Section 6(b)(5) of the Occupational Safety and Health Act of
1970 (Act) requires the Secretary of Labor (Secretary), in
promulgating occupational safety and health standards dealing with
toxic materials or harmful physical agents, to set the standard
"which most adequately assures, to the extent feasible, on the
basis of the best available evidence" that no employee will suffer
material impairment of health. Section 3(8) of the Act defines the
term "occupational safety and health standard" as meaning a
standard which requires conditions, or the adoption or use of
practices, means, methods, operations, or processes, "reasonably
necessary or appropriate" to provide safe or healthful employment
and places of employment. Section 6(f) of the Act provides that the
Secretary's determinations "shall be conclusive if supported by
substantial evidence in the record considered as a whole." The
Secretary, acting through the Occupational Safety and Health
Administration (OSHA), promulgated the so-called Cotton Dust
Standard limiting occupational exposure to cotton dust (an airborne
particle byproduct of the preparation and manufacture of cotton
products), exposure to which induces byssinosis, a serious and
potentially disabling respiratory disease known in its more severe
manifestations as "brown lung" disease. Estimates indicate that at
least 35,000 employed and retired cotton mill workers, or 1 in 12,
suffer from the most disabling form of byssinosis, and 100,000
employed and retired workers suffer from some form of the disease.
The Standard sets permissible exposure levels to cotton dust for
the different operations in the cotton industry. Implementation of
the Standard depends primarily on a mix of engineering controls,
such as installation of ventilation systems, and work practice
controls, such as special floor-sweeping procedures. During the
4-year interim period permitted for full compliance with the
Standard, employers are required to provide respirators to
employees and to transfer employees
Page 452 U. S. 491
unable to wear respirators to another position, if available,
having a dust level that meets the Standard's permissible exposure
limit, with no loss of earnings or other employment rights or
benefits. OSHA estimated the total industrywide cost of compliance
as $656.5 million. Petitioners, representing the cotton industry,
challenged the validity of the Standard in the Court of Appeals,
contending,
inter alia, that the Act requires OSHA to
demonstrate that the Standard reflects a reasonable relationship
between the costs and benefits associated with the Standard, that
OSHA's determination of the Standard's "economic feasibility" was
not supported by substantial evidence, and that the wage guarantee
requirement was beyond OSHA's authority. The Court of Appeals
upheld the Standard in all major respects. It held that the Act did
not require OSHA to compare costs and benefits; that Congress
itself balanced the costs and benefits in its mandate to OSHA under
§ 6(b)(5) to adopt the most protective feasible standard; and that
OSHA's determination of economic feasibility was supported by
substantial evidence in the record as a whole. The court also held
that OSHA had authority to require employers to guarantee
employees' wage and employment benefits following transfer because
of inability to wear a respirator.
Held:
1. Cost-benefit analysis by OSHA in promulgating a standard
under 6(b)(5) is not required by the Act because feasibility
analysis is. Pp.
452 U. S.
506-522.
(a) The plain meaning of the word "feasible" is "capable of
being done," and, thus, § 6(b)(5) directs the Secretary to issue
the standard that most adequately assures that no employee will
suffer material impairment of health, limited only by the extent to
which this is "capable of being done." In effect then, as the Court
of Appeals held, Congress itself defined the basic relationship
between costs and benefits by placing the "benefit" of the worker's
health above all other considerations save those making attainment
of this "benefit" unachievable. Any standard based on a balancing
of costs and benefits by the Secretary that strikes a different
balance than that struck by Congress would be inconsistent with the
command set forth in § 6(b)(5). Pp.
452 U. S.
508-512.
(b) Section 3(8), either alone or in tandem with § 6(b)(5), does
not incorporate a cost-benefit requirement for standards dealing
with toxic materials or harmful physical agents. Even if the phrase
"reasonably necessary or appropriate" in § 3(8) might be construed
to contemplate some balancing of costs and benefits, Congress
specifically chose in § 6(b)(5) to impose separate and additional
requirements for issuance of standards dealing with such materials
and agents: it required that those standards be issued to prevent
material health impairment
Page 452 U. S. 492
to the extent feasible. To interpret § 3(8) as imposing an
additional and overriding cost-benefit analysis requirement on the
issuance of § 6(b)(5) standards would eviscerate § 6(b)(5)'s "to
the extent feasible" requirement. Pp.
452 U. S.
512-513.
(c) The Act's legislative history supports the conclusion that
Congress itself, in § 6(b)(5), balanced the costs and benefits.
There is no indication whatsoever that Congress intended OSHA to
conduct its own cost-benefit analysis before promulgating a "toxic
material" or "harmful physical agent" standard. Rather, not only
does the history confirm that Congress meant "feasible," rather
than "cost-benefit," when it used the former term, but it also
shows that Congress understood that the Act would create
substantial costs for employers, yet intended to impose such costs
when necessary to create a safe and healthful working environment.
Pp.
452 U. S.
514-522.
2. Whether or not, in the first instance, this Court would find
OSHA's findings supported by substantial evidence, it cannot be
said that the Court of Appeals, on the basis of the whole record,
"misapprehended or grossly misapplied" the substantial evidence
test when it upheld such findings. Pp.
452 U. S.
522-536.
3. Whether or not OSHA has the underlying authority to
promulgate a wage guarantee requirement with respect to employees
who are transferred to another position when they are unable to
wear a respirator, OSHA failed to make the necessary determination
or statement of reasons that this requirement was related to
achievement of health and safety goals. Pp.
452 U. S.
536-540.
199 U.S. App.D.C. 54, 617 F.2d 636, affirmed in part, vacated in
part, and remanded.
BRENNAN, .J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
WHITE, MARSHALL, BLACKMUN, and STEVENS, JJ., joined. STEWART, J.,
filed a dissenting opinion,
post p
452 U. S. 541.
REHNQUIST, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which BURGER, C.J.,
joined,
post, p.
452 U. S. 543.
POWELL, J., took no part in the decision of the cases.
Page 452 U. S. 493
JUSTICE BRENNAN delivered the opinion of the Court.
Congress enacted the Occupational Safety and Health Act of 1970
(Act) "to assure so far as possible every working man and woman in
the Nation safe and healthful working conditions. . . ." § 2(b), 84
Stat. 1590, 29 U.S.C. § 651(b). The Act authorizes the Secretary of
Labor to establish, after notice and opportunity to comment,
mandatory nationwide standards governing health and safety in the
workplace. 29 U.S.C. §§ 655(a), (b). In 1978, the Secretary, acting
through the Occupational Safety and Health Administration
Page 452 U. S. 494
(OSHA,) [
Footnote 1]
promulgated a standard limiting occupational exposure to cotton
dust, an airborne particle byproduct of the preparation and
manufacture of cotton products, exposure to which induces a
"constellation of respiratory effects" known as "byssinosis." 43
Fed.Reg. 27352, col. 3 (1978). This disease was one of the
expressly recognized health hazards that led to passage of the Act.
S.Rep. No. 91-1282, p. 3 (1970), Legislative History of the
Occupational Safety and Health Act of 1970, p. 143 (Comm. Print
1971) (Leg.Hist.).
Petitioners in these consolidated cases, representing the
interests of the cotton industry, [
Footnote 2] challenged the validity of the "Cotton Dust
Standard" in the Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia
Circuit pursuant to § 6(f) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. § 65(f). They
contend in this Court, as they did below, that the Act requires
OSHA to demonstrate that its Standard reflects a reasonable
relationship between the costs and benefits associated with the
Standard. Respondents, the Secretary of Labor and two labor
organizations, [
Footnote 3]
counter that Congress balanced the costs and benefits in the Act
itself, and that the Act should therefore be construed not to
require
Page 452 U. S. 495
OSHA to do so. They interpret the Act as mandating that OSHA
enact the most protective standard possible to eliminate a
significant risk of material health impairment, subject to the
constraints of economic and technological feasibility. The Court of
Appeals held that the Act did not require OSHA to compare costs and
benefits.
AFL-CIO v. Marshall, 199 U.S.App.D.C. 54, 617
F.2d 636 (1979). We granted certiorari, 449 U.S. 817 (1980), to
resolve this important question, which was presented but not
decided in last Term's
Industrial Union Dept. v. American
Petroleum Institute, 448 U. S. 607
(1980), [
Footnote 4] and to
decide other issues related to the Cotton Dust Standard. [
Footnote 5]
I
Byssinosis, known in its more severe manifestations as "brown
lung" disease, is a serious and potentially disabling respiratory
disease primarily caused by the inhalation of cotton dust.
[
Footnote 6]
See 43
Fed.Reg. 27352-27354 (1978); Exhibit
Page 452 U. S. 496
6-16, App. 15-22. [
Footnote
7] Byssinosis is a "continuum . . . disease," 43 Fed.Reg.
27354, col. 2 (1978), that has been categorized into four grades.
[
Footnote 8] In its least
serious form, byssinosis produces both subjective symptoms, such as
chest tightness, shortness of breath, coughing, and wheezing, and
objective indications of loss of pulmonary functions.
Id.
at 27352, col. 2. In its most serious form, byssinosis is a chronic
and irreversible obstructive pulmonary disease, clinically similar
to chronic bronchitis or emphysema, and can be severely disabling.
Ibid. At worst, as is true of other respiratory diseases,
including bronchitis, emphysema, and asthma, byssinosis can create
an additional strain on cardiovascular functions and can contribute
to death from heart failure.
See Exhibit 6-73, App. 72
("there is an association between mortality and the extent of dust
exposure"). One authority has described the increasing seriousness
of byssinosis as follows:
"In the first few years of exposure [to cotton dust], symptoms
occur on Monday, or other days after absence
Page 452 U. S. 497
from the work environment; later, symptoms occur on other days
of the week; and eventually, symptoms are continuous, even in the
absence of dust exposure."
A. Bouhuys, Byssinosis in the United States, Exhibit 6-16, App.
15. [
Footnote 9]
While there is some uncertainty over the manner in which the
disease progresses from its least serious to its disabling grades,
it is likely that prolonged exposure contributes to the
progression. 43 Fed.Reg. 27354, cols. 1 and 2 (1978); Exhibit
Page 452 U. S. 498
6-27, App. 25; Exhibit 11, App. 152. It also appears that a
worker may suddenly contract a severe grade without experiencing
milder grades of the disease. Exhibit 41, App.192. [
Footnote 10]
Estimates indicate that at least 35,000 employed and retired
cotton mill workers, or 1 in 12 such workers, suffer from the most
disabling form of byssinosis. [
Footnote 11] 43 Fed.Reg. 27353, col. 3 (1978); Exhibit
124, App. 347. The Senate Report accompanying the Act cited
estimates that 100,000 active and retired workers suffer from some
grade of the disease. S.Rep. No. 91-1282, p. 3 (1970), Leg.Hist.
143. One study found that over 25% of a sample of active cotton
preparation and yarn manufacturing workers suffer at least some
form of the disease at a dust exposure level common prior to
adoption of the current Standard. 43 Fed.Reg. 27355, col. 3 (1978);
Exhibit 6-51, App. 44. [
Footnote
12] Other studies confirm these general findings on the
prevalence of byssinosis.
See, e.g., Ct. of App. J.A.
3683; Ex. 6-56,
id. at 376-385.
Not until the early 1960's was byssinosis recognized in the
United States as a distinct occupational hazard associated with
cotton mills. S.Rep. No. 91-1282,
supra, at 3,
Leg.Hist.
Page 452 U. S. 499
142 [
Footnote 13] In
1966, the American Conference of Governmental Industrial Hygienists
(ACGIH), a private organization, recommended that exposure to total
cotton dust [
Footnote 14] be
limited to a "threshold limit value" of 1,000 micrograms per cubic
meter of air (1,000 �g/m^3) averaged over an 8-hour workday.
See 43 Fed.Reg. 2731, col. 1 (1978). The United States
Government first regulated exposure to cotton dust in 1968, when
the Secretary of Labor, pursuant to the Walsh-Healey Act, 41 U.S.C.
§ 35(e), promulgated airborne contaminant threshold limit values,
applicable to public contractors, that included the 1,000 �g/m^3
limit for total cotton dust. 34 Fed.Reg. 7953 (1969). [
Footnote 15] Following passage of
the Act in 1970, the 1,000 �g/m^3 standard was adopted as an
"established Federal standard" under § 6(a) of the Act, 84 Stat.
1593, 29 U.S.C. § 65(a), a provision designed to guarantee
immediate protection of workers for the period between enactment of
the statute and promulgation of permanent standards. [
Footnote 16]
In 1974, ACGIH, adopting a new measurement unit of respirable,
rather than total, dust, lowered its previous exposure
Page 452 U. S. 500
limit recommendation to 200 �g/m^3 measured by a vertical
elutriator, a device that measures cotton dust particles 15 microns
or less in diameter. 43 Fed.Reg. 27351, col. 1, 27355, col. 2
(1978). [
Footnote 17] That
same year, the Director of the National Institute for Occupational
Safety and Health (NIOSH), [
Footnote 18] pursuant to the Act, 29 U.S.C. §§ 669(a)(3),
671 (d)(2), submitted to the Secretary of Labor a recommendation
for a cotton dust standard with a permissible exposure limit (PEL)
that "should be set at the lowest level feasible, but in no case at
an environmental concentration as high as 0.2 mg lint-free cotton
dust/cu m," or 200 �g/m^3 of lint-free respirable dust. [
Footnote 19] Ex. 1, Ct. of App. J.A.
11; 41 Fed.Reg. 56500, col. 1 (1976). Several months later, OSHA
published an Advance Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 39 Fed.Reg.
44769 (1974), requesting comments from interested parties on the
NIOSH recommendation and other related matters. Soon thereafter,
the Textile Worker's Union
Page 452 U. S. 501
of America, joined by the North Carolina Public Interest
Research Group, petitioned the Secretary, urging a more stringent
PEL of 100 �g/m^3.
On December 28, 1976, OSHA published a proposal to replace the
existing federal standard on cotton dust with a new permanent
standard, pursuant to § 6(b)(5) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. § 655(b)(5).
41 Fed.Reg. 56498. The proposed standard contained a PEL of 200
�g/m^3 of vertical elutriated lint-free respirable cotton dust for
all segments of the cotton industry.
Ibid. It also
suggested an implementation strategy for achieving the PEL that
relied on respirators for the short term and engineering controls
for the long-term.
Id. at 5656, cols. 2 and 3. OSHA
invited interested parties to submit written comments within a
90-day period. [
Footnote
20]
Following the comment period, OSHA conducted three hearings in
Washington, D.C., Greenville, Miss., and Lubbock, Tex., that lasted
over 14 days. Public participation was widespread, involving
representatives from industry and the workforce, scientists,
economists, industrial hygienists, and many others. By the time the
informal rulemaking procedure had terminated, OSHA had received 263
comments and 109 notices of intent to appear at the hearings. 43
Fed.Reg. 27351, col. 2 (1978). The voluminous record, composed of a
transcript of written and oral testimony, exhibits, and posthearing
comments and briefs, totaled some 105,000 pages. 199 U.S.App.D.C.
at 65, 617 F.2d at 647. OSHA issued its final Cotton Dust Standard
-- the one challenged in the instant case -- on June 23, 1978.
Along with an accompanying statement of findings and reasons, the
Standard occupied 69 pages of the Federal Register. 43 Fed.Reg.
2735-27418 (1978);
see 29 CFR § 1910.1043 (1980).
The Cotton Dust Standard promulgated by OSHA establishes
Page 452 U. S. 502
mandatory PEL's over an 8-hour period of 200 �g/m^3 for yarn
manufacturing, [
Footnote 21]
750 g/m^3 for slashing and weaving operations, and 500 �g/m^3 for
all other processes in the cotton industry. [
Footnote 22] 29 CFR § 1910.1043(c) (1980). These
levels represent a relaxation of the proposed PEL of 200 �g/m^3 for
all segments of the cotton industry.
OSHA chose an implementation strategy for the Standard that
depended primarily on a mix of engineering controls, such as
installation of ventilation systems, [
Footnote 23] and work practice controls, such as special
floor-sweeping procedures. Full compliance with the PEL's is
required within four years, except to the extent that employers can
establish that the engineering and work practice controls are
infeasible. § 1910.1043(e)(1). During this compliance period, and
at certain other
Page 452 U. S. 503
times, the Standard requires employers to provide respirators to
employees. 1910.1043(f). Other requirements include monitoring of
cotton dust exposure, medical surveillance of all employees, annual
medical examinations, employee education and training programs, and
the posting of warning signs. A specific provision also under
challenge in the instant case requires employers to transfer
employees unable to wear respirators to another position, if
available, having a dust level at or below the Standard's PEL's,
with "no loss of earnings or other employment rights or benefits as
a result of the transfer." § 1910.1043(f)(2)(v).
On the basis of the evidence in the record as a whole, the
Secretary determined that exposure to cotton dust represents a
"significant health hazard to employees," 43 Fed.Reg. 27350, col. 1
(1978), and that "the prevalence of byssinosis should be
significantly reduced" by the adoption of the Standard's PEL's,
id. at 27359, col. 3. In assessing the health risks from
cotton dust and the risk reduction obtained from lowered exposure,
OSHA relied particularly on data showing a strong linear
relationship between the prevalence of byssinosis and the
concentration of lint-free respirable cotton dust.
Id. at
27355-27359; Exhibit 6-51, App. 29-55.
See also Ex. 6-17,
Ct. of App. J.A. 235-245; Ex. 38D,
id. at 1492-1839. Even
at the 200 �g/m^3 PEL, OSHA found that the prevalence of at least
Grade 1/1 byssinosis would be 137% of all employees in the yarn
manufacturing sector. 43 Fed.Reg. 27359, cols. 2 and 3 (1978).
In promulgating the Cotton Dust Standard, OSHA interpreted the
Act to require adoption of the most stringent standard to protect
against material health impairment, bounded only by technological
and economic feasibility.
Id. at 27361, col. 3. OSHA
therefore rejected the industry's alternative proposal for a PEL of
500 �g/m^3 in yarn manufacturing, a proposal which would produce a
25% prevalence of at least Grade 1/2 byssinosis. The agency
expressly found the Standard to be both technologically and
economically feasible
Page 452 U. S. 504
based on the evidence in the record as a whole. Although
recognizing that permitted levels of exposure to cotton dust would
still cause some byssinosis, OSHA nevertheless rejected the union
proposal for a 100 �g/m^3 PEL because it was not within the
"technological capabilities of the industry."
Id. at
27359-27360. Similarly, OSHA set PEL's for some segments of the
cotton industry at 500 �g/m^3 in part because of limitations of
technological feasibility.
Id. at 27361, col. 3. Finally,
the Secretary found that "engineering dust controls in weaving may
not be feasible even with massive expenditures by the industry,"
id. at 27360, col. 2, and, for that and other reasons,
adopted a less stringent PEL of 750 �g/m^3 for weaving and
slashing.
The Court of Appeals upheld the Standard in all major respects.
[
Footnote 24] The court
rejected the industry's claim that OSHA failed to consider its
proposed alternative or give sufficient reasons for failing to
adopt it. 199 U.S.App.D.C. at 70-72, 617 F.2d at 652-654. The court
also held that the Standard was "reasonably necessary and
appropriate" within the meaning of § 3(8) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. §
652(8), because of the risk of material health impairment caused by
exposure to cotton dust. 199 U.S.App.D.C. at 72-73, and n. 83, 617
F.2d at 654-655, and n. 83. Rejecting the industry position that
OSHA must demonstrate that the benefits of the Standard are
proportionate to its costs, the court instead agreed with OSHA's
interpretation that the Standard must protect employees against
material health impairment, subject only to the limits of
technological and economic feasibility.
Id. at 80-84, 617
F.2d at 662-666. The court held that "Congress itself struck the
balance between costs and
Page 452 U. S. 505
benefits in the mandate to the agency" under § 6(b)(5) of the
Act, 29 U.S.C. § 655(b)(5), and that OSHA is powerless to
circumvent that judgment by adopting less than the most protective
feasible standard. 199 U.S.App.D.C. at 81, 617 F.2d at 663.
Finally, the court held that the agency's determination of
technological and economic feasibility was supported by substantial
evidence in the record as a whole.
Id. at 73-80, 617 F.2d
at 655-662.
We affirm in part, and vacate in part. [
Footnote 25]
Page 452 U. S. 506
II
The principal question presented in these cases is whether the
Occupational Safety and Health Act requires the Secretary, in
promulgating a standard pursuant to § 6(b)(5) of the Act, 29 U.S.C.
§ 655(b)(5), to determine that the costs of the standard bear a
reasonable relationship to its benefits. Relying on §§ 6(b)(5) and
3(8) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. §§ 655(b)(5) and 652(8), petitioner urge
not only that OSHA must show that a standard addresses a
significant risk of material health impairment,
see Industrial
Union, Dept. v. American Petroleum Institute, 448 U.S. at
448 U. S. 639
(plurality opinion), but also that OSHA must demonstrate that the
reduction in risk of material health impairment is significant in
light of the costs of attaining that reduction.
See Brief
for Petitioners in No. 79-1429, pp. 38-41. [
Footnote 26] Respondents,
Page 452 U. S. 507
on the other hand, contend that the Act requires OSHA to
promulgate standards that eliminate or reduce such risks "to the
extent such protection is technologically and economically
feasible." Brief for Federal Respondent 38; Brief for Union
Respondents 227. [
Footnote
27] To resolve this debate, we must
Page 452 U. S. 508
turn to the language, structure, and legislative history of the
Act.
A
The starting point of our analysis is the language of the
statute itself.
Steadman v. SEC, 450 U. S.
91,
450 U. S. 97
(1981);
Reiter v. Sonotone Corp., 442 U.
S. 330,
442 U. S. 337
(1979). Section 6(b)(5) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. § 655(b)(5) (emphasis
added), provides:
"The Secretary, in promulgating standards dealing with toxic
materials or harmful physical agents under this subsection, shall
set the standard which most adequately assures,
to the extent
feasible, on the basis of the best available evidence, that no
employee will suffer material impairment of health or functional
capacity even if such employee has regular exposure to the hazard
dealt with by such standard for the period of his working life.
[
Footnote 28]"
Although their interpretations differ, all parties agree that
the phrase "to the extent feasible" contains the critical language
in § 6(b)(5) for purposes of these cases.
The plain meaning of the word "feasible" supports respondents'
interpretation of the statute. According to Webster's Third New
International Dictionary of the English Language 831 (1976),
"feasible" means "capable of being
Page 452 U. S. 509
done, executed, or effected."
Accord, the Oxford
English Dictionary 116 (1933) ("Capable of being done, accomplished
or carried out"); Funk & Wagnalls New "Standard" Dictionary of
the English Language 903 (1957) ("That may be done, performed or
effected"). Thus, § 6(b)(5) directs the Secretary to issue the
standard that "most adequately assures . . . that no employee will
suffer material impairment of health," limited only by the extent
to which this is "capable of being done." In effect, then, as the
Court of Appeals held, Congress itself defined the basic
relationship between costs and benefits by placing the "benefit" of
worker health above all other considerations save those making
attainment of this "benefit" unachievable. Any standard based on a
balancing of costs and benefits by the Secretary that strikes a
different balance than that struck by Congress would be
inconsistent with the command set forth in § 6(b)(5). Thus,
cost-benefit analysis by OSHA is not required by the statute,
because feasibility analysis is. [
Footnote 29]
See Industrial Union Dept. v. American
Petroleum Institute, 448 U.S. at
448 U. S.
718-719 (MARSHALL, J., dissenting).
Page 452 U. S. 510
When Congress has intended that an agency engage in cost-benefit
analysis, it has clearly indicated such intent on the face of the
statute. One early example is the Flood Control Act of 1936, 33
U.S.C. § 71:
"[T]he Federal Government should improve or participate in the
improvement of navigable waters or their tributaries, including
watersheds thereof, for flood-control purposes if the
benefits
to whomsoever they may accrue are in excess of the estimated
costs, and if the lives and social security of people are
otherwise adversely affected."
(Emphasis added.) A more recent example is the Outer Continental
Shelf Lands Act Amendments of 1978, 43 U.S.C. § 1347(b) (1976 ed.,
Supp. III), providing that offshore drilling operations shall
use
"the best available and safest technologies which the Secretary
determines to be economically
feasible, wherever failure
of equipment would have a significant effect on safety, health, or
the environment, except where the Secretary determines that the
incremental benefits are clearly insufficient to justify the
incremental costs of using such technologies."
These and other statutes [
Footnote 30] demonstrate that Congress uses
Page 452 U. S. 511
specific language when intending that an agency engage in
cost-benefit analysis.
See Industrial Union Dept. v. American
Petroleum Institute, supra, at
448 U. S. 710,
n. 27 (MARSHALL, J., dissenting). Certainly, in light of its
ordinary meaning, the word "feasible" cannot be construed to
articulate such congressional
Page 452 U. S. 512
intent. We therefore reject the argument that Congress required
cost-benefit analysis in § 6(b)(5).
B
Even though the plain language of § 6(b)(5) supports this
construction, we must still decide whether § 3(8), the general
definition of an occupational safety and health standard, either
alone or in tandem with § 6(b)(5), incorporates a cost-benefit
requirement for standards dealing with toxic materials or harmful
physical agents. Section 3(8) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. § 652(8)
(emphasis added), provides:
"The term 'occupational safety and health standard' means a
standard which requires conditions, or the adoption or use of one
or more practices, means, methods, operations, or processes,
reasonably necessary or appropriate to provide safe or
healthful employment and places of employment."
Taken alone, the phrase "reasonably necessary or appropriate"
might be construed to contemplate some balancing of the costs and
benefits of a standard. Petitioners urge that, so construed, § 3(8)
engrafts a cost-benefit analysis requirement on the issuance of §
6(b)(5) standards, even if § 6(b)(5) itself does not authorize such
analysis. We need not decide whether § 3(8), standing alone, would
contemplate some form of cost-benefit analysis. For even if it
does, Congress specifically chose in § 6(b)(5) to impose separate
and additional requirements for issuance of a subcategory of
occupational safety and health standards dealing with toxic
materials and harmful physical agents: it required that those
standards be issued to prevent material impairment of health
to
the extent feasible. Congress could reasonably have concluded
that
health standards should be subject to different
criteria than
safety standards because of the special
problems presented in regulating them.
See Industrial Union
Dept. v. American Petroleum Institute, 448 U.S. at
448 U. S. 649,
n. 54 (plurality opinion).
Page 452 U. S. 513
Agreement with petitioners' argument that § 3(8) imposes an
additional and overriding requirement of cost-benefit analysis on
the issuance of § 6(b)(5) standards would eviscerate the "to the
extent feasible" requirement. Standards would inevitably be set at
the level indicated by cost-benefit analysis, and not at the level
specified by § 6(b)(5). For example, if cost-benefit analysis
indicated a protective standard of 1,000 �g/m^3 PEL, while
feasibility analysis indicated a 500 �g/m^3 PEL, the agency would
be forced by the cost-benefit requirement to choose the less
stringent point. [
Footnote
31] We cannot believe that Congress intended the general terms
of § 3(8) to countermand the specific feasibility requirement of §
6(b)(5). Adoption of petitioners' interpretation would effectively
write § 6(b)(5) out of the Act. We decline to render Congress'
decision to include a feasibility requirement nugatory, thereby
offending the well-settled rule that all parts of a statute, if
possible, are to be given effect.
E.g., Reiter v. Sonotone
Corp., 442 U.S. at
442 U. S. 339;
Weinberger v. Hynson, Westcott & Dunning, Inc.,
412 U. S. 609,
412 U. S.
633-634 (1973);
Jarecki v. G. D. Searle &
Co., 367 U. S. 303,
367 U. S.
307-308 (1961). Congress did not contemplate any further
balancing by the agency for toxic material and harmful physical
agents standards, and we should not "
impute to Congress a
purpose to analyze with one hand what it sought to promote with the
other.'" Weinberger v. Hynson, Westcott & Dunning, Inc.,
supra, at 412 U. S. 631,
quoting Clark v. Uebersee Finanz-Korporation, 332 U.
S. 480, 332 U. S. 489
(1947). [Footnote
32]
Page 452 U. S. 514
C
The legislative history of the Act, while concededly not crystal
clear, provides general support for respondents' interpretation of
the Act. The congressional Reports and debates certainly confirm
that Congress meant "feasible," and nothing else, in using that
term. Congress was concerned that the Act might be thought to
require achievement of absolute safety, an impossible standard, and
therefore insisted that health and safety goals be capable of
economic and technological accomplishment. Perhaps most telling is
the absence of any indication whatsoever that Congress intended
OSHA to conduct its own cost-benefit analysis before promulgating a
toxic material or harmful physical agent standard. The legislative
history demonstrates conclusively that Congress was fully aware
that the Act would impose real and substantial costs of compliance
on industry, and believed that such costs were part of the cost of
doing business. We thus turn to the relevant portions of the
legislative history.
Neither the original Senate bill, S. 2193, 91st Cong., 1st Sess.
(1969), introduced by Senator Williams, nor the original House
bill, H.R. 16785, 91st Cong., 2d Sess. (1970), introduced by
Representative Daniels, included specific provisions
Page 452 U. S. 515
controlling the issuance of standards governing toxic materials
and harmful physical agents, Leg.Hist. 1, 6-7 (Williams bill); 721,
728-732 (Daniels bill), although both contained the definitional
section enacted as § 3(8). [
Footnote 33] The House Committee on Education and Labor,
to which the Daniels bill was referred, reported out an amended
bill that included the following section:
"The Secretary, in promulgating standards under this subsection,
shall set the standard which most adequately assures, on the basis
of the best available professional evidence, that no employee will
suffer any impairment of health or functional capacity, or
diminished life expectancy, even if such employee has regular
exposure to the hazard dealt with by such standard for the period
of his working life."
H.R.Rep. No. 91-1291, p. 4 (1970) (to accompany H.R. 16785),
Leg.Hist. 834.
The Senate Committee on Labor and Public Welfare, reporting on
the Williams bill, included a provision virtually identical to the
House version, except for the additional requirement that the
Secretary set the standard "which most adequately
and feasibly
assures . . . that no employee will suffer any impairment of
health."
Id. at 242 (the Senate provision was numbered §
6(b)(5)) (emphasis added). This addition to the Williams bill was
offered by Senator Javits, who explained his amendment:
"As a result of this amendment, the Secretary, in setting
standards, is expressly required to consider feasibility of
proposed standards. This is an improvement over the Daniels bill
[as reported out of the House Committee], which might be
interpreted to require
absolute health and safety in all
cases, regardless of feasibility, and the Administration bill,
which contains no criteria for standards
Page 452 U. S. 516
at all."
S.Rep. No. 91-1282, p. 58 (1970), Leg.Hist.197 (emphasis added).
[
Footnote 34] Thus, the
Senator's concern was that a standard might require "absolute
health and safety" without any consideration as to whether such a
condition was achievable. The full Senate Committee also noted that
standards promulgated under this provision "shall represent
feasible requirements," S.Rep. No. 91-1282, at 7, Leg.Hist. 147,
and commented that "[s]uch standards should be directed at
assuring,
so far as possible, that no employee will suffer
impaired health. . . ,"
ibid. (emphasis added).
Page 452 U. S. 517
The final amendments to this Senate provision, resulting in §
6(b)(5) of the Act, were proposed and adopted on the Senate floor
after the Committee reported out the bill. Senator Dominick, who
played a prominent role in this amendment process,
see 116
Cong.Rec. 37631 (1970), Leg.Hist. 526 (comments of Sen. Javits);
116 Cong.Rec. at 37631, Leg.Hist. 527 (comments of Sen. Williams),
continued to be concerned that the Act might be read to require
absolute safety. He therefore proposed that the entire first
sentence of § 6(b)(5) be struck, explaining:
"This requirement is inherently confusing and unrealistic. It
could be read to require the Secretary to ban all occupations in
which there remains
some risk of injury, impaired health,
or life expectancy. In the case of all occupations, it will be
impossible to eliminate all risks to safety and health. Thus, the
present criteria could, if literally applied, close every business
in this nation. In addition, in many cases, the standard which
might most 'adequately' and 'feasibly' assure the elimination of
the danger would be the prohibition of the occupation itself."
Leg.Hist. 367 (comments of Sen. Dominick on his proposed
amendment No. 1054) (emphasis in original).
In the ensuing floor debate on this issue, Senator Dominick
reiterated his concern that
"[i]t is unrealistic to attempt as [the Committee's § 6(b)(5)]
apparently does, to establish a utopia free from any hazards.
Absolute safety is an impossibility. . . ."
116 Cong.Rec. 37614 (1970), Leg.Hist. 480. [
Footnote 35] The Senator concluded:
"Any administrator responsible
Page 452 U. S. 518
for enforcing the statute will be faced with an impossible
choice. Either he must forbid employment in all occupations where
there is any risk of injury, even if the technical state of the art
could not remove the hazard, or he must ignore the mandate of
Congress. . . ."
116 Cong.Rec. at 37614, Leg.Hist. 48182.
Senator Dominick failed in his efforts to have the first
sentence of § 6(b)(5) deleted. However, after working with Senators
Williams and Javits, he introduced an amended version of the first
sentence which he thought was "agreeable to all" and which became §
6(b)(5) as it now appears in the Act. 116 Cong.Rec. at 37622,
Leg.Hist. 502. This amendment limited the applicability of §
6(b)(5) to "toxic materials and harmful physical agents," changed
"health impairment" to "material impairment of health," and deleted
the reference to "diminished life expectancy." Significantly, the
feasibility requirement was left intact in the statute. Instead of
the phrase "which most adequately and feasibly assures," the
amendment merely substituted "which most adequately assures, to the
extent feasible," to emphasize that the feasibility requirement
operated as a limit on the promulgation of standards under §
6(b)(5).
Senator Dominick believed that his modifications made clearer
that attainment of an absolutely safe working environment could not
be achieved through "prohibition of the occupation itself,"
Leg.Hist. 367, and that toxic material and harmful physical agent
standards should not address frivolous harms that exist in every
workplace. The feasibility requirement, along with the need for a
"
material impairment of health," were thus thought to
satisfy these two concerns. He explained the effect of the
amendment:
"What we were trying to do in the bill -- unfortunately,
Page 452 U. S. 519
we did not have the proper wording or the proper drafting -- was
to say that, when we are dealing with toxic agents or physical
agents, we ought to take such steps as are feasible and practical
to provide an atmosphere within which a person's health or safety
would not be affected. Unfortunately, we had language providing
that anyone would be assured that no one would have a hazard. . .
."
116 Cong.Rec. 37622 (1970), Leg.Hist. 502. Senator Williams
added that the amendment
"will provide a continued direction to the Secretary that he
shall be required to set the standard which most adequately and, to
the greatest extent feasible, assures"
that no employee will suffer any material health impairment. 116
Cong.Rec. at 37622, Leg.Hist. 503. The Senate thereafter passed S.
2193. One week later, the House passed a substitute bill which
failed to contain any substantive criteria for the issuance of
health standards in place of its original bill. 116 Cong.Rec. at
38716-38717, Leg.Hist. 1094-1096. At the joint House-Senate
Conference, however, the House conferees acceded to the Senate's
version of § 6(b)(5). [
Footnote
36]
Not only does the legislative history confirm that Congress
meant "feasible," rather than "cost-benefit," when it used the
former term, but it also shows that Congress understood that
Page 452 U. S. 520
the Act would create substantial costs for employers, yet
intended to impose such costs when necessary to create a safe and
healthful working environment. [
Footnote 37] Congress viewed the costs of health and
safety as a cost of doing business. Senator Yarborough, a
co-sponsor of the Williams bill, stated "We know the costs would be
put into consumer goods, but that is the price we should pay for
the 80 million workers in America." 116 Cong.Rec. at 37345,
Leg.Hist. 444. He asked:
"One may well ask too expensive for whom? Is it too expensive
for the company who, for lack of proper safety equipment, loses the
services of its skilled employees? Is it too expensive for the
employee who loses his hand or leg or eyesight? Is it too expensive
for the widow trying to raise her children on meager allowance
under workmen's compensation and social security? And what about
the man -- a good hardworking man -- tied to a wheel chair or
hospital bed for the rest of his life? That
Page 452 U. S. 521
is what we are dealing with when we talk about industrial
safety."
"
* * * *"
"We are talking about people's lives, not the indifference of
some cost accountants."
116 Cong.Rec. at 37625, Leg.Hist. 510. Senator Eagleton
commented that
"[t]he costs that will be incurred by employers in meeting the
standards of health and safety to be established under this bill
are, in my view,
reasonable and necessary costs of doing
business."
116 Cong.Rec. at 41764, Leg.Hist. 1150-1151 (emphasis added).
[
Footnote 38]
Other Members of Congress voiced similar views. [
Footnote 39] Nowhere is there any
indication that Congress contemplated a different balancing by OSHA
of the benefits of worker health and safety against the costs of
achieving them. Indeed Congress thought that the
financial
costs of health and safety problems in the workplace were as
large as or larger than the
financial costs of eliminating
these problems. In its statement
Page 452 U. S. 522
of findings and declaration of purpose encompassed in the Act
itself, Congress announced that
"personal injuries and illnesses arising out of work situations
impose a substantial burden upon, and are a hindrance to,
interstate commerce in terms of lost production, wage loss, medical
expenses, and disability compensation payments."
29 U.S.C. § 651(a). The Senate was well aware of the magnitude
of these costs:
"[T]he economic impact of industrial deaths and disability is
staggering. Over $1.5 billion is wasted in lost wages, and the
annual loss to the Gross National Product is estimated to be over
$8 billion. Vast resources that could be available for productive
use are siphoned off to pay workmen's compensation benefits and
medical expenses."
S.Rep. No. 91-1282, p. 2 (1970), Leg.Hist. 142. Senator Eagleton
summarized:
"Whether we, as individuals, are motivated by simple humanity or
by simple economics, we can no longer permit profits to be
dependent upon an unsafe or unhealthy worksite."
116 Cong.Rec. 41764 (1970), Leg.Hist. 1150-1151.
III
Section 6(f) of the Act provides that "[t]he determinations of
the Secretary shall be conclusive if supported by substantial
evidence in the record considered as a whole." 29 U.S.C. § 655(f).
Petitioners contend that the Secretary's determination that the
Cotton Dust Standard is "economically feasible" is not supported by
substantial evidence in the record considered as a whole. In
particular, they claim (1) that OSHA underestimated the financial
costs necessary to meet the Standard's requirements; and(2) that
OSHA incorrectly found that the Standard would not threaten the
economic viability of the cotton industry.
In statutes with provisions virtually identical to § 6(f) of the
Act, we have defined substantial evidence as "such relevant
evidence as a reasonable mind might accept as adequate to support a
conclusion."
Universal Camera Corp. v.
NLRB,
Page 452 U. S. 523
340 U. S. 474,
340 U. S. 477
(1951). The reviewing court must take into account contradictory
evidence in the record,
id. at
340 U. S.
487-488, but
"the possibility of drawing two inconsistent conclusions from
the evidence does not prevent an administrative agency's finding
from being supported by substantial evidence,"
Consolo v. FMC, 383 U. S. 607,
383 U. S. 620
(1966). Since the Act places responsibility for determining
substantial evidence questions in the courts of appeals, 29 U.S.C.
§ 655(f), we apply the familiar rule that
"[t]his Court will intervene only in what ought to be the rare
instance when the [substantial evidence] standard appears to have
been misapprehended or grossly misapplied"
by the court below.
Universal Camera Corp. v. NLRB,
supra, at
340 U. S. 491;
see Mobil Oil Corp. v. FPC, 417 U.
S. 283,
417 U. S. 292,
417 U. S. 310
(1974);
FTC v. Standard Oil Co., 355 U.
S. 396,
355 U. S.
400-401 (1958). Therefore, our inquiry is not to
determine whether we, in the first instance, would find OSHA's
findings supported by substantial evidence. Instead, we turn to
OSHA's findings and the record upon which they were based to decide
whether the Court of Appeals "misapprehended or grossly misapplied"
the substantial evidence test.
A
OSHA derived its cost estimate for industry compliance with the
Cotton Dust Standard after reviewing two financial analyses, one
prepared by the Research Triangle Institute (RTI), an
OSHA-contracted group, the other by industry representatives
(Hocutt-Thomas). [
Footnote
40] The agency carefully
Page 452 U. S. 524
explored the assumptions and methodologies underlying the
conclusions of each of these studies. From this exercise, the
agency was able to build upon conclusions from each which it found
reliable and explain its process for choosing its cost estimate. A
brief summary of OSHA's treatment of the two studies follows.
OSHA rejected RTI's cost estimate of $1.1 billion for textile
industry engineering controls for three principal reasons.
[
Footnote 41] First, OSHA
believed that RTI's estimate should be discounted by 30%, 43
Fed.Reg. 27372, col. 3 (1978), because that estimate was based on
the assumption that engineering controls would be applied to all
equipment in mills, including those processing pure synthetic
fibers, even though cotton dust is not generated by such equipment.
RTI had observed that "[e]xclusion of equipment processing man-made
fibers only could reduce these costs by as much as 30 percent." Ex.
6-76, Ct. of App. J.A. 585. [
Footnote 42] Since the Standard did not require controls
on synthetics-only equipment, OSHA rejected RTI's assumption about
application of controls to synthetics-only machines. 43 Fed.Reg.
27371, col. 3 (1978). Second, OSHA concluded that RTI
"may have overestimated compliance costs, since some operations
are already in compliance with the permissible exposure limit of
the new standard."
Id. at 27370, cols. 2 and 3. Evidence indicated that
some
Page 452 U. S. 525
mills had attained PEL's of 200 �g/m^3 or less, while others
were below the 1,000 �g/m^3 total dust level. [
Footnote 43] Therefore, OSHA disagreed with
RTI's assumption that the industry had not reduced cotton dust
exposure below the existing standard's 1,000 �g/m^3 total dust PEL.
Id. at 27370, col. 3. Third, OSHA found that the RTI study
suffered from lack of recent accurate industry data.
Id.
at 27373, col. 1;
see Ex. 76, Ct. of App. J.A. 88; Ex.
16.,
id. at 1367, 1359.
In light of these deficiencies in the RTI study, OSHA adopted
the Hocutt-Thomas estimate for textile industry engineering
controls of $543 million, [
Footnote 44] emphasizing that, because it was based on
the most recent industry data, it was more realistic than RTI's
estimate. 43 Fed.Reg. 27373, col. 1 (1978). [
Footnote 45] Nevertheless OSHA concluded that
the Hocutt-Thomas
Page 452 U. S. 526
estimate was overstated for four principal reasons. First,
Hocutt-Thomas included costs of achieving the existing PEL of 1,000
�g/m^3, while OSHA thought it likely that compliance was more
widespread, and that some mills had in fact achieved the final
standard's PEL.
Ibid.; see n 43,
supra. [
Footnote 46] Second, Hocutt-Thomas declined to make any
allowance for the trend toward replacement of existing production
machines with newer more productive equipment. [
Footnote 47] Relying on this "[n]atural
production tren[d]," 43 Fed.Reg. 27359, col. 1 (1978), OSHA
concluded that fewer machines than estimated by Hocutt-Thomas would
require retrofitting or other controls,
Page 452 U. S. 527
id. at 27372, col. 3. Third, OSHA thought that
Hocutt-Thomas failed to take into account development of new
technologies likely to occur during the 4-year compliance period.
Ibid. [
Footnote 48]
Fourth, OSHA believed that Hocutt-Thomas might have improperly
included control costs for synthetics-only machines,
ibid., an inclusion which could result in a 30% cost
overestimate. [
Footnote
49]
Petitioners criticize OSHA's adopt.ion of the Hocutt-Thomas
estimate, since that estimate was based on achievement of somewhat
less stringent PEL's than those ultimately promulgated in the final
Standard. [
Footnote 50]
Thus, even if the Hocutt-Thomas estimate was exaggerated, they
assert that
"only by the most remarkable coincidence would the amount of
that overestimate be equal to the additional costs required to
attain the far more stringent limits of the Standard OSHA actually
adopted."
Brief for Petitioners in No. 79-1429, p. 27;
see Brief
for Petitioner in No. 79-1583, pp. 14-15. The agency itself
recognized the problem cited by petitioners, but found itself
limited in the precision of its estimates by the
Page 452 U. S. 528
industry's refusal to make more of its own data available.
[
Footnote 51] OSHA explained
that, "in the absence of the [industry] survey data [of textile
mills], OSHA cannot develop more accurate estimates of compliance
costs." 43 Fed. Reg 27373, col. 1 (1978). Since § 6(b)(5) of the
Act requires that the Secretary promulgate toxic material and
harmful physical agent standards "on the basis of the best
available evidence," 29 U.S.C. § 655(b)(5), and since OSHA could
not obtain the more detailed confidential industry data it thought
essential to further precision, we conclude that the agency acted
reasonably in adopting the Hocutt-Thomas estimate. [
Footnote 52] While
Page 452 U. S. 529
a cost estimate based on the standard actually promulgated
surely would be preferable, [
Footnote 53] we decline to hold as a matter of law that
its absence, under the circumstances, required the Court of Appeals
to find that OSHA's determination was unsupported by substantial
evidence. [
Footnote 54]
Therefore, whether or not in the first instance we would find
the Secretary's conclusions supported by substantial evidence, we
cannot say that the Court of Appeals in this case
Page 452 U. S. 530
"misapprehended or grossly misapplied" the substantial evidence
test when it found that "OSHA reasonably evaluated the cost
estimates before it, considered criticisms of each, and selected
suitable estimates of compliance costs." 199 U.S.App.D.C. at 79,
617 F.2d at 661 (footnote omitted).
B
After estimating the cost of compliance with the Cotton Dust
Standard, OSHA analyzed whether it was "economically feasible" for
the cotton industry to bear this cost. [
Footnote 55] OSHA
Page 452 U. S. 531
concluded that it was, finding that,
"although some marginal employers may shut down, rather than
comply, the industry as a whole will not be threatened by the
capital requirements of the regulation."
43 Fed.Reg. 27378, col. 2 (1978);
see id. at 27379,
col. 3 ("compliance with the standard is well within the financial
capability of the covered industries"). In reaching this conclusion
on the Standard's economic impact, OSHA made specific findings with
respect to employment, energy consumption, capital financing
availability, and profitability.
Id. at 27377-27378. To
support its findings, the agency relied primarily on RTI's
comprehensive investigation of the Standard's economic impact.
[
Footnote 56]
RTI evaluated the likely economic impact on the cotton industry
and the United States' economy of OSHA's original proposed
standard, an across-the-board 200 �g/m^3 PEL. Ex. 6-76, Ct. of App.
J.A. 626. [
Footnote 57] RTI
had estimated a total
Page 452 U. S. 532
compliance cost of $2.7 billion for a 200 �g/m^3 PEL, [
Footnote 58] and used this estimate
in assessing the economic impact of such a standard.
Id.
at 736-737. As described in n.
44 supra, OSHA estimated total compliance costs
of $656.5 million for the final Cotton Dust Standard, [
Footnote 59] a standard less
stringent than the across-the-board 200 �g/m^3 PEL of the proposed
standard. Therefore, the agency found that the economic impact of
its Standard would be "much less severe" than that suggested by RTI
for a 200 �g/m^3 PEL estimate of $2.7 billion. 43 Fed.Reg. 27378,
col. 2 (1978). Nevertheless, it is instructive to review RTI's
conclusions with respect to the economic impact of a $2.7 billion
cost estimate. RTI found:
"Implementation of the proposed [200 �g/m^3] standard will
require adjustments within the cotton textile industry that will
take time to work themselves out and that may be difficult for many
firms. In time, however, prices may be expected to rise and markets
to adjust so that revenues will cover costs. Although the impact on
any one firm cannot be specified in advance, nothing in the RTI
study indicates that the cotton textile industry as a whole will be
seriously threatened by the impact of the proposed standard for
control of cotton dust exposure."
Ex. 16, Ct. of App. J.A. 1380;
id. at 3620. In reaching
this conclusion, RTI analyzed the total and annual economic impact
[
Footnote 60] on each of the
different sectors of the cotton industry.
Page 452 U. S. 533
For example, in yarn production (opening through spinning), RTI
found that the total additional capital requirement per dollar of
industry shipment was 7.8 cents, and that the corresponding annual
requirement was 1.9 cents. Ex. 676,
id. at 729. Average
price increases necessary to maintain pre-standard rates of return
on investment were estimated to range from 0.22 cents to 6.25 cents
per dollar of industry sales. [
Footnote 61]
Ibid. Even assuming no price
increases, only one of the six yarn-producing operations would
experience a negative rate of return on investment, while the five
other rates of return would range from l.4% to 3.9%.
Id.
at 652. [
Footnote 62]
Page 452 U. S. 534
RTI estimated the average pre-standard rate of return for the
yarn-producing sector as 4.1%.
Ibid.
Through an output demand elasticity analysis, RTI determined
that price increases necessitated by the 200 �g/m^3 standard would
result in a. 1.68% contraction of cotton yarn consumption.
[
Footnote 63]
Id.
at 685;
see id. at 680-687. RTI also discussed the effects
of such price increases on interfiber and domestic/foreign
competition. RTI observed that "non-price factors have probably
dominated" the competition between cotton and man-made fibers.
Id. at 623, 948-953. [
Footnote 64] Noting that international trade agreements
restricting foreign imports of textile products "have tended to
smother the effects of a small change in the relative prices of
domestic versus foreign textile products,"
id. at 622, RTI
concluded that such small
Page 452 U. S. 535
changes have had "very little impact" on domestic industries and
markets,
id. at 961;
see id. at 95961. In order
to measure the ability of different sized textile companies to
finance compliance costs, RTI constructed a ratio of capital
requirements to profit after taxes. RTI found that two of the six
yarn production operations would have financing difficulties, but
that such difficulties decreased as company size increased.
Id. at 730. [
Footnote
65] Finally, impacts on energy costs, employment, inflation,
and market structure were evaluated.
See id. at 72731.
[
Footnote 66]
Relying on its comprehensive economic evaluation of the cotton
industry's ability to absorb the $2.7 billion compliance cost of a
200 �g/m^3 PEL standard, RTI concluded that "nothing in the RTI
study indicates that the cotton textile industry as a whole will be
seriously threatened." Ex. 16,
id. at 1380. [
Footnote 67] Therefore, it follows
a fortiori that OSHA's
Page 452 U. S. 536
estimated compliance cost of $656.6 million is "economically
feasible." [
Footnote 68]
Even if OSHA's estimate was understated, we are fortified in
observing that RTI found that a standard more than four times as
costly was nevertheless economically feasible.
The Court of Appeals found that the agency "explained the
economic impact it projected for the textile industry," and that
OSHA has "substantial support in the record for its . . . findings
of economic feasibility for the textile industry." 199 U.S.App.D.C.
at 80, 617 F.2d at 662. On the basis of the whole record, we cannot
conclude that the Court of Appeals "misapprehended or grossly
misapplied" the substantial evidence test.
IV
The final Cotton Dust Standard places heavy reliance on the use
of respirators to protect employees from exposure to cotton dust,
particularly during the 4-year interim period necessary to install
and implement feasible engineering controls. [
Footnote 69] One part of the respirator
provision requires the
Page 452 U. S. 537
employer to give employees unable to wear a respirator [
Footnote 70] the opportunity to
transfer to another position, if available, where the dust level
meets the Standard's PEL. 2 CFR § 1910.1043(f)(2)(v) (1980). When
such a transfer occurs, the employer must guarantee that the
employee suffers no loss of earnings or other employment rights or
benefits. [
Footnote 71]
Petitioners do not object to the transfer provision, but challenge
OSHA's authority under the Act to require employers to guarantee
employees' wage and employment benefits following the transfer. The
Court of Appeals held that OSHA has such authority. 199
U.S.App.D.C. at 93, 617 F.2d at 675. We hold that, whether or not
OSHA has this underlying authority, the agency has failed to make
the necessary determination or statement of reasons that its wage
guarantee
Page 452 U. S. 538
requirement is related to the achievement of a safe and
healthful work environment.
Respondents urge several statutory bases for the authority
exercised here. They cite § 2(b) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. § 651(b),
which declares that the purpose of the Act is "to assure so far as
possible every working man and woman in the Nation safe and
healthful working conditions"; § 2(b)(5), which suggests
achievement of the purpose "by developing innovative methods,
techniques, and approaches for dealing with occupational safety and
health problems"; § 6(b)(5), which requires the agency to "set the
standard which most adequately assures . . . that no employee will
suffer material impairment of health or functional capacity . . .";
and § 3(8), which provides that a standard must require
"conditions, or the adoption or use of one or more practices,
means, methods, operations, or processes, reasonably necessary or
appropriate to provide safe or healthful employment."
Brief for Federal Respondent 68. Whatever methods these
provisions authorize OSHA to apply, it is clear that such methods
must be justified on the basis of their relation to safety or
health.
Section 6(f) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. 655(f), requires that
"
determinations of the Secretary" must be supported by
substantial evidence. Section 6(e), 29 U.S.C. 655(e), requires the
Secretary to include "a statement of the reasons for such action,
which shall be published in the Federal Register." In his "Summary
and Explanation of the Standard," the Secretary stated:
"Each section includes an analysis of the record evidence and
the policy considerations underlying the decisions adopted
pertaining to specific provisions of the standard."
43 Fed.Reg. 27380, col. 2 (1978). But OSHA never explained the
wage guarantee provision as an approach designed to contribute to
increased health protection. Instead the agency stated that the
"goal of this provision is to minimize any adverse economic impact
on the employee by virtue of the inability to wear a respirator."
Id. at 27387,
Page 452 U. S. 539
col. 3. Perhaps in recognition of this fact, respondents in
their briefs argue:
"Experience under the Act has shown hat employees are reluctant
to disclose symptoms of disease and tend to minimize work-related
health problems for fear of being discharged or transferred to a
lower paying job. . . . It may reasonably be expected, therefore,
that many employees incapable of using respirators would continue
to breathe unhealthful air rather than request a transfer, thus
destroying the utility of the respirator program."
Brief for Federal Respondent 67.
See Brief for Union
Respondents 51. [
Footnote
72]
Whether these arguments have merit, and they very well may,
[
Footnote 73] the
post
hoc rationalizations of the agency or the parties to this
litigation cannot serve as a sufficient predicate for agency
action.
See Citizens to Preserve Overton Park v. Volpe,
401 U. S. 402,
401 U. S. 419
(1971);
Burlington Truck Lines v. United States,
371 U. S. 156,
371 U. S.
168-169 (1962);
SEC v.
Page 452 U. S. 540
Chenery Corp., 318 U. S. 80,
318 U. S. 87
(1943). For Congress gave OSHA the responsibility to protect worker
health and safety, and to explain its reasons for its actions.
Because the Act in no way authorizes OSHA to repair general
unfairness to employees that is unrelated to achievement of health
and safety goals, we conclude that OSHA acted beyond statutory
authority when it issued the wage guarantee regulation. [
Footnote 74]
V
When Congress passed the Occupational Safety and Health Act in
1970, it chose to place preeminent value on assuring employees a
safe and healthful working environment, limited only by the
feasibility of achieving such an environment. We must measure the
validity of the Secretary's actions against the requirements of
that Act. For "[t]he judicial function does not extend to
substantive revision of regulatory
Page 452 U. S. 541
policy. That function lies elsewhere -- in Congressional and
Executive oversight or amendatory legislation."
Industrial
Union Dept. v. American Petroleum Institute, 448 U.S. at
448 U. S. 663
(BURGER, C.J., concurring);
see TVA v. Hill, 437 U.
S. 153,
437 U. S. 185,
437 U. S.
187-188,
437 U. S.
194-195 (1978). [
Footnote 75]
Accordingly, the judgment of the Court of Appeals is affirmed in
all respects except to the extent of its approval of the
Secretary's application of the wage guarantee provision of the
Cotton Dust Standard at 29 CFR § 1910.1043(f)(2)(v) (1980). To that
extent, the judgment of the Court of Appeals is vacated and the
case remanded with directions to remand to the Secretary for
further proceedings consistent with this opinion.
It is so ordered.
JUSTICE POWELL took no part in the decision of these cases.
* Together with No. 79-1583,
National Cotton Council of
America v. Donovan, Secretary of Labor, et al., also on
certiorari to the same court.
[
Footnote 1]
This opinion will use the terms OSHA and the Secretary
interchangeably when referring to the agency, the Secretary of
Labor, or the Assistant Secretary for Occupational Safety and
Health. The Secretary of Labor has delegated the authority to
promulgate occupational safety and health standards to the
Assistant Secretary.
See 29 CFR § 1910.4 (1980).
[
Footnote 2]
Petitioners in No. 79-1429 include 12 individual cotton textile
manufacturers, and the American Textile Manufacturers Institute,
Inc. (ATMI), a trade association representing approximately 175
companies. Brief for Petitioners in No. 79-1429, pp. i, 2. In No.
79-1583, petitioner is the National Cotton Council of America, a
nonprofit corporation chartered for the purpose of increasing the
consumption of cotton and cotton products. Brief for Petitioner in
No. 79-1583, pp. 3-4.
[
Footnote 3]
The two labor organizations are the American Federation of Labor
and Congress of Industrial Organizations, Industrial Union
Department, AFL-CIO, and the Amalgamated Clothing & Textile
Workers Union, AFL-CIO. In the Court of Appeals, the labor
organizations challenged the Cotton Dust Standard as not
sufficiently stringent.
[
Footnote 4]
JUSTICE POWELL, concurring in part and in the judgment, was the
only member of the Court to decide the cost-benefit issue
expressly. JUSTICE POWELL concluded that the statute "requires the
agency to determine that the economic effects of its standard bear
a reasonable relationship to the expected benefits."
Industrial
Union Dept. v. American Petroleum Institute, 448 U.S. at
448 U. S. 667.
JUSTICE MARSHALL, dissenting, joined by JUSTICE BRENNAN, JUSTICE
WHITE, and JUSTICE BLACKMUN, indicated that the statute did not
contemplate cost-benefit analysis.
See id. at
448 U. S.
717-718, n. 30,
448 U. S. 719-720, n. 32.
[
Footnote 5]
In addition to the cost-benefit issue, the other questions
presented and addressed are (1) whether substantial evidence in the
record as a whole supports OSHA's determination that the Cotton
Dust Standard is economically feasible; and (2) whether OSUA has
the authority under the Act to require that employers guarantee the
wages and benefits of employees who are transferred to other
positions because of their inability to wear respirators.
[
Footnote 6]
Cotton dust is defined as
"dust present in the air during the handling or processing of
cotton, which may contain a mixture of many substances including
ground up plant matter, fiber, bacteria, fungi, soil, pesticides,
non-cotton plant matter, and other contaminants which may have
accumulated with the cotton during the growing, harvesting and
subsequent processing or storage periods. Any dust present during
the handling and processing of cotton through the weaving or
knitting of fabrics, and dust present in other operations or
manufacturing processes using new or waste cotton fibers or cotton
fiber byproducts from textile mills, are considered cotton
dust."
29 CFR § 1910.1043(b) (1980) (Cotton Dust Standard).
[
Footnote 7]
References are made throughout this opinion to the Joint
Appendix filed in this Court (App.), and to the Joint Appendix
lodged in the Court of Appeals below (Ct. of App. J.A.).
[
Footnote 8]
Known generally as the Schilling classification grades, they
include:
"[Grade] 1/2: slight acute effect of dust on ventilatory
capacity; no evidence of chronic ventilatory impairment."
"[Grade] 1: definite acute effect of just on ventilatory
capacity; no evidence of chronic ventilatory impairment."
"[Grade] 2: evidence of slight to moderate irreversible
impairment of ventilatory capacity."
"[Grade] 3: evidence of moderate to severe irreversible
impairment of ventilatory capacity."
Exhibit 6-27, App. 25;
see 41 Fed.Reg. 56500-56501
(1976).
[
Footnote 9]
Descriptions of the disease by individual mill workers,
presented in hearings on the Cotton Dust Standard before an
Administrative Law Judge, are more vivid:
"When they started speeding the looms up, the dust got finer and
more and more people started leaving the mill with breathing
problems. My mother had to leave the mill in the early fifties.
Before she left, her breathing got so short she just couldn't hold
out to work. My stepfather left the mill on account of breaching
[
sic] problems. He had coughing spells til he couldn't
breath [
sic], like a child's whooping cough. Both my
sisters who work in the mill have breathing problems. My husband
had to give up his job when he was only fifty-four years old
because of the breathing problem."
Ct. of App. J.A. 3791.
"I suppose I had a breathing problem since 1973. I just kept on
getting sick and began losing time at the mill. Every time that I
go into the mill, I get deathly sick, choking and vomiting losing
my breath. It would blow down all that lint and cotton and I have
clothes right here where I have wore and they have been washed
several times and I would like for you all to see them. That will
not come out in washing."
"I am only fifty-seven years old, and I am retired, and I can't
even get to go to church because of my breathing. I get short of
breath just walking around the house or dressing [or] sometimes
just watching T.V. I cough all the time."
Id. at 3793.
". . . I had to quit because I couldn't lay down and rest
without oxygen in the night, and my doctor told me I would have to
get out of there. . . . I couln't [
sic] even breathe, I
had to get out of the door so I could breathe and he told me not to
go back in [the mill] under any circumstances."
Id. at 3804. Byssinosis is not a newly discovered
disease, having been described as early as in the 1820's in
England, App. 404-405, and observed in Belgium in a study of 2,000
cotton workers in 1845, Exhibit 6-16, App. 15.
[
Footnote 10]
As an expert representing the industry noted:
"[T]he assumption is often made that the disorder progresses
from 1/2 to 1 to 2 to 3 and, thus, all grades reflect the progress
of the individual's disability. In many instances, however, there
is no progression at all. Sometimes Grade 3 seems to appear
de
novo, or there is a jump from 1 to 3. Among those who develop
permanent disability, Grade 2 very often never occurs."
Exhibit 41, App.192.
[
Footnote 11]
The criterion of disability used for the 35,000-worker estimate
was a Forced Expirator Volume (FEV[1]) measurement of pulmonary
function of 1.2 liters or less. 43 Fed.Reg. 27353, col. 3 (1978). A
FEV[1] of 1.2 liters "is a small fraction of the pulmonary
performance of a normal lung."
Ibid.; Ct. of App. J.A.
1231.
[
Footnote 12]
There are between 126,000 and 200,000 active workers in the yarn
preparation and manufacturing segments of the cotton industry. 43
Fed.Reg. 27379, col. 2 (1978).
[
Footnote 13]
Indeed the Senate Report on the Act expressly observed:
"Studies of particular industries provide specific emphasis
regarding the magnitude of the problem. For example, despite
repeated warnings over the years from other countries that their
cotton workers suffered from lung disease, it is only within the
past decade that we have recognized byssinosis as a distinct
occupational disease among workers in American cotton mills."
S.Rep. 91-1282, p. 3 (1970), Leg.Hist. 143.
[
Footnote 14]
"Total dust" includes both respirable and nonrespirable cotton
dust.
[
Footnote 15]
The Secretary of Labor adopted the threshold limit values
contained in a list that had been prepared by the ACGIH.
[
Footnote 16]
Section 6(a) of the Act, as set forth in 29 U.S.C. § 655(a),
provides in pertinent part:
"[T]he Secretary shall, as soon as practicable during the period
beginning with the effective date of this chapter and ending two
years after such date, by rule promulgate as an occupational safety
or health standard . . . any established Federal standard, unless
he determines that the promulgation of such a standard would not
result in improved safety or health for specifically designated
employees."
[
Footnote 17]
In many cotton preparation and manufacturing operations,
including opening, picking, and carding, 1,000 �g/m^3 of total dust
is roughly equivalent to 500 �g/m^3 of respirable dust. App. 464;
43 Fed.Reg. 27361, col. 2 (1978);
see n 22
infra.
[
Footnote 18]
The Act established the National Institute for Occupational
Safety and Health as part of the then Department of Health,
Education, and Welfare. NIOSH is authorized,
inter alia,
to "develop and establish recommended occupational safety and
health standards." 20 U.S.C. § 671(c)(1). At the request of the
Secretary of Labor or the Secretary of HEW or, on his own
initiative, the Director of NIOSH, may
"conduct such research and experimental programs as he
determines are necessary for the development of criteria for new
and improved occupational safety and health standards, and . . .
after consideration of the results of such research and
experimental programs make recommendations concerning new or
improved occupational safety and health standards."
§ 671(d).
[
Footnote 19]
NIOSH presented its recommendation in a lengthy and detailed
document entitled "Criteria for a Recommended Standard:
Occupational Exposure to Cotton Dust." Ex. 1, Ct. of App. J.A.
11-169. The report examined the effects of cotton dust exposure and
suggested implementation of work practices, engineering controls,
medical surveillance, and monitoring to decrease exposure to the
recommended level.
[
Footnote 20]
The Act specifies an informal rulemaking procedure to accompany
the promulgation of occupational safety and health standards.
See 29 U.S.C. §§ 655(b)(2), (3), (4).
[
Footnote 21]
The Standard provides that exposure to lint-free respirable
cotton dust may be measured by a vertical elutriator, with its
15-micron particle size cutoff, or "a method of equivalent accuracy
and precision." 29 CFR § 1910.1043(c) (1980).
[
Footnote 22]
The manufacturing of cotton textile products is divided into
several different stages. (1) In the operations of
opening,
picking, carding, drawing, and
roving, raw cotton is
cleaned and prepared for spinning into yarn. Brief for Petitioners
in No. 79-1429, p. 7, n. 12. (2) In the operations of
spinning,
twisting, winding, spooling, and
warping, the
prepared cotton is made into yarn and readied for weaving and other
processing.
Id. at 7, n. 13. (3) In
slashing and
weaving, the yarn is manufactured into a woven fabric.
Id. at 7, n. 14. The Cotton Dust Standard defines "yarn
manufacturing" to mean "all textile mill operations from opening
to, but not including, slashing and weaving." 29 CFR § 1910.1043(b)
(1980).
See generally 43 Fed.Reg. 27365, cols. 1 and 2
(1978).
The nontextile industries covered by the Standard's 500 �g/m^3
PEL include, but are not limited to,
"warehousing, compressing of cotton lint, classing and
marketing, using cotton yarn (
i.e., knitting), reclaiming
and marketing of textile manufacturing waste, delinting of
cottonseed, marketing and converting of linters, reclaiming and
marketing of gin motes and batting, yarn felt manufacturing using
waste cotton fibers and byproducts."
Id. at 27360, col. 3.
[
Footnote 23]
Ventilation systems include general controls, such as central
air conditioning, and local exhaust controls, which capture
emissions of cotton dust as close to the point of generation as
possible.
See id. at 27363-27364.
[
Footnote 24]
The court remanded to the agency that portion of the Standard
dealing with the cottonseed oil industry, after concluding that the
record failed to establish adequately the Standard's economic
feasibility.
AFL-CIO v. Marshall, 199 U.S.App.D.C. 54, 87,
95, 617 F.2d 636, 669, 677 (1979) .
[
Footnote 25]
The post-argument motions of the several parties for leave to
file supplemental memoranda are granted. We decline to adopt the
suggestion of the Secretary of Labor that we should
"vacate the judgment of the court of appeals and remand the case
so that the record may be returned to the Secretary for further
consideration and development."
Supplemental Memorandum for Federal Respondent 4. We also
decline to adopt the suggestion of petitioners that we should
"hold these cases in abeyance and . . . remand the record to the
court of appeals with an instruction that the record be remanded to
the agency for further proceedings."
Response of Petitioners to Supplemental Memorandum for Federal
Respondent 4.
At oral argument, and in a letter addressed to the Court after
oral argument, petitioners contended that the Secretary's recent
amendment of OSHA's so-called "Cancer Policy" in light of this
Court's decision in
Industrial Union Dept. v. American
Petroleum Institute, 448 U. S. 607
(1980), was relevant to the issues in the present cases. We
disagree.
OSHA amended its Cancer Policy to
"carry out the Court's interpretation of the Occupational Safety
and Health Act of 1970 that consideration must be given to the
significance of the risk in the issuance of a carcinogen standard
and that OSHA must consider all relevant evidence in making these
determinations."
46 Fed.Reg. 4889, col. 3 (1981). Previously, although lacking
such evidence as dose-response data, the Secretary presumed that no
safe exposure level existed for carcinogenic substances.
Industrial Union Dept. v. American Petroleum Institute,
supra, at
448 U. S. 620,
448 U. S.
624-625,
448 U. S.
635-636, nn. 39 and 40 (plurality opinion). Following
this Court's decision, OSHA deleted those provisions of the Cancer
Policy which required the "automatic setting of the lowest feasible
level" without regard to determinations of risk significance. 46
Fed.Reg. 4890, col. 1 (1981).
In distinct contrast with its Cancer Policy, OSHA expressly
found that "exposure to cotton dust presents a significant health
hazard to employees," 43 Fed.Reg. 27350, col. 1 (1978), and that
"cotton dust produced significant health effects at low levels of
exposure,"
id. at 27358, col. 2. In addition, the agency
noted that
"grade 1/2 byssinosis and associated pulmonary function
decrements are significant health effects in themselves, and should
be prevented in so far as possible."
Id. at 27354, col. 2. In making its assessment of
significant risk, OSHA relied on dose-response curve data (the
Merchant Study) showing that 25% of employees suffered at least
Grade 1/2 byssinosis at a 500 �g/m^3 PEL, and that 12.7% of all
employees would suffer byssinosis at the 200 �g/m^3 PEL standard.
Id. at 27358, cols. 2 and 3. Examining the Merchant Study
in light of other studies in the record, the agency found that "the
Merchant study provides a reliable assessment of health risk to
cotton textile workers from cotton dust."
Id. at 27357,
col. 3. OSHA concluded that the "prevalence of byssinosis should be
significantly reduced" by the 200 �g/m^3 PEL.
Id. at
27359, col. 3;
see id. at 27359, col. 1 ("200 �g/m^3
represents a significant reduction in the number of affected
workers"). It is difficult to imagine what else the agency could do
to comply with this Court's decision in
Industrial Union Dept.
v. American Petroleum Institute.
[
Footnote 26]
Petitioners ATMI
et al. express their position in
several ways. They maintain that OSHA "is required to show that a
reasonable relationship exists between the risk reduction benefits
and the costs of its standards." Brief for Petitioners in No.
79-1429, p. 36. Petitioners also suggest that OSHA must show that
"the standard is expected to achieve a
significant reduction
in [the significant risk of material health impairment]" based
on "an assessment of the costs of achieving it."
Id. at
38, 40. Allowing that "[t]his does not mean that OSHA must engage
in a rigidly formal cost-benefit calculation that places a dollar
value on employee lives or health,"
id. at 39, petitioners
describe the required exercise as follows:
"First, OSHA must make a responsible determination of the costs
and risk reduction benefits of its standard. Pursuant to the
requirement of Section 6(f) of the Act, this determination must be
factually supported by substantial evidence in the record. The
subsequent determination whether the reduction in health risk is
'significant' (based upon the factual assessment of costs and
benefits) is a judgment to be made by the agency in the first
instance."
Id. at 40.
Respondent Secretary disputes petitioners' description of the
exercise, claiming that any meaningful balancing must involve
"placing a [dollar] value on human life and freedom from
suffering," Brief for Federal Respondent 59, and that there is no
other way but through formal cost-benefit analysis to accomplish
petitioners' desired balancing,
id. at 59-60. Cost-benefit
analysis contemplates
"systematic enumeration of all benefits and all costs, tangible
and intangible, whether readily quantifiable or difficult to
measure, that will accrue to all members of society if a particular
project is adopted."
E. Stokey & R. Zeckhauser, A Primer for Policy Analysis 134
(1978);
see Commission on Natural Resources, National
Research Council, Decision Making for Regulating Chemicals in the
Environment 38 (1975).
See generally E. Mishan,
Cost-Benefit Analysis (1976); Prest & Turvey, Cost-Benefit
Analysis, 300 Economic Journal 683 (1965). Whether petitioners' or
respondent's characterization is correct, we will sometimes refer
to petitioners' proposed exercise as "cost-benefit analysis."
[
Footnote 27]
As described by the union respondents, the test for determining
whether a standard promulgated to regulate a "toxic material or
harmful physical agent" satisfies the Act has three parts:
"First, whether the 'place of employment is unsafe -- in the
sense that significant risks are present and can be eliminated or
lessened by a change in practices.' [
Industrial Union Dept.,
supra, at
448 U. S. 642 (plurality
opinion).] Second, whether, of the possible available correctives,
the Secretary has selected '
the standard . . . that is
most protective.'
Ibid. Third, whether that standard is
'feasible.'"
Brief for Union Respondents 441. We will sometimes refer to this
test as "feasibility analysis."
[
Footnote 28]
Section 6(b)(5) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. § 655(b)(5), also
provides:
"Development of standards under this subsection shall be based
upon research, demonstrations, experiments, and such other
information as may be appropriate. In addition to the attainment of
the highest degree of health and safety protection for the
employee, other considerations shall be the latest available
scientific data in the field, the feasibility of the standards, and
experience gained under this and other health and safety laws.
Whenever practicable, the standard promulgated shall be expressed
in terms of objective criteria, and of the performance
desired."
[
Footnote 29]
In these cases, we are faced with the issue whether the Act
requires OSHA to balance costs and benefits in promulgating a
single toxic material and harmful physical agent standard under §
6(b)(5). Petitioners argue that, without cost-benefit balancing,
the issuance of a single standard might result in a "serious
misallocatio[n] of the finite resources that are available for the
protection of worker safety and health," given the other health
standards in the workplace. Reply Brief for Petitioners in No.
79-1429, p. 10;
see Brief for Petitioners in No. 79-1429,
pp. 38-39; Brief for Chamber of Commerce of United States as
Amicus Curiae 12; Brief for American Industrial Health
Council as
Amicus Curiae 19. This argument is more
properly addressed to other provisions of the Act which may
authorize OSHA to explore costs and benefits for deciding between
issuance of several standards regulating different varieties of
health and safety hazards,
e.g., § 6(g) of the Act, 29
U.S.C. § 655(g);
see Industrial Union Dept. v. American
Petroleum Institute, 448 U.S. at
448 U. S.
643-644;
see also Case Comment, 60 B.U.L.Rev.
115, 122, n. 52 (1980), or for promulgating other types of
standards not issued under § 6(b)(5). We express no view on these
questions.
[
Footnote 30]
See, e.g., Energy Policy and Conservation Act of 1975,
42 U.S.C. §§ 6295(c), (d) (1976 ed., Supp. III); Federal Water
Pollution Control Act Amendments of 1972, 33 U.S.C. §§ 1312(b)(1),
(2), 1314(b)(1)(B); Clean Water Act of 1977, 33 U.S.C. §
1314(b)(4)(B) (1976 ed., Supp. III); Clean Air Act Amendments of
1970, 42 U.S.C. § 7545(c)(2)(B) (1976 ed., Supp. III). In the
Federal Water Pollution Control Act Amendments of 1972, Congress
directed the Administrator to consider "the total cost of
application of technology in relation to the effluent reduction
benefits to be achieved from such application." 33 U.S.C. §
1314(b)(1) ("BPT" limitations). With regard to 1987 effluent
limitations, the Administrator is directed to consider total cost,
but not in comparison with effluent reduction benefits. §
1314(b)(2)(B) ("BAT" limitations).
See EPA v. National Crushed
Stone Assn., 449 U. S. 64,
449 U. S. 71, n.
10,
449 U. S. 76-77
(1980) .
In other statutes, Congress has used the phrase "unreasonable
risk," accompanied by explanation in legislative history, to
signify a generalized balancing of costs and benefits.
See,
e.g., the Consumer Product Safety Act of 1972, 15 U.S.C. §
2056(a) ("unreasonable risk of injury"); H.R.Rep. No. 92-1153, p.
33 (1972) (where the House stated: "It should be noted that the
Commission's authority to promulgate standards under this bill is
limited to instances where the hazard associated with a consumer
product presents an unreasonable risk of death, injury, or serious
or frequent illness. . . . Protection against unreasonable risks is
central to many Federal and State safety statutes, and the courts
have had broad experience in interpreting the term's meaning and
application. It is generally expected that the determination of
unreasonable hazard will involve the Commission in balancing the
probability that risk will result in harm and the gravity of such
harm against the effect on the product's utility, cost, and
availability to the consumer"); S.Rep. No. 92-749, pp. 14-15
(1972).
See also Aqua Slide 'N' Dive Corp. v. Consumer Product
Safety Comm'n, 569 F.2d 831, 839 (CA5 1978);
Forester v.
Consumer Product Safety Comm'n, 182 U.S.App.D.C. 153, 168, 559
F.2d 774, 789 (1977). The error of several cases finding a
cost-benefit analysis mandate in the Act is their reliance on the
different language and clear legislative history of the Consumer
Product Safety Act to reach their conclusions.
See Texas
Independent Ginners Assn. v. Marshall, 630 F.2d 398, 410 (CA5
1980);
American Petroleum Institute v. OSHA, 581 F.2d 493,
502-503 (CA5 1978),
aff'd on other grounds, Industrial Union
Dept. v. American Petroleum Institute, supra.
Senator Chiles was sufficiently certain that the Act did not
contemplate cost-benefit analysis that he introduced an amendment
in 1973 that,
inter alia,
"directs the Secretary to recognize the cost-benefit ratio in
promulgating a new standard and to publish information relative to
the projected financial impact. This provision will promote the
development of standards justifiable in terms of the benefits to be
derived and afford those to be affected an opportunity to make a
reasoned evaluation of the proposal."
119 Cong.Rec. 42151 (1973).
[
Footnote 31]
In addition, as the legislative history makes plain,
see
infra at
452 U. S.
517-518, any standard that was not economically or
technologically feasible would
a fortiori not be
"reasonably necessary or appropriate" under the Act.
See
Industrial Union Dept. v. Hodson, 162 U.S.App.D.C. 331, 342,
499 F.2d 467, 478 (1974) ("Congress does not appear to have
intended to protect employees by putting their employers out of
business").
[
Footnote 32]
This is not to say that § 3(8) might not require the balancing
of costs and benefits for standards promulgated under provisions
other than § 6(b)(5) of the Act. As a plurality of this Court noted
in
Industrial Union Dept., if § 3(8) had no substantive
content,
"there would be no statutory criteria at all to guide the
Secretary in promulgating either national consensus standards or
permanent standards other than those dealing with toxic materials
and harmful physical agents."
448 U.S. at
448 U. S. 640,
n. 45. Furthermore, the mere fact that a § 6(b)(5) standard is
"feasible" does not mean that § 3(8)'s "reasonably necessary or
appropriate" language might not impose additional restraints on
OSHA. For example, all § 6(b)(5) standards must be addressed to
"significant risks" of material health impairment.
Id. at
448 U. S. 642.
In addition, if the use of one respirator would achieve the same
reduction in health risk as the use of five, the use of five
respirators was "technologically and economically feasible," and
OSHA thus insisted on the use of five, then the "reasonably
necessary or appropriate" limitation might come into play as an
additional restriction on OSHA to choose the one-respirator
standard. In this case, we need not decide all the applications
that § 3(8) might have, either alone or together with §
6(b)(5).
[
Footnote 33]
Although both versions of the Act contained provisions identical
to § 3(8), 29 U.S.C. § 652(8), there is no discussion in the
legislative history of the meaning of the phrase "reasonably
necessary or appropriate."
[
Footnote 34]
Petitioners' primary legislative history argument is that
Senator Javits
"took the position that OSHA standards should be 'feasible' in
the sense of being 'reasonable' and 'practical' as well as
technologically achievable."
Brief for Petitioners in No. 79-1429, p. 32. A review of the
record belies this contention. Senator .Javits himself had
introduced the administration's bill, S. 2788, 91st Cong., 1st
Sess. (1969), which he observed contained no criteria for issuance
of standards. Leg.Hist. 31, 39-42. That proposed legislation, which
established a National Occupational Safety and Health Board to
promulgate standards, required the Board to submit proposed
standards to an appropriate national standards-producing
organization "to prepare a report on the technical feasibility,
reasonableness and practicality of such standard."
Id. at
39. Furthermore, either the Secretary of Labor or the Secretary of
Health, Education, and Welfare could object to a proposed standard
on the basis,
inter alia, that it "is not feasible,"
id. at 40, at which point the Board could reaffirm the
standard by a majority vote,
ibid. President Nixon's
message accompanying S. 2788, which Senator Javits inserted in the
Congressional Record, described the "report on the technical
feasibility, reasonableness and practicality of such standard"
under the Act as a "report on the feasibility of the proposed
standards." 115 Cong.Rec. 22517 (1969).
From this slim reed, petitioners fashion their legislative
history argument. But even if Senator Javits fully subscribed to
statements by President Nixon on the proposed legislation, of which
there is some doubt,
see id. at 22512, this hardly
supports the view that the Senator's addition of the feasibility
requirement to the Williams bill included any such baggage. After
all, the Senator described his amendment only with the word
"feasible," and specifically distinguished the amended Williams
bill from the administration's on the basis of the latter's lack of
criteria.
[
Footnote 35]
Senator Dominick gave several examples. For instance:
"[L]et us take a fellow who is a streetcar conductor or a bus
conductor at the present time. How in the world, in the process of
the pollution we have in the streets or in the process of the
automobile accidents that we have all during a working day of
anyone driving a bus or trolley car, or whatever it may be, can we
set standards that will make sure he will not have any risk to his
life for the rest of his life? It is totally impossible for this to
be put in a bill; and yet it is in the committee bill."
116 Cong.Rec. 37337 (1970), Leg.Hist. 423.
See also 116
Cong.Rec. at 37614, 36522, Leg.Hist. 481, 345.
[
Footnote 36]
In acceding, the House obtained Senate agreement to another
amendment, now § 6(b)(6)(A) of the Act, that allowed employers to
petition for a temporary variance from an occupational safety and
health standard in certain cases, except that "[e]conomic hardship
is not to be a consideration for the qualification for a temporary
extension order." H.R.Conf.Rep. No. 91-1765, p. 35 (1970),
Leg.Hist. 1188. The Conference Report limited the variance
procedure to the following cases:
"unavailability of professional or technical personnel or of
necessary materials or equipment or because necessary construction
or alteration of facilities cannot be completed on time. . . . Such
an order may be issued for a maximum period of one year, and may
not be renewed more than twice."
Ibid.
[
Footnote 37]
Because the costs of compliance would weigh particularly heavily
on small businesses, Congress provided in § 28 of the Act an
amendment to the Small Business Act, 15 U.S.C. § 636, making small
businesses eligible for economic assistance through the Small
Business Administration to comply with standards promulgated by the
Secretary. 84 Stat. 1618, Leg.Hist. 1257. Senator Dominick
explained:
"There is a provision in the bill which recognizes the impact
that this particular legislation may have on small businesses. . .
. It permits the Secretary to make loans to small businesses
wherever the standards that are set by the National Government are
so severe as to have caused a real and substantial economic injury.
Under those circumstances, the Secretary is entitled, through the
Small Business Administration, to make loans to those businesses to
get them over the hump, because of the need for new equipment, or
because of new conditions within the shop, which would permit them
to continue in operation."
"I think that is a very significant and important provision for
minimizing economic injury which could occur if the bill resulted
in situations which would have very serious effects on
businesses."
116 Cong.Rec. 37631 (1970), Leg.Hist. 525.
[
Footnote 38]
Congress was concerned that some employers not obtain a
competitive advantage over others by declining to invest in worker
health and safety:
"Although many employers in all industries have demonstrated an
exemplary degree of concern for health and safety in the workplace,
their efforts are too often undercut by those who are not so
concerned. Moreover, the fact is that many employers --
particularly smaller ones -- simply cannot make the necessary
investment in health and safety, and survive competitively, unless
all are compelled to do so."
S.Rep. 91-1282, p. 4 (1970), Leg.Hist. 144.
[
Footnote 39]
See, e.g., 116 Cong.Rec. 38386 (1970), Leg.Hist.
1030-1031 (remarks of Cong. Dent):
"Although I am very much disturbed over adding new costs to the
operation of our production facilities because of the threats from
abroad, I would say there is a greater concern, and that must be
for the production men who do the producing -- the men who work in
the service industries and the men and women in this country who
daily go out and keep the economy moving and make it safe for all
of us to live and to work and to be able to prosper in it."
[
Footnote 40]
See RTI, Cotton Dust: Technological Feasibility
Assessment and Final Inflationary Impact Statement (1976), Ex.
6-76, Ct. of App. J.A. 457, 573-748; RTI, Technological Feasibility
and Economic Impact of Regulations for Cotton Dust: Testimony to be
Presented by the Research Triangle Institute at Public Hearing
(1977), Ex. 16,
id. at 1320, 1351-1357. The industry
estimates were presented by Hovan Hocutt and Arthur Thomas,
employees of dust control equipment manufacturers. Statement of
Hovan Hocutt, Senior Vice President, Engineering, Pneumafil Corp.,
Ex. 60,
id. at 2228-2247; Statement of Arthur Thomas,
Senior Vice President, The Bahnson Co., Ex. 62,
id. at
2248-2257. OSHA referred collectively to these two statements as
the Hocutt-Thomas estimate.
[
Footnote 41]
RTI estimated compliance costs of $984.4 million for yarn
production (opening through spinning), Ex. 6-76,
id. at
473, and $127.7 million for yarn processing (winding through
weaving/slashing),
id. at 600. In another part of its
study, RTI estimated yarn production costs of $885.6 million.
Id. at 589. The explanation for this discrepancy is not
readily apparent from the record, although it may be attributable
to cost estimates for different years.
[
Footnote 42]
RTI made what it called a "conservative estimate" that
"controls would be applied to all the production equipment in
mills processing cotton and cotton-synthetic blends, even if part
of their product is pure synthetic."
Id. at 585.
[
Footnote 43]
RTI's David LeSourd explained that RTI did not have data on the
degree of compliance for the industry as a whole, but only for some
specific mills.
Id. at 3637-3638. Therefore RTI merely
assumed that industrywide PEL's were at a 1,000 �g/m^3 total dust
PEL. Ex. 6-76,
id. at 579-580. The record contains
conflicting evidence on the actual level of control in the
industry. Some evidence suggests compliance by mills substantially
better than the 1,000 �g/m^3 total dust level.
See, e.g.,
Ex. 47,
id. at 2037 (66% of Burlington Industries work
areas at or below 500 �g/m^3, 28% below 200 �g/m^3); Ex. 78,
id. at 2387. One expert, commenting on another study,
observed that "substantial proportions of the industry are, in
fact, within compliance of [200 �g/m^3]."
Id. at 3637.
Other evidence in the record suggests that some segments of the
industry are not in compliance with the 1,000 �g/m^3 total dust
PEL.
See, e.g., id. at 3939 (criticizing RTI assumption of
compliance). In any event, OSHA found that the "actual level of
controls in the cotton industry could not be determined" on the
basis of data available to RTI at the time of its study. 43
Fed.Reg. 27370, col. 3 (1978).
[
Footnote 44]
OSHA's cost estimate included $543 million for engineering
controls (the Hocutt-Thomas estimate), $7 million for monitoring,
medical surveillance, and other provisions (the RTI estimate),
$31.5 million for waste processing, and $75 million for seed
processing, for a total of $656.5 million.
Id. at 27380,
col. 1.
[
Footnote 45]
The Hocutt-Thomas study based its estimates on data obtained
from a recent ATMI survey of cotton mills. Completed questionnaires
from 353 mills, which processed 80% of the cotton bales in the
United States, were returned. Ex. 60, Ct. of App. J.A. 2231.
[
Footnote 46]
The Hocutt-Thomas study included an allowance for existing
compliance efforts, by subtracting from its total estimate the cost
of all engineering controls purchased by the industry prior to
February 11, 1977.
Id. at 2232, 2247. Whether this is a
sufficient proxy for current industry compliance is not apparent
from the record. Hocutt himself admitted that he did not have
figures on what portion of the industry was meeting the 1,000
�g/m^3 total dust PEL.
Id. at 3941.
[
Footnote 47]
John Figh, a vice-president at Chase Manhattan Bank specializing
in the textile industry, commented on the trend toward modernizing
equipment in the mills:
"[B]y continuing to upgrade plants with the most modern and
efficient equipment, the textile manufacturing industry will likely
not be required due to demand to add much in the way of new bricks
and mortar. There may be some individual cases of out-of-date
facilities being replaced by new buildings; but, for the most part,
I believe we will see
more in the way of modernization of
existing plants. . . ."
Ex. 63,
id. at 2260 (emphasis added). One study
explained why the costs of controls should be lower if a mill
converts to new equipment as opposed to retrofitting old
machines:
"1) The operating cost of new equipment with controls on that
equipment is less than the operating cost of the old equipment with
controls necessary for the older, slower equipment to meet
proscribed [
sic] dust levels; and 2) by going to newer
equipment with controls, there is a likelihood that increased
production rates will result in recovery of some or all of the
capital cost of control."
Ex. 79A,
id. at 2532;
see Ex. 79C,
id. at 2550-2551; Ex. 63,
id. at 2261; Ex. 78,
id. at 2376-2377.
[
Footnote 48]
Chase Manhattan Bank vice-president Figh noted that
"[t]here does not appear to be any vast new technology on the
horizon,' but that, '[a]s for new machinery, evolutionary changes
are continuing at what appears to me to be about the same rate as
in the last few years."
Ex. 63,
id. at 2260-2261. One study is particularly
critical of the assumption of a "static state of technology," Ex.
78,
id. at 2380, and documents technological advances that
can be expected,
id. at 2380-2386. Some experts were less
optimistic of the role of technology.
See, e.g., id. at
3643644 (RTI study).
[
Footnote 49]
Hocutt-Thomas had some information on the "ratio of synthetics
to cotton in blends" in the mills, but it is not clear from the
record if and how they used this information. Ex. 60,
id.
at 2230.
[
Footnote 50]
The final Cotton Dust Standard calls for PEL's of 200 �g/m^3 in
opening through roving and spinning through warping, and 750 �g/m^3
for slashing and weaving. The Hocutt-Thomas study similarly assumed
a 200 �g/m^3 PEL for opening through roving, but assumed less
stringent PEL's of 500 �g/m^3 for spinning through warping, and
1,000 �g/m^3 for slashing and weaving.
[
Footnote 51]
For example, in questioning before an Administrative Law Judge,
Hocutt answered:
"Well, I'm beginning to wish I hadn't said anything about this,
which I did, and I have to be helpful. Practically all of this
information that I have is confidential, and I couldn't reveal any
of the sources. You can only take my word for the figures. I can't
substantiate it in any manner."
Id. at 3929. Petitioners note, however, that the
industry subsequently provided its survey data to OSHA, and that
the only information deleted was confidential information withheld
by agreement with the agency in order to prevent identification of
specific mills. Reply Brief for Petitioners in No. 79-1429, p. 23,
n. 32;
see App. 388-390. OSHA responds that,
"[b]ecause the number of machines was deleted and correlated
dust data were not supplied, the data could not be used to support
a specific cost adjustment."
Brief for Federal Respondent 64, n. 70. In any event, no
contention is made that OSHA had access to Hocutt's own data used
to calculate his cost estimate.
[
Footnote 52]
Both petitioners and respondents attempt their own calculations
from evidence in the record to show the unreasonableness or
reasonableness of OSHA's rough equation between the Hocutt-Thomas
overstatement in costs and the expense of achieving a standard
somewhat more stringent for some operations.
See, e.g.,
Brief for Petitioner in No. 79-1583, pp. 9-10; Brief for Union
Respondents 14-18. Such manipulation of the data suggests a wide
margin of error for any estimate, whether it be OSHA's, the
industry's, or the unions'. Viewed in that light, the agency's
candor in confessing its own inability to achieve a more precise
estimate should not precipitate a judicial review that nonetheless
demands what the congressionally delegated "expert" says it cannot
provide.
[
Footnote 53]
The Secretary originally asked RTI to prepare cost estimates for
several PEL levels, including 500, 200, and 100 �g/m^3. Ex. 6-76,
Ct. of App. J.A. 509. Clearly the Secretary intended to have cost
information on the different PEL's that he might promulgate.
Although RTI provided estimates for these levels in its final
report, OSHA found them to be too unreliable to adopt as final
estimates.
See supra at
452 U. S.
524-525.
Even if the Secretary had wanted to obtain a cost estimate based
on confidential industry data for the actual PEL's in the adopted
Standard, he would have been unable to do so. Hocutt had concluded
that it was technologically impractical to achieve PEL's below 500
�g/m^3 for the operations of spinning through warping, Ex. 60, Ct.
of App. J.A. 2239-2241, and PEL's below 1,000 �g/m^3 for weaving
and slashing,
id. at 2241-2243. Therefore, he declined to
prepare cost estimates of a 200 �g/m^3 PEL for those operations.
The Secretary obviously disagreed with his judgment of
technological feasibility. We also note that, although petitioners
challenged the technological feasibility of the final Cotton Dust
Standard in the Court of Appeals, they have abandoned such
challenge here. Brief for Petitioners in No. 79-1429, p. 8, n.
16.
[
Footnote 54]
The Court of Appeals observed that "the agency's underlying cost
estimates are not free from imprecision," 199 U.S.App.D.C. at 80,
617 F.2d at 662, but that "[t]he very nature of economic analysis
frequently imposes practical limits on the precision which
reasonably can be required of the agency,"
id. at 79, 617
F.2d at 661. We suspect that this results not only from the
difficulty of obtaining accurate data, but also from the inherent
crudeness of estimation tools. Of necessity, both the RTI and
Hocutt-Thomas studies had to rely on assumptions the truth or
falsity of which could wreak havoc on the validity of their final
numerical cost estimates. As the official charged by Congress with
the promulgation of occupational safety and health standards that
protect workers "to the extent feasible," the Secretary was
obligated to subject such assumptions to careful scrutiny, and to
decide how they might affect the correctness of the proffered
estimates.
[
Footnote 55]
In one of their questions presented, petitioners ATMI
et
al. ask whether
"the statutory requirement that compliance with an OSHA standard
must be 'economically feasible' can be satisfied merely by the
agency's conclusion that the standard will not put the affected
industry out of business."
Pet. for Cert. in No. 79-1429, p. 2. However, in argument in
their brief, petitioners appear to treat this issue primarily as a
substantial evidence question.
See Brief for Petitioners
in No. 79-1429, pp. 24-31. They finally summarize their position as
follows:
"OSHA must present a responsible prediction, supported by
substantial evidence, of what its standard will cost and what
impact it will have on such factors as production, employment,
competition, and prices. And the agency must explain in a cogent
manner -- on the basis of intelligible criteria -- why it concludes
that a standard having such an economic impact is 'feasible.'"
Id. at 35 (footnote omitted).
As our review of OSHA's economic feasibility determination
demonstrates, OSHA presented a "responsible prediction" of what its
Standard would cost and its impact on "production, employment,
competition, and prices." The agency concluded that its Standard is
feasible because "compliance with [it] is well within the financial
capability of the covered industries." 43 Fed.Reg. 27379, col. 3
(1978). OSHA also found that the industry "will be able to meet the
demands for production of cotton products."
Id. at 27378,
col. 2. We take these findings to mean, as the Secretary suggests,
that, "[a]t bottom, the Secretary must [and did] determine that the
industry will maintain long-term profitability and
competitiveness." Brief for Federal Respondent 49.
See also
United Steelworkers of America v. Marshall, 208 U.S.App.D.C.
60, 136, 647 F.2d 1189, 1265 (1981) ("the practical question is
whether the standard threatens the competitive stability of an
industry");
Industrial Union Dept. v. Hodgson, 162
U.S.App.D.C. at 342, 499 F.2d at 478. This interpretation by the
Secretary is certainly consistent with the plain meaning of the
word "feasible."
See Industrial Union Dept. v. American
Petroleum Institute, 448 U.S. at
448 U. S.
717-718, n. 30 (MARSHALL, J., dissenting). Therefore,
these cases do not present, and we do not decide, the question
whether a standard that threatens the long-term profitability and
competitiveness of an industry is "feasible" within the meaning of
§ 6(b)(5) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. § 655(b)(5)
[
Footnote 56]
In contrast to the compliance cost estimates prepared by RTI,
OSHA did not find any major flaws with RTI's study of the economic
impact of compliance costs.
[
Footnote 57]
RTI specifically analyzed the impact of the Standard on the
following areas in the cotton industry:
"1) Additional employment requirements."
"2) Energy consumption."
"3) Increases in production costs and consequent price increases
by affected industries."
"4) Capital requirements and capital financing problems."
"5) Competition effects on profit and market structure."
"6) Inflationary impact on consumers and U.S. economy."
"7) Employment impact due to the contraction of output
demand."
Ex. 6-76, Ct. of App. J.A. 626. RTI also examined the economic
impact of two other across-the-board PEL's of 500 �g/m^3 and 100
�g/m^3.
Ibid.
[
Footnote 58]
This cost estimate included $984.4 million for yarn production
(opening through spinning), $1,387.9 billion for winding through
weaving/slashing, $292.2 million for cotton ginning, and $32
million for waste processing.
Id. at 737.
[
Footnote 59]
Cotton ginning was the subject of separate regulation not at
issue here. 43 Fed.Reg. 27350, col. 1 (1978);
see 29 CFR §
1910.1046 (1980).
[
Footnote 60]
RTI's annual cost-of-compliance figure contained three
components: an annualized capital charge, direct operating cost,
and energy cost. Ex. 6-76, Ct. of App. J.A. 643. The annualized
capital charge consisted of depreciation, interest, administrative
overhead, property tax, and insurance.
Ibid. Depreciation
and interest were computed
"by use of a capital recovery factor based upon the concept of
capital rent, the value of which depends on the operating life of
the equipment and the market interest rate."
Ibid.
[
Footnote 61]
Petitioners' primary criticism of OSHA's reliance on the RTI
study derives from their disagreement with RTI's assumption that
compliance costs would be passed on to the consumers. Brief for
Petitioners in No. 79-1429, pp. 28-29. This characterization
misstates RTI's position. In calculating price increases necessary
to maintain pre-standard rates of return, RTI "decided to adopt an
extreme assumption of zero price demand elasticity in computing
post-control price increases" because of difficulties in obtaining
data necessary to compute elasticities for cotton yarns. Ex. 6-76,
Ct. of App. J.A. 657. However, RTI carefully tested this assumption
to determine "how much bias" it would introduce into the analysis.
Id. at 657-659. RTI concluded that,
"unless the true demand elasticity for the output of the given
sector is substantially greater than unity, our impact analysis
based on the assumption of zero price elasticity of demand would
not be invalidated."
Id. at 659. Therefore, unless a 1% increase in price
was met with substantially more than a 1% decrease in demand, RTI's
estimates of the price increases necessary to maintain pre-standard
rates of return were valid. Since there was no evidence suggesting
such an effect, RTI proceeded with its assumption.
In any event, RTI subsequently investigated short-term price
elasticities of demand for 25 cotton consumer products, finding
that 19 of them had elasticities less than or equal to unity.
Id. at 681.
[
Footnote 62]
RTI found higher price increases and lower rates of return when
framing its analysis in pounds of cotton yarn produced.
See
id. at 654, 729-730.
[
Footnote 63]
Petitioner National Cotton Council of America criticizes RTI's
use of short-term price elasticity coefficients, claiming that this
underestimates long-term demand responses to price increases. Brief
for Petitioner in No. 79-1583, pp. 16-17. However, RTI's Dr. Lee,
who conducted the elasticity analysis, observed that he used two
independent procedures to compute demand contraction, and only one
relied on short-term price elasticities. Ct. of App. J.A.
3626-3627. His "main procedure [was] input output table
procedures," which produced an even smaller demand contraction
estimate than those calculations relying on the short-term
coefficients.
Ibid.
[
Footnote 64]
RTI cited such nonprice factors as "research expenditures,
promotion and advertising, fiber and fabric development, fiber
properties, and care characteristics of fabric." Ex. 6-76,
id. at 623. John Figh, Chase Manhattan Bank
vice-president, observed that
"polyester has grown at the expense of cotton over the last 10
years, and I think it has penetrated most of the markets it can
penetrate. . . . [T]he majority of it, the growth of polyester at
the expense of cotton, has been completed."
App. 474-475. He noted that some cotton products, such as towels
and 100% cotton men's shirts, enjoy the support of consumer
preferences.
Ibid. Although RTI cited the energy crisis
without detailing its possible impact on man-made fiber products,
Ex. 6-76, Ct. of App. J.A. 948, OSHA observed that changes in
petroleum prices, a key ingredient in synthetic products, may have
important impacts on the competitive balance,
see 43
Fed.Reg. 27370, col. 2 (1978).
[
Footnote 65]
Two of the six yarn production operations had ratios less than
1, two had ratios less than 2, and the remaining two were less than
6. Ex. 6-76, Ct. of App. J.A. 665. Chase Manhattan Bank's John Figh
agreed with RTI's assessment that financing the $2.7 billion
compliance cost for a 200 �g/m^3 PEL standard would be most
difficult for smaller textile companies. Ex. 63,
id. at
2264-2265.
[
Footnote 66]
RTI conducted similar economic impact analyses, although in less
depth, for the twisting through weaving and waste-processing
sectors of the cotton industry covered by the proposed 200 �g/m^3
PEL standard. Ex. 6-76,
id. at 462. RTI found, for
example, that price increases per dollar of industry sales ranged
from 0.5 cents to 18 cents for twisting through weaving operations,
and that some of these operations would experience "severe"
financing difficulties.
Id. at 733-734. To recount in
further detail these conclusions would be an irrelevant exercise.
RTI calculated that a 200 �g/m^3 standard for weaving/slashing
would cost $1.259 billion,
id. at 600, and computed the
economic impact based on that figure. But RTI had also estimated
that compliance costs for a 500 �g/m^3 PEL would be zero.
Ibid. Since the final Cotton Dust Standard sets a 750
�g/m^3 PEL for weaving/slashing, further review of RTI's conclusion
with respect to its $1.259 billion cost is particularly
unnecessary.
[
Footnote 67]
Petitioners note that, although RTI estimated that compliance
with the Cotton Dust Standard would take eight or more years, OSHA
required compliance within four years. Brief for Petitioners in No.
79-1429, p. 29. RTI chose an 8-year period primarily because of
"problems the control industry may have in supplying the required
equipment." App. 415;
see id. at 415-416. If this proves
to be the case, then presumably individual mills will be able to
obtain variances from the Standard's requirements because of
technological infeasibility.
See 29 CFR § 1910.1043(e)(1)
(1980); 29 U.S.C. § 655(b).
[
Footnote 68]
Perhaps in light of this fact, neither petitioners ATMI
et
al. nor petitioner National Cotton Council of America frame
their "economic impact" substantial evidence arguments based on
OSHA's estimate of compliance costs. Instead, they adopt as a
minimum RTI's $2.7 billion estimate for compliance costs with the
proposed standard's 200 �g/m^3 PEL. Brief for Petitioner in No.
79-1583, pp. 15-16; Brief for Petitioners in No. 79-1429, p.
29.
[
Footnote 69]
The final Standard, 29 CFR § 1910.1043(f)(1) (1980),
provides:
"Where the use of respirators is required under this section,
the employer shall provide, at no cost to the employee, and assure
the use of respirators which comply with the requirements of this
paragraph (f). Respirators shall be used in the following
circumstances:"
"(i) During the time periods necessary to install or implement
feasible engineering controls and work practice controls;"
"(ii) During maintenance and repair activities in which
engineering and work practice controls are not feasible;"
"(iii) In work situations where feasible engineering and work
practice controls are not yet sufficient to reduce exposure to or
below the permissible exposure limit; and"
"(iv) In operations specified under paragraph (g)(1);"
"(v) Whenever an employee requests a respirator."
[
Footnote 70]
An employee may be unable to wear a respirator because of facial
irritation, severe discomfort, or impaired breathing. 43 Fed.Reg.
27387, cols. 1 and 2 (1978).
[
Footnote 71]
The regulation, 29 CFR § 1019.1043(f)(2)(v) (1980) (emphasis
added), provides:
"Whenever a physician determines that an employee is unable to
wear any form of respirator, including a power air purifying
respirator, the employee shall be given the opportunity to transfer
to another position which is available or which later becomes
available having a dust level at or below the PEL.
The employer
shall assure that an employee who is transferred due to an
inability to wear a respirator suffers no loss of earnings or other
employment rights or benefits as a result of the
transfer."
[
Footnote 72]
Although it cited no specific determination or statement of
reasons proffered by the Secretary, the Court of Appeals was
persuaded by this argument. 199 U.S.App.D.C. at 93, 617 F.2d at
675.
[
Footnote 73]
There is evidence in the record that might support such a
determination. Dr. Merchant testified that a medical surveillance
program alone would not be sufficient for identifying and
relocating employees suffering from byssinosis. App. 440-441. He
observed:
"There is reluctance very often among the employee himself to
leave his job. I think clearly some guarantees as to wages and
opportunities must be an integral part of any recommendation to
relocate somebody, and it has been the experience in coal mining
where miners are allowed, under the Coal Mine Health and Safety Act
of 1968, to be transferred, a very low proportion of these men
actually exercise their transfer rights."
Id. at 441.
However, the courts will not be expected to scrutinize the
record to uncover and formulate a rationale explaining an action,
when the agency in the first instance has failed to articulate such
rationale.
See Automotive Parts & Accessories Assn. v.
Boyd, 132 U.S.App.D.C. 200, 208, 407 F.2d 330, 338 (1968).
[
Footnote 74]
In its specific discussion of the transfer/guarantee provision,
occupying more than two-thirds of a page in the Federal Register,
OSHA argued that
"[i]t is manifestly unfair that employees who are unable to wear
respirators suffer . . . economic detriment because their employers
have not yet achieved compliance with the engineering control
requirements of the standard, but are relying instead on the
interim and less effective device of respirators."
43 Fed.Reg. 27387, cols. 2 and 3 (1978). The agency then stated
its judgment that the
"protection [the transfer and guarantee regulation] affords
should greatly increase the success of the standard's respiratory
protection provisions."
Id. at 27387, col. 3. Since the Secretary had already
presented an unauthorized reason for the guarantee provision, we
decline to accept this "boilerplate" statement as a sufficient
determination and statement of reasons within the meaning of the
Act. 29 U.S.C. §§ 655 (e),(f).
See Synthetic Organic Chemical
Manufacturers Assn. v. Brennan, 503 F.2d 1155, 1157, 1160 (CA3
1974),
cert. denied, 420 U.S. 973 (1975);
Industrial
Union Dept. v. Hodson, 162 U.S.App.D.C. at 339-340, 499 F.2d
at 475-476;
Associated Industries of New York State, Inc. v.
U.S. Dept. of Labor, 487 F.2d 342, 354 (CA2 1973);
Dry
Color Manufacturers' Assn. v. Department of Labor, 486 F.2d
98, 105-106 (CA3 1973).
See also Berger & Riskin,
Economic and Technological Feasibility in Regulating Toxic
Substances Under the Occupational Safety and Health Act, 7 Ecology
L.Q. 285, 298-299 (1978).
[
Footnote 75]
Even had JUSTICE REHNQUIST correctly characterized the Court's
opinion,
post at
452 U. S. 544
-- and there were three possible constructions of the phrase "to
the extent feasible" -- this would hardly have been grounds for
invalidating § 6(b)(5) under the delegation doctrine. After all,
this would not be the first time that more than one interpretation
of a statute had been argued.
See, e.g., Pennhurst State School
v. Halderman, 451 U. S. 1 (1981);
Watt v. Alaska, 451 U. S. 259
(1981).
JUSTICE STEWART, dissenting.
Section 6(b)(5) of the Occupational Safety and Health Act
provides:
"The Secretary, in promulgating standards dealing with toxic
materials or harmful physical agents under this subsection, shall
set the standard which most adequately assures,
to the extent
feasible, on the basis of the best available evidence, that no
employee will suffer material impairment of health or functional
capacity even if such employee has regular exposure to the hazard
dealt with by such standard for the period of his working
life."
29 U.S.C. § 655(b)(5) (emphasis added).
Page 452 U. S. 542
Everybody agrees that, under this statutory provision, the
Cotton Dust Standard must at least be economically feasible, and
everybody would also agree, I suppose, that, in order to determine
whether or not something is economically feasible, one must have a
fairly clear idea of how much it is going to cost. Because I
believe that OSHA failed to justify its estimate of the cost of the
Cotton Dust Standard on the basis of substantial evidence, I would
reverse the judgment before us without reaching the question
whether the Act requires that a standard, beyond being economically
feasible, must meet the demands of a cost-benefit examination.
The simple truth about OSHA's assessment of the cost of the
Cotton Dust Standard is that the agency never relied on any study
or report purporting to predict the cost to industry of the
Standard finally adopted by the agency. OSHA did have before it one
cost analysis, that of the Research Triangle Institute, which
attempted to predict the cost of the final Standard. However, as
recognized by the Court,
ante at
452 U. S.
524-525, the agency flatly rejected that prediction as a
gross overestimate. The only other estimate OSHA had, the
Hocutt-Thomas estimate prepared by industry researchers, was not
designed to predict the cost of the final OSHA Standard. Rather, it
assumed a far less stringent and inevitably far less costly
standard for all phases of cotton production except roving.
Ante at
452 U. S. 527,
n. 50. The agency examined the Hocutt-Thomas study and concluded
that it too was an overestimate of the costs of the less stringent
standard it was addressing. I am willing to defer to OSHA's
determination that the Hocutt-Thomas study was such an
overestimate, conceding that such subtle financial and technical
matters lie within the discretion and skill of the agency. But in a
remarkable
non sequitur, the agency decided that, because
the Hocutt-Thomas study was an overestimate of the cost of a less
stringent standard, it could be treated as a reliable estimate for
the more costly final Standard actually promulgated, never
rationally explaining how it came to this happy
Page 452 U. S. 543
conclusion. This is not substantial evidence. It is unsupported
speculation.
Of course, as the Court notes, this Court will reexamine a court
of appeals' review of a question of substantial evidence "only in
what ought to be the rare instance when the standard appears to
have been misapprehended or grossly misapplied."
Universal
Camera Corp. v. NLRB, 340 U. S. 474,
340 U. S. 491.
But I think this is one of those rare instances where an agency has
categorically misconceived the nature of the evidence necessary to
support a regulation, and where the Court of Appeals has failed to
correct the agency's error. Of course, broad generalizations about
the meaning of "substantial evidence" have limited value in
deciding particular cases. But within the confines of a single
statute, where the agency and reviewing courts have identified
certain specific factual matters to be proved, we can establish
practical general criteria for comprehending "substantial
evidence."
Unlike the Court, I think it clear to the point of being obvious
that, as a matter of law, OSHA's prediction of the cost of the
Cotton Dust Standard lacks a basis in substantial evidence, since
the agency did not rely on even a single estimate of the cost of
the actual Standard it promulgated. Accordingly, I respectfully
dissent.
JUSTICE REHNQUIST, with whom THE CHIEF JUSTICE joins,
dissenting.
A year ago I stated my belief that Congress, in enacting §
6(b)(5) of the Occupational Safety and Health Act of 1970,
unconstitutionally delegated to the Executive Branch the authority
to make the "hard policy choices" properly the task of the
legislature.
Industrial Union Dept. v. American Petroleum
Institute, 448 U. S. 607,
448 U. S. 671
(1980) (concurring in judgment). Because I continue to believe that
the Act exceeds Congress' power to delegate legislative authority
to nonelected officials,
see 276 U. S. W.
Hampton Co. v. United
Page 452 U. S. 544
States, 276 U. S. 394
(1928), and
Panama Refining Co. v. Ryan, 293 U.
S. 388 (1935), I dissent.
I will repeat only a little of what I said last Term. Section
6(b)(5) provides in pertinent part:
"The Secretary, in promulgating standards dealing with toxic
materials or harmful physical agents under this subsection, shall
set the standard which most adequately assures,
to the extent
feasible, on the basis of the best available evidence, that no
employee will suffer material impairment of health or functional
capacity even if such employee has regular exposure to the hazard
dealt with by such standard for the period of his working
life."
(Emphasis added.)
As the Court correctly observes, the phrase "to the extent
feasible" contains the critical language for the purpose of these
cases. We are presented with a remarkable range of interpretations
of that language. Petitioners contend that the statute requires the
Secretary to demonstrate that the benefits of its "Cotton Dust
Standard," in terms of reducing health risks, bear a reasonable
relationship to its costs. Brief for Petitioners in No. 79-1429,
pp. 38-41. Respondents, including the Secretary of Labor at least
until his postargument motion, counter that Congress itself
balanced costs and benefits when it enacted the statute, and that
the statute prohibits the Secretary from engaging in a cost-benefit
type balancing. Their view is that the Act merely requires the
Secretary to promulgate standards that eliminate or reduce such
risks "to the extent . . . technologically or economically
feasible." Brief for Federal Respondent 38; Brief for Union
Respondents 26-27. As I read the Court's opinion, it takes a
different position. It concludes that, at least as to the "Cotton
Dust Standard," the Act does not require the Secretary to engage in
a cost-benefit analysis, which suggests, of course, that the Act
permits the Secretary to undertake such an analysis if he so
chooses.
Ante at
452 U. S.
510-512.
Page 452 U. S. 545
Throughout its opinion, the Court refers to § 6(b)(5) as
adopting a "feasibility standard" or a "feasibility requirement."
Ante at
452 U. S.
508-522. But as I attempted to point out last Term in
Industrial Union Dept. v. American Petroleum Institute,
supra, at
448 U. S.
681-685, the "feasibility standard" is no standard at
all. Quite the contrary, I argued there that the insertion into §
6(b)(5) of the words "to the extent feasible" rendered what had
been a clear, if somewhat unrealistic, statute into one so vague
and precatory as to be an unconstitutional delegation of
legislative authority to the Executive Branch. Prior to the
inclusion of the "feasibility" language, § 6(b)(5) simply required
the Secretary to
"set the standard which most adequately assures, on the basis of
the best available professional evidence, that no employee will
suffer any impairment of health. . . ."
Legislative History, Occupational Safety and Health Act of 1970,
p. 943 (Comm. Print 1971) (hereinafter Leg.Hist.). Had that statute
been enacted, it would undoubtedly support the result the Court
reaches in these cases, and it would not have created an excessive
delegation problem. The Secretary of Labor would quite clearly have
been authorized to set exposure standards without regard to any
kind of cost-benefit analysis.
But Congress did not enact that statute. The legislative history
of the Act reveals that a number of Members of Congress, such as
Senators Javits, Saxbe, and Dominick, had difficulty with the
proposed statute, and engaged Congress in a lengthy debate about
the extent to which the Secretary should be authorized to create a
risk-free work environment. Congress had at least three choices. It
could have required the Secretary to engage in a cost-benefit
analysis prior to the setting of exposure levels, it could have
prohibited cost-benefit analysis, or it could have permitted the
use of such an analysis. Rather than make that choice and resolve
that difficult policy issue, however, Congress passed. Congress
simply said that the Secretary should set standards "to the extent
feasible." Last year, JUSTICE POWELL reflected that
Page 452 U. S. 546
"one might wish that Congress had spoken with greater clarity."
American Petroleum Institute, 448 U.S. at
448 U. S. 668
(POWELL, J., concurring in part and in judgment). I am convinced
that the reason that Congress did not speak with greater "clarity"
was because it could not. The words "to the extent feasible" were
used to mask a fundamental policy disagreement in Congress. I have
no doubt that, if Congress had been required to choose whether to
mandate, permit, or prohibit the Secretary from engaging in a
cost-benefit analysis, there would have been no bill for the
President to sign.
The Court seems to argue that Congress
did make a
policy choice when it enacted the "feasibility" language. Its view
is that Congress required the Secretary to engage in something
called "feasibility analysis."
Ante at
452 U. S. 509.
But those words mean nothing at all. They are a "legislative
mirage, appearing to some Members [of Congress] but not to others,
and assuming any form desired by the beholder."
American
Petroleum Institute, supra, at
448 U. S. 681.
Even the Court does not settle on a meaning. It first suggests that
the language requires the Secretary to do what is "capable of being
done."
Ante at
452 U. S.
508-509. But if that is all the language means, it is
merely precatory, and "no more than an admonition to the Secretary
to do his duty. . . ." Leg.Hist. 367 (remarks of Sen. Dominick).
The Court then seems to adopt the Secretary's view that feasibility
means "technological and economic feasibility." But there is
nothing in the words of § 6(b)(5), or their legislative history, to
suggest why they should be so limited. One wonders why the
"requirement" of § 6(b)(5) could not include considerations of
administrative or even political feasibility. As even the Court
recognizes, when Congress has wanted to limit the concept of
feasibility to technological and economic feasibility it has said
so.
Ante at
452 U. S. 510.
Thus, the words "to the extent feasible" provide no meaningful
guidance to those who will administer the law.
Page 452 U. S. 547
In believing that § 6(b)(5) amounts to an unconstitutional
delegation of legislative authority to the Executive Branch, I do
not mean to suggest that Congress, in enacting a statute, must
resolve all ambiguities or must "fill in all of the blanks." Even
the neophyte student of government realizes that legislation is the
art of compromise, and that an important, controversial bill is
seldom enacted by Congress in the form in which it is first
introduced. It is not unusual for the various factions supporting
or opposing a proposal to accept some departure from the language
they would prefer and to adopt substitute language agreeable to
all. But that sort of compromise is a far cry from this case, where
Congress simply abdicated its responsibility for the making of a
fundamental and most difficult policy choice -- whether and to what
extent "the statistical possibility of future deaths should . . .
be disregarded in light of the economic costs of preventing those
deaths."
American Petroleum Institute, supra, at
448 U. S. 672.
That is a "quintessential legislative" choice, and must be made by
the elected representatives of the people, not by nonelected
officials in the Executive Branch. As stated last Term:
"In drafting § 6(b)(5), Congress was faced with a clear, if
difficult, choice between balancing statistical lives and
industrial resources or authorizing the Secretary to elevate human
life above all concerns save massive dislocation in an affected
industry. That Congress recognized the difficulty of this choice is
clear. . . . That Congress chose, intentionally or unintentionally,
to pass this difficult choice on to the Secretary is evident from
the spectral quality of the standard it selected."
448 U.S. at
448 U. S.
685.
In sum, the Court is quite correct in asserting that the phrase
"to the extent feasible" is the critical language for the purposes
of these cases. But that language is critical, not because it
establishes a general standard by which those charged
Page 452 U. S. 548
with administering the statute may be guided, but because it has
precisely the opposite effect: in failing to agree on whether the
Secretary should be either mandated, permitted, or prohibited from
undertaking a cost-benefit analysis, Congress simply left the
crucial policy choices in the hands of the Secretary of Labor.* As
I stated at greater length last Term, I believe that, in so doing,
Congress unconstitutionally delegated its legislative
responsibility to the Executive Branch.
|452 U.S. ast2|
* Contrary to the suggestion of the Court,
ante at
452 U. S. 541,
n. 75, I do not argue that the existence of several plausible
interpretations of the statute is a ground for invoking the
delegation doctrine: I invoke the delegation doctrine because
Congress failed to choose among those plausible
interpretations.