing Co. v. Walling, 327 U.
S. 186,
327 U. S. 194
(1946).
Cf. Mabee v. White Plains Publishing Co.,
327 U. S. 178
(1946). The Minnesota Supreme Court specifically found that the
exemption was not a "deliberate and calculated device" designed
with an illicit purpose. 314 N.W.2d at 208. There is nothing in the
record which would cast doubt on this conclusion. The Minnesota
court further explained:
"[I]t is necessary for the legislature to construct economically
sound taxes in order to raise revenue. In order to do so, the
legislature must classify or grant exemptions to insure that the
burden upon the taxpayer in paying the tax or upon the state in
collecting the tax does not outweigh the benefit of the revenues to
the state."
"Traditionally, classification has been a device for fitting tax
programs to local needs and usages in order to achieve an equitable
distribution of the tax burden."
"
Madden v. Kentucky, 309 U. S. 83,
309 U. S.
88 (1940)."
Id. at 209-210.
Page 460 U. S. 604
There is no reason to conclude that the State, in drafting the
$4,000 credit, acted other than reasonably and rationally to fit
its sales and use tax scheme to its own local needs and usages.
To collect from newspapers their fair share of taxes under the
sales and use tax scheme, and at the same time avoid abridging the
freedoms of speech and press, the Court holds today that Minnesota
must subject newspapers to millions of additional dollars in sales
tax liability. Certainly this is a hollow victory for the
newspapers, and I seriously doubt the Court's conclusion that this
result would have been intended by the "Framers of the First
Amendment."
For the reasons set forth above, I would affirm the judgment of
the Minnesota Supreme Court.
* The sales tax exemption and use tax liability are not,
strictly speaking, for newspapers alone. The term of art used in
the Minnesota taxing scheme is "publications." Publications is
defined to include such materials as magazines, advertising
supplements, shoppers guides, house organs, trade and professional
journals, and serially issued comic books.
See Minn.Stat.
§ 331.02 (1982); 13 Minn.Code of Agency Rules, Tax S & U 409(b)
(1979).