The provision of Treas.Reg. § 1.562-1(a) that a personal holding
company's distribution of appreciated property to its shareholders
results, under §§ 561 and 562 of the Internal Revenue Code of 1954,
in a dividends-paid deduction limited to an amount that is the
adjusted tax basis of the property in the hands of the company at
the time of the distribution held valid as having a reasonable
basis, as against the contention that such deduction should be
equal in amount to the fair market value of the property
distributed. Given the fact that § 27(d) of the Internal Revenue
Code of 1939 expressly provided the "adjusted basis" measure for
valuation of dividends paid in appreciated property, rather than
money, and the ambiguity surrounding the legislative history of §
562 of the 1954 Code, which sets forth the rules applicable in
determining dividends eligible for the dividends-paid deduction but
contains no counterpart to § 27(d) of the 1939 Code, no "weighty
reason" justifying setting aside the regulation in question can be
identified. Pp.
434 U. S.
530-539.
545 F.2d 268, affirmed.
BRENNAN, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
BURGER, C.J., and STEWART, WHITE, MARSHALL, and REHNQUIST, JJ.,
joined. STEVENS, J., filed an opinion concurring in the judgment
and concurring in part,
post, p.
434 U. S. 539.
POWELL, J., filed a dissenting opinion,
post, p.
434 U. S. 539.
BLACKMUN, J., took no part in the consideration or decision of the
case.
Page 434 U. S. 529
MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN delivered the opinion of the Court.
The question presented in this case is the validity of the
provision of Treas.Reg. § 1.562-1(a), 26 CFR § 1.562-1(a) (1977),
that a personal holding company's distribution of appreciated
property to its shareholders results, under § 561 and 562 of the
Internal Revenue Code of 1954, 26 U.S.C. §§ 561 and 562, in a
dividends-paid deduction limited to an amount that is "the adjusted
basis of the property in the hands of the distributing corporation
at the time of the distribution." [
Footnote 1] The Court of Appeals for the First Circuit
sustained the validity of the provision in this case, 545 F.2d 268
(1976), disagreeing with the Court of Appeals for the Sixth Circuit
in
H. Wetter Mfg. Co. v. United States, 458 F.2d 1033
(1972), which had concluded that the limitation on the
dividends-paid deduction is invalid, and that a personal holding
company is entitled to a deduction equal in amount to the fair
market
Page 434 U. S. 530
value of property distributed. [
Footnote 2] We granted certiorari to resolve the conflict.
431 U.S. 928 (1977). We agree with the Court of Appeals for the
First Circuit that the limitation on the dividends-paid deduction
provided by the regulations is valid, and therefore affirm its
judgment.
I
The maximum income tax rate applied to corporations has for many
years been substantially below marginal tax rates applicable to
high-income individuals. As early as 1913, Congress recognized that
this disparity provided an incentive for individuals to create
corporations solely to avoid taxes. In response, Congress imposed a
tax on the shareholders of any corporation "formed or fraudulently
availed of" for the purpose of avoiding personal income taxes.
Tariff Act of 1913, § II-A, Subdivision 2, 38 Stat. 166;
see
Ivan Allen Co. v. United States, 422 U.
S. 617,
422 U. S.
624-625, and n. 8 (1975). Section 220 of the Revenue Act
of 1921, 42 Stat. 247, shifted the incidence of this tax to the
corporation itself, where it has remained to this day.
See Ivan
Allen Co. v. United States, supra at
422 U. S. 625
n. 8.
Early statutes designed to combat abuse of the corporate form
were not notably successful, however, and, in 1934, Congress
concluded that the "incorporated pocketbook" -- a closely held
corporation formed to receive passive investment property and to
accumulate income accruing with respect to that property -- had
become a major vehicle of tax avoidance. [
Footnote 3]
Page 434 U. S. 531
Congress' response was the personal holding company tax, enacted
in 1934, and now codified as §§ 541-547 and 561-565 of the Internal
Revenue Code of 1954, [
Footnote
4] 26 U.S.C. §§ 541-547 and 561-565 (1970 ed. and Supp. V).
The object of the personal holding company tax is to force
corporations which are "personal holding companies" [
Footnote 5] to pay in each tax year dividends
at least equal to the corporation's undistributed personal holding
company income --
i.e. its adjusted taxable income less
dividends paid to shareholders of the corporation,
see §
545 -- thus ensuring that taxpayers cannot escape personal taxes by
accumulating income at the corporate level. This object is
effectuated by imposing on a personal holding company
both
the ordinary income tax applicable to its operation as a
corporation
and a penalty tax of 70% on its undistributed
personal holding company income.
See §§ 541, 545, 561.
Since the penalty tax rate equals or exceeds the highest rate
applicable to individual taxpayers,
see 26 U.S.C. § 1
(1970 ed. and Supp. V), it will generally be in the interest of
those controlling the personal holding company to distribute all
personal holding company income, thereby avoiding the 70% tax at
the corporate level by reducing to zero the tax base against which
it is applied. [
Footnote 6]
II
Petitioners are the successors to Pierce Investment Corp. In
1966, the Commissioner audited Pierce and determined that it was a
personal holding company for the tax years 1959, 1960,
Page 434 U. S. 532
1962, and 1963. Deficiencies in personal holding company taxes
of $26,571.30 were assessed against Pierce. In response to the
audit, Pierce entered an agreement with the Commissioner pursuant
to § 547 of the Code which provides that a corporation in Pierce's
position may enter such an agreement, acknowledging its deficiency
and personal holding company status, and may within 90 days
thereafter make "deficiency dividend" payments that become a
deduction against personal holding company income in the years for
which a deficiency was determined and reduce that deficiency.
Shares of stock Pierce held in other companies were promptly
distributed as deficiency dividends. The fair market value of this
stock at the time of distribution is agreed to have been $32,535;
its adjusted tax basis, $18,725.11.
Pierce then filed a claim for a deficiency-dividend deduction,
as required by § 547(e), indicating that the value of dividends
distributed for the tax years in question was $32,535. The
Commissioner, relying on Treas.Reg. § 1.562-1(a), allowed this
claim only to the extent of Pierce's adjusted basis in the stock,
and he determined a new deficiency after reducing Pierce's personal
holding company income by the amount of the deficiency dividends
allowed. Pierce paid this tax and the Commissioner denied its claim
for a refund.
Petitioners as Pierce's successors thereafter brought a refund
suit in the United States District Court for the District of
Massachusetts, arguing that the deficiency dividends should have
been valued at their fair market value. The District Court on
cross-motions for summary judgment denied relief,
407 F.
Supp. 1039 (1976), and the Court of Appeals for the First
Circuit affirmed. Each court found the Treasury Regulation to be a
reasonable interpretation of the personal holding company tax
statute, and each expressly refused to follow the contrary holding
of
H. Wetter Mfg. Co. v. United States, supra. [
Footnote 7] Accordingly, a refund was
denied.
Page 434 U. S. 533
III
"[I]t is fundamental . . . that as 'contemporaneous
constructions by those charged with administration of' the Code,
[Treasury] Regulations 'must be sustained unless unreasonable and
plainly inconsistent with the revenue statutes,' and 'should not be
overruled except for weighty reasons.'"
Bingler v. Johnson, 394 U. S. 741,
394 U. S.
749-750 (1969), quoting
Commissioner v. South Texas
Lumber Co., 333 U. S. 496,
333 U. S. 501
(1948);
accord, United States v. Correll, 389 U.
S. 299,
389 U. S.
306-307 (1967). This rule of deference is particularly
appropriate here, [
Footnote 8]
since, while obviously some rule of valuation must be applied,
Congress, as we shall see, failed expressly to provide one.
See
United States v. Correll, supra; 26 U.S.C. § 7805(a).
Section 547(a) of the Code requires that a taxpayer who like
Pierce pays dividends after a determination of liability by the
Commissioner "shall be allowed"
"a deduction . . . for the amount of deficiency dividends (as
defined in subsection (d)) for the purpose of determining the
personal holding company tax."
Subsection 547(d) in turn provides that
"the term 'deficiency dividends' means the amount of the
dividends paid by the corporation . . . , which would have been
includible in the computation of the deduction for dividends paid
under section 561 for the taxable year with respect to which the
liability for personal holding
Page 434 U. S. 534
company tax exists, if distributed during such taxable
year."
Continuing this chain of definitions, § 561(a) provides that the
deduction for dividends "shall be the sum of,"
inter alia,
dividends paid during the taxable year; and § 561(b)(1) points to §
562 as the source of a rule for valuing such dividends. Section
562, however, provides only exceptions to a basic rule said to be
provided by § 316 of the Code, 26 U.S.C. § 316. But when we turn to
§ 316, the trail of definitions finally turns cold, for that
section states only that a dividend is a "distribution of property
made by a corporation to its shareholders" out of current or
accumulated earnings or, in the case of personal holding companies,
out of its current personal holding company income. Inexplicably,
moreover, the draftsmen refer us back to § 562 for "[r]ules
applicable in determining dividends eligible for dividends paid
credit deduction."
See Cross References following §
316.
Petitioners suggest that the way out of this circularity is to
adopt the valuation rules for distributions of property found in §
301 of the Code, 26 U.S.C. § 301. We cannot agree, for § 301 deals
not with the problem of valuing the distribution with respect to
the distributing corporation, but establishes rules governing the
valuation with respect to distributees. This is not to deny the
logical force of petitioners' argument that, since the purpose of
the personal holding company tax is to force individuals to include
personal holding company income in their individual returns, the
corporate distributor should get a deduction at the corporate level
equal to the income generated by the distribution at the
shareholder level as defined by § 301, that is, the fair market
value of the appreciated property in this case. [
Footnote 9]
See 26 U.S.C. §
301(b)
Page 434 U. S. 535
(1)(A). Indeed,
H. Wetter Mfg Co. v. United States, 458
F.2d 1033 (1972), and
Gulf Inland Corp. v. United States,
75-2 USTC � 9620 (WD La.),
appeal docketed, No.
75-3767
Page 434 U. S. 536
(CA5 1975), have taken the view urged by petitioners, and but
for the Regulation, the argument might well prevail. [
Footnote 10] But, as we have
indicated, the issue before us is not how we might resolve the
statutory ambiguity in the first instance, but whether there is any
reasonable basis for the resolution embodied in the Commissioner's
Regulation. We conclude that there is.
In the Revenue Act of 1936, Congress enacted a surtax on
undistributed profits intended to supplement the 1934 enactment of
the personal holding company tax. In § 27(c) of the 1936 Act, 49
Stat. 1665, later codified as § 27(d) of the Internal Revenue Code
of 1939, 53 Stat. 20, Congress expressly provided the "adjusted
basis" measure for valuation with respect to the distributing
corporation of dividends paid in appreciated property, rather than
money:
"If a dividend is paid in property other than money . . . the
dividends paid credit with respect thereto shall be the adjusted
basis of the property in the hands of the corporation at the time
of the payment, or the fair market value of the property at the
time of the payment, whichever is the lower."
Although this section may not have been enacted with the
personal holding company tax primarily in mind, [
Footnote 11] § 351(b)(2)(C) of the 1936 Act
[
Footnote 12] nonetheless
expressly provided that the dividends-paid credit for that tax
would be governed by § 27(c). At the same time, in contrast, the
1936 Act provided that property distributed as a dividend would be
valued with
Page 434 U. S. 537
respect to distributees at its fair market value.
See
Revenue Act of 1936, § 115(j), 49 Stat. 1689.
The relevant provisions of the 1936 Revenue Act were carried
over without material change into the Internal Revenue Code of
1939.
See §§ 27(d), 115(j), of that Code, 53 Stat. 20, 48.
Thus, the logical symmetry between the gain recognized at the
shareholder level and the dividend credit allowed at the corporate
level, which petitioners argue should be the touchstone for our
decision, was not part of the scheme of the Internal Revenue Code
from 1936 to 1954.
Nor can Congress' failure to reenact a counterpart to § 27(c) in
the 1954 Code be read unambiguously to indicate that Congress had
abandoned the "adjusted basis" measure in favor of the "fair market
value" measure. In describing the purpose of § 562(a), which
defines dividends eligible for deduction for personal holding
company tax purposes, the Senate Finance Committee explained:
"Subsection (a) provides that the term 'dividend' for purposes
of this part shall include, except as otherwise provided in this
section, only those dividends described in section 316. . . . The
requirements of sections 27(d), (e), (f), and (i) of existing law
[Internal Revenue Code of 1939, as amended] are contained in the
definition of 'dividend' in section 312, and accordingly are not
restated in section 562."
S.Rep. No. 1622, 83d Cong., 2d Sess., 325 (1954). The Report of
the House Ways and Means Committee is
in haec verba,
except that it says that the requirements of §§ 27(d), (e), (f),
and (i) are contained in what is now § 316 of the 1954 Code.
[
Footnote 13]
See
H.R.Rep. No. 1337, 83d Cong., 2d Sess.,
Page 434 U. S. 538
A181 (1954). The discrepancy between the House and Senate
Reports is not material, however, since, as we have explained,
there is no way to reach the result of § 27(c) by following any
path through the language of the 1954 Code. [
Footnote 14] In light of the failure of the
language of the Code to create the result of § 27(c), the statement
in the House and Senate Reports could be read to indicate that
Congress meant to incorporate only so much of § 27 as was actually
enacted -- that is, none of it. But this meaning is not compelled,
and we cannot say that the language of the Reports cannot be real
to evince Congress' intention, albeit erroneously abandoned in
execution, to retain the "adjusted basis" valuation rule of §
27(c).
At the least, it is not unreasonable for the Commissioner to
have assumed that Congress intended to carry forward the law
existing prior to the 1954 Code with respect to the measure of
valuation. As we said in
United States v. Ryder,
110 U. S. 729,
110 U. S. 740
(1884):
"It will not be inferred that the legislature, in revising and
consolidating the laws, intended to change their policy, unless
such intention be clearly expressed."
Accord, Aberdeen & Rockfish R. Co. v. SCRAP,
422 U. S. 289,
422 U. S. 309
n. 12 (1975);
Muniz v. Hoffman, 422 U.
S. 454,
422 U. S.
467-472 (1975);
Fourco Glass Co. v. Transmirra
Corp., 353 U. S. 222,
Page 434 U. S. 539
353 U. S. 227
(1957). If we will not read legislation to abandon previously
prevailing law when, as here, a recodification of law is incomplete
or departs substantially and without explanation from prior law, we
cannot conclude that the Commissioner may not adopt a similar
rationale in drafting his rule. [
Footnote 15] In any case, given the law under the 1939
Code and the ambiguity surrounding the House and Senate Reports on
§ 662, it is impossible to identify in this case any "weighty
reasons" that would justify setting aside the Treasury
Regulation.
Affirmed.
MR. JUSTICE BLACKMUN took no part in the consideration or
decision of this case.
[
Footnote 1]
"§ 561. Definition of deduction for dividends paid."
"(a) General rule."
"The deduction for dividends paid shall be the sum of -- "
"(1) the dividends paid during the taxable year,"
"
* * * *"
"(b) Special rules applicable."
"(1) In determining the deduction for dividends paid, the rules
provided in section 562 . . . shall be applicable."
"§ 562. Rules applicable in determining dividends eligible for
dividends paid deduction."
"(a) General rule."
"For purposes of this part, the term 'dividend' shall, except as
otherwise provided in this section, include only dividends
described in section 316. . . ."
"§ 1.562-1 Dividends for which the dividends paid deduction is
allowable."
"(a)
General rule. . . . If a dividend is paid in
property (other than money) the amount of the dividends paid
deduction with respect to such property shall be the adjusted basis
of the property in the hands of the distributing corporation at the
time of the distribution. . . ."
[
Footnote 2]
Accord, Gulf Inland Corp. v. United States, 75-2 USTC �
9620 (WD La.),
appeal docketed, No. 75-3767 (CA5 1975).
But see C. Blake McDowell, Inc. v. Commissioner, 67 T.C.
1043 (1977).
[
Footnote 3]
See H.R.Rep. No. 704, 73d Cong., 2d Sess., pt. 1, pp.
11-12 (1934); Subcommittee of House Committee on Ways and Means,
73d Cong., 2d Sess., Preliminary Report on Prevention of Tax
Avoidance 6-8 (Comm.Print 1934). For a history of the personal
holding company tax,
see Libin, Personal Holding Companies
and the Revenue Act of 1964, 63 Mich.L.Rev. 421, 421-429
(1965).
[
Footnote 4]
Sections 561-565 also define the dividends-paid deduction used
in the accumulated earnings tax, 26 U.S.C. §§ 531-537 (1970 ed. and
Supp. V).
[
Footnote 5]
A personal holding company is defined as a corporation at least
60% of whose adjusted ordinary gross income is personal holding
company income, and 50% of whose stock is owned by five or fewer
persons. 26 U.S.C. § 542(a). Personal holding company income is
income from passive investment property such as dividends, rents,
or royalties. § 543.
[
Footnote 6]
Such dividends would, of course, be taxable to noncorporate
shareholders at their fair market value.
See 26 U.S.C. §
301(b)(1)(A).
[
Footnote 7]
In Wetter, the Sixth Circuit, adopting a "plain meaning" rule,
held that the 1954 Code required the rule of 26 U.S.C. § 301 to be
used in establishing the value of the dividend deduction under the
personal holding company tax. The meaning of the 1954 Code is,
however, anything but plain.
[
Footnote 8]
Although we have said that penalty tax provisions are to be
strictly construed,
see Ivan Allen Co. v. United States,
422 U. S. 617,
422 U. S. 627
(1975);
Commissioner v. Acker, 361 U. S.
87,
361 U. S. 91
(1959), this rule of construction does not apply to the personal
holding company tax, since any penalty can be easily avoided by
following -- as petitioners' predecessor did -- the guidelines set
out in 26 U.S.C. § 547.
[
Footnote 9]
Petitioners also argue that the valuation standard provided by §
301 was expressly adopted by the House as the standard to be used
in establishing the value of a dividend with respect to a
corporation as well as to a distributee-shareholder. In H.R. 8300,
83d Cong., 2d Sess. (1954), the forerunner of the Internal Revenue
Code of 1954, § 562(a) referred to § 312 which stated: "The term
dividend' when used in this subtitle means a distribution
(as determined in section 301(a)). . . ." (Emphasis added.)
Section 301(a) defined a "distribution" as "the amount of money . .
. and the fair market value of securities and property received" by
a distributee. This, petitioners conclude, shows that Congress
meant to use the standard of § 301, now codified as 26 U.S.C. §
301, as the standard for valuing distributions of property with
respect to both the distributing corporation and the
distributee-shareholder.
The language in § 312 italicized above was deleted by the
Senate, however, and does not appear in § 316 of the 1954 Code --
which corresponds to § 312 of H.R. 8300,
supra. Moreover,
as explained
infra, at
434 U. S.
536-538, the House Report states that the rule of §
27(c) of the Revenue Act of 1936, 49 Stat. 1665, was incorporated
in the 1954 Code. If that is indeed the case, then § 301 cannot be
the section that governed valuation of property dividends under §
562(a) of H.R. 8300, since § 301 does not embody the valuation rule
of § 27(c) with respect to distributions to noncorporate
shareholders. Instead, H.R. 8300, § 301(a), mandates the use of
fair market value without regard to basis when the distributee is a
noncorporate shareholder, whereas § 27(c) mandated the use of the
lower of basis or fair market value. The rule of § 27(c)
is used in H.R. 8300 only with respect to corporate distributees,
taxpayers who were
not the target of the personal holding
company tax. There is, therefore, no unambiguous inference to be
drawn from the linkage between §§ 301, 312, and 562 of the House
bill.
See also nn.
13-14 infra.
Finally, petitioners argue that our decision in
Ivan Allen
Co. v. United States, supra, supports their contention that
fair market value must be the measure of property dividends. But
this is not the case. As we made abundantly clear in
Ivan
Allen, the fair market value of liquid assets figures only in
calculating whether "earnings and profits . . . [have been]
permitted to accumulate beyond the reasonable needs of the
business." 26 U.S.C. § 533(a). Unrealized appreciation does not
figure in the tax base to which the accumulated earnings tax
applies.
See 422 U.S. at
422 U. S. 627,
422 U. S. 633.
Since
Ivan Allen thus holds that appreciation does
not figure in the accumulated earnings tax base, there is
no justification for reasoning from that opinion that such
appreciation must nonetheless figure in the dividends to be
subtracted from that base.
[
Footnote 10]
See generally Drake, Distributions in Kind and the
Dividends Paid Deduction -- Conflict in the Circuits, 1977
B.Y.U.L.Rev. 45.
[
Footnote 11]
Section 27 was added as part of a general revision of the
undistributed profits and accumulated earnings taxes.
See
S.Rep. No. 2156, 74th Cong., 2d Sess., 12-13, 16-18 (1936). There
is no discussion in the legislative history of the 1936 Act of the
reason for applying § 27 to personal holding companies.
[
Footnote 12]
49 Stat. 1732.
[
Footnote 13]
The Court of Appeals theorized that this discrepancy may have
been due to a typographical error in the Senate Report. As the bill
which was to become the 1954 Code was passed by the House, the
provisions of § 316 of the Code were set out as § 312. The Senate
renumbered the bill, but adopted the discussion of the House Report
essentially verbatim, possibly failing to correct all instances
where section numbers had changed.
See 545 F.2d at 270 n.
2.
[
Footnote 14]
If one assumes that S.Rep. No. 1622, 83d Cong., 2d Sess. (1954),
is correct in stating that Congress reenacted § 27(c) of the
Revenue Act of 1936 as § 312 of the 1954 Code, 26 U.S.C. § 312,
but see n 13,
supra, then Treas.Reg. 1.562-1(a), 26 CFR § 1.562-1(a)
(1977), must be upheld because § 312(a)(3) provides a dividend
valuation rule identical to that of § 27(c). But § 312 is, on its
face, addressed only to the narrow issue of the effect of dividends
on corporate earnings and profits, an issue unrelated to the
personal holding company tax. Therefore, § 312 is no more likely to
be the correct locus of the reenactment of § 27(c) than § 301 of
the Code. Moreover, even if the Senate did intend § 312 to be the
locus of the rule of § 27(c), ambiguity remains because the House,
if it put § 27(c) anywhere, put it in §§ 301 and 316 of the Code.
See n 9,
supra.
[
Footnote 15]
Treas.Reg. 1.562-1(a), 26 CFR § 1.562-1(a) (1977), does not, of
course, correspond to § 27(c) of the Revenue Act of 1936 in valuing
depreciated property. The Treasury Regulation requires adjusted
basis to be used in valuing all distributions of property; § 27(c)
provided that the lower of adjusted basis or fair market value
would be used.
See supra at
434 U. S. 536.
However, we have no occasion to pass on the validity of §
1.562-1(a) as applied to depreciated property since, even if it
should be invalid in that circumstance, this would not help
petitioners in this case.
MR. JUSTICE STEVENS, concurring in the judgment and concurring
in part.
The only portion of the Court's opinion which I am unable to
join is that quoted by MR JUSTICE POWELL in dissent. I do not see
the ineluctable logical need to equate the amount of income
received by the shareholder distributee with the amount of the
deduction allowed the corporate distributor. In my judgment, market
value is the appropriate measure of the recipient's income, and
adjusted basis is the appropriate debit on the corporation's
books.
MR. JUSTICE POWELL, dissenting.
The Court's opinion, with commendable candor, recognizes that
logic supports petitioners' position:
"[We do] not . . . deny the logical force of petitioners'
Page 434 U. S. 540
argument that, since the purpose of the personal holding company
tax is to force individuals to include personal holding company
income in their individua returns, the corporate distributor should
get a deduction at the corporate level equal to the income
generated by the distribution at the shareholder level as defined
by § 301, that is, the fair market value of the appreciated
property in this case.
See 26 U.S.C. § 301(b)(1)(A)."
Ante at
434 U. S.
534-535.
The Court also recognizes the "circularity," ante
at
434 U. S. 534,
and the "ambiguity," ante at
434 U. S. 536,
of the relevant provisions of the Internal Revenue Code, as well as
the absence of any clarification thereof in the legislative
history. The Court simply resolves the statutory jumble in favor of
the Treasury Regulation.
It is virtually conceded that this result cannot be squared with
the acknowledged purpose of the personal holding company tax. Where
statutory ambiguity exists without clarification in the legislative
history, a court should read the statute to accord with its
manifest purpose. A regulation that defies logic, as well as the
statutory purpose, merits little weight.
I find no answer in the Court's opinion to the arguments
advanced by Professor Drake.
See Drake, Distributions in
Kind and Dividends Paid Deduction -- Conflict in the Circuits, 1977
B.Y.U.L.Rev. 45.
See also H. Wetter Mfg. Co. v. United
States, 458 F.2d 1033 (CA6 1972).
*
I respectfully dissent.
* I do not view this as a case that, under the Court's holding
today, the Government "wins" and personal holding company taxpayers
(other than petitioners) "lose." It is not at all clear to me that
the Court's resolution of the statutory ambiguity will in the end
increase the Government's "take." The personal holding company
device is used by a limited number of sophisticated taxpayers.
Under the "adjusted basis" rule upheld by this decision, many of
them will be able to schedule the distribution of appreciated and
depreciated property in an advantageous manner.
Cf. General
Securities Co. v. Commissioner, 42 B.T.A. 754 (1940),
aff'd, 123 F.2d 192 (CA10 1941). I simply would have
preferred a resolution that advanced the symmetry of the relevant
Code provisions,
see, e.g., 26 U.S.C. §§ 301, 311, and one
compatible with the plain purpose of the personal holding company
tax.