In exchange for respondent real estate development corporation's
promise to purchase prefabricated houses to be erected on certain
land, petitioner United States Steel Corp.'s Home Division (the
manufacturer of the houses) and petitioner Credit Corp., a wholly
owned subsidiary that provides financing to the Home Division's
customers, agreed to finance respondent's cost of acquiring and
developing the land. After difficulties arose while the development
was in progress, respondent brought a treble damages action against
petitioners, alleging that the transaction was a tying arrangement
forbidden by the Sherman Act, because the competition for
prefabricated houses (the tied product) was restrained by
petitioners abuse of power over credit (the tying product). After
this Court, in a prior review of the case upon reversing a summary
judgment in petitioners' favor, held that the agreement affected a
"not insubstantial" amount of commerce in the tied product, and
that respondent was entitled to an opportunity to prove that
petitioners possessed "appreciable economic power" in the market
for the tying product, the District Court ultimately held that the
evidence justified the conclusion that petitioners did have
sufficient economic power in the credit market to make the tying
arrangement unlawful, and the Court of Appeals affirmed. That
evidence related to four propositions: (1) petitioner Credit Corp.
and the Home Division were owned by one of the Nation's largest
corporations; (2) petitioners entered into tying arrangements with
a significant number of customers in addition to respondent; (3)
the Home Division charged respondent a noncompetitive price for its
prefabricated houses; and (4) the financing provided to respondent
was "unique," primarily because it covered 100% of respondent's
acquisition and development costs.
Held: The record does not support the conclusion that
petitioners had appreciable economic power in the market for
credit, the tying product. Where the record merely shows that the
credit terms are unique because the seller was willing to accept a
lesser profit -- or to incur greater risks -- than its competitors,
such uniqueness does not give rise to any inference of economic
power in the credit market. The
Page 429 U. S. 611
unusual credit bargain offered to respondent proves nothing more
than a willingness to provide cheap financing in order to sell
expensive houses, and without any evidence that the Credit Corp.
had some cost advantage over its competitors -- or could offer a
form of financing that was significantly differentiated from that
which other lenders could offer if they so elected -- the unique
character of its financing does not support the lower courts'
conclusion that petitioners had the kind of economic power that
respondent had the burden of proving in order to prevail. Pp.
429 U. S.
614-622.
523 F.2d 961, reversed.
STEVENS, J., delivered the opinion for a unanimous Court.
BURGER, C.J., filed a concurring opinion, in which REHNQUIST, J.,
joined,
post, p.
429 U. S.
622.
Mr. JUSTICE STEVENS delivered the opinion of the Court.
In exchange for respondent's promise to purchase prefabricated
houses to be erected on land near Louisville, Ky., petitioners
agreed to finance the cost of acquiring and developing the land.
Difficulties arose while the development was in progress, and
respondent (Fortner) commenced this treble damages action, claiming
that the transaction was a tying arrangement forbidden by the
Sherman Act. Fortner alleged that competition for prefabricated
houses (the tied product) was restrained by petitioners' abuse of
power over credit (the tying product). A summary judgment in favor
of petitioners was reversed by this Court.
Fortner Enterprises
v. United States Steel Corp., 394 U.
S. 495 (
Fortner I). We held that the agreement
affected a "not insubstantial" amount of commerce in the tied
product and that Fortner was entitled to an opportunity to prove
that petitioners possessed "appreciable
Page 429 U. S. 612
economic power" in the market for the tying product. The
question now presented is whether the record supports the
conclusion that petitioners had such power in the credit market.
[
Footnote 1]
The conclusion that a violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act
[
Footnote 2]
Page 429 U. S. 613
had been proved was only reached after two trials. At the first
trial following our remand, the District Court directed a verdict
in favor of Fortner on the issue of liability, and submitted only
the issue of damages to the jury. The jury assessed damages, before
trebling, of $93,200. The Court of Appeals reversed the directed
verdict and remanded for a new trial on liability. 452 F.2d 1095
(CA6 1971),
cert. denied, 406 U.S. 919. The parties then
waived the jury; the trial judge heard additional evidence, and
entered extensive findings of fact which were affirmed on appeal.
523 F.2d 961 (1975). Both courts held that the findings justified
the conclusion that petitioners had sufficient economic power in
the credit market to make the tying arrangement unlawful.
Before explaining why we disagree with the ultimate conclusion
of the courts below, we first describe the tying arrangement, and
then summarize the findings on the economic power issue.
I
Only the essential features of the arrangement between the
parties need be described. Fortner is a corporation which was
activated by an experienced real estate developer for the purpose
of buying and improving residential lots. One petitioner, United
States Steel Corp., operates a "Home Division" which manufactures
and assembles components of prefabricated houses; the second
petitioner, the "Credit Corp.," is a wholly owned subsidiary, which
provides financing to customers of the Home Division in order to
promote sales. Although their common ownership and control make it
appropriate to regard the two as a single seller, they sell two
separate products -- prefabricated houses and credit. The credit
extended to Fortner was not merely for the price of the homes.
Petitioners agreed to lend Fortner over $2,000,000 in exchange for
Fortner's promise to purchase the components of 210 homes for about
$689,000. The additional borrowed funds were intended to cover
Fortner's cost of acquiring and
Page 429 U. S. 614
developing the vacant real estate, and the cost of erecting the
houses.
The impact of the agreement on the market for the tied product
(prefabricated houses) is not in dispute. On the one hand, there is
no claim -- nor could there be that the Home Division had any
dominance in the prefabricated housing business. The record
indicates that it was only moderately successful, and that its
sales represented a small fraction of the industry total. [
Footnote 3] On the other hand, we have
already held that the dollar value of the sales to respondent was
sufficient to meet the "not insubstantial" test described in
earlier cases.
See 394 U.S. at
394 U. S.
501-502. We therefore confine our attention to the
source of the tying arrangement -- petitioners' "economic power" in
the credit market.
II
The evidence supporting the conclusion that the Credit Corp. had
appreciable economic power in the credit market relates to four
propositions: (1) petitioner Credit Corp. and the Home Division
were owned by one of the Nation's largest corporations; (2)
petitioners entered into tying arrangements with a significant
number of customers in addition to Fortner; (3) the Home Division
charged respondent a noncompetitive price for its prefabricated
homes; and (4) the financing provided to Fortner was "unique,"
primarily because it covered 100% of Fortner's acquisition and
development costs.
The Credit Corp. was established in 1954 to provide financing
for customers of the Home Division. The United States Steel Corp.
not only provided the equity capital, but also allowed the Credit
Corp. to use its credit in order
Page 429 U. S. 615
to borrow money from banks at the prime rate. Thus, although the
Credit Corp. itself was not a particularly large company, it was
supported by a corporate parent with great financial strength.
The Credit Corp.'s loan policies were primarily intended to help
the Home Division sell its products. [
Footnote 4] It extended credit only to customers of the
Home Division, and over two-thirds of the Home Division customers
obtained such financing. With few exceptions, all the loan
agreements contained a tying clause comparable to the one
challenged in this case. Petitioner's home sales in 1960 amounted
to $6,747,353. Since over $4,600,000 of these sales were tied to
financing provided by the Credit Corp., [
Footnote 5] it is apparent that the tying arrangement
was used with a number of customers in addition to Fortner.
The least expensive house package that Fortner purchased from
the Home Division cost about $3,150. One witness testified that the
Home Division's price was $455 higher than the price of comparable
components in a conventional home; another witness, to whom the
District Court made no reference in its findings, testified that
the Home Division's price was $443 higher than a comparable
prefabricated product. Whether the price differential was as great
as 15% is not entirely clear, but the record does support the
conclusion that the contract required Fortner to pay a
noncompetitive price for the Home Division's houses.
The finding that the credit extended to Fortner was unique
Page 429 U. S. 616
was based on factors emphasized in the testimony of Fortner'
expert witness, Dr. Masten, a professor with special knowledge of
lending practices in the Kentucky area. Dr. Masten testified that
mortgage loans equal to 100% of the acquisition and development
cost of real estate were not otherwise available in the Kentucky
area; that, even though Fortner had a deficit of $16,000, its loan
was not guaranteed by a shareholder, officer, or other person
interested in its business; and that the interest rate of 6%
represented a low rate under prevailing economic conditions.
[
Footnote 6] Moreover, he
explained that the stable price levels at the time made the risk to
the lender somewhat higher than would have been the case in a
period of rising prices. Dr. Masten concluded that the terms
granted to respondent by the Credit Corp. were so unusual that it
was almost inconceivable that the funds could have been acquired
from any other source. It is a fair summary of his testimony, and
of the District Court's findings, to say that the loan was unique
because the lender accepted such a high risk and the borrower
assumed such a low cost.
The District Court also found that banks and federally insured
savings and loan associations generally were prohibited by law from
making 100% land acquisition and development loans, and
"that other conventional lenders would not have made such loans
at the time in question, since they were not prudent loans due to
the risk involved."
App. 1596.
Accordingly, the District Court concluded
"that all of the required elements of an illegal tie-in
agreement did exist since the tie-in itself was present, a not
insubstantial amount of interstate commerce in the tied product was
restrained and the Credit Corporation did possess sufficient
economic power or leverage to effect such restraint."
Id. at 1602.
Page 429 U. S. 617
III
Without the finding that the financing provided to Fortner was
"unique," it is clear that the District Court's findings would be
insufficient to support the conclusion that the Credit Corp.
possessed any significant economic power in the credit market.
Although the Credit Corp. is owned by one of the Nation's
largest manufacturing corporations, there is nothing in the record
to indicate that this enabled it to borrow funds on terms more
favorable than those available to competing lenders, or that it was
able to operate more efficiently than other lending institutions.
In short, the affiliation between the petitioners does not appear
to have given the Credit Corp. any cost advantage over its
competitors in the credit market. Instead, the affiliation was
significant only because the Credit Corp. provided a source of
funds to customers of the Home Division. That fact tells us nothing
about the extent of petitioners' economic power in the credit
market.
The same may be said about the fact that loans from the Credit
Corp. were used to obtain house sales from Fortner and others. In
some tying situations, a disproportionately large volume of sales
of the tied product resulting from only a few strategic sales of
the tying product may reflect a form of economic "leverage" that is
probative of power in the market for the tying product. If, as some
economists have suggested, the purpose of a tie-in is often to
facilitate price discrimination, such evidence would imply the
existence of power that a free market would not tolerate. [
Footnote 7] But, in this case, Fortner
was only required to purchase houses for the number of lots for
which it received financing. The tying product produced no
commitment from Fortner to purchase varying quantities of the tied
product over an extended period of time. This record, therefore,
does not describe
Page 429 U. S. 618
the kind of "leverage" found in some of the Court's prior
decisions condemning tying arrangements. [
Footnote 8]
The fact that Fortner -- and presumably other Home Division
customers as well -- paid a noncompetitive price for houses also
lends insufficient support to the judgment of the lower court.
Proof that Fortner paid a higher price for the tied product is
consistent with the possibility that the financing was unusually
inexpensive [
Footnote 9] and
that the price for the entire package was equal to, or below, a
competitive price. And this possibility is equally strong even
though a number of Home Division customers made a package purchase
of homes and financing. [
Footnote 10]
Page 429 U. S. 619
The most significant finding made by the District Court related
to the unique character of the credit extended to Fortner. This
finding is particularly important because the unique character of
the tying product has provided critical support for the finding of
illegality in prior cases. Thus, the statutory grant of a patent
monopoly in
International Salt Co. v. United States,
332 U. S. 392; the
copyright monopolies in
United States v. Paramount Pictures,
Inc., 334 U. S. 131, and
United States v. Loew's Inc., 371 U. S.
38; and the extensive land holdings in
Northern
Pacific R. Co. v. United States, 356 U. S.
1, [
Footnote 11]
represented tying products that the Court regarded as sufficiently
unique to give rise to a presumption of economic power. [
Footnote 12]
Page 429 U. S. 620
As the Court plainly stated in its prior opinion in this case,
these decisions do not require that the defendant have a monopoly
or even a dominant position throughout the market for a tying
product.
See 394 U.S. at
394 U. S.
502-503. They do, however, focus attention on the
question whether the seller has the power, within the market for
the tying product, to raise prices or to require purchasers to
accept burdensome terms that could not be exacted in a completely
competitive market. [
Footnote
13] In short, the question is whether the seller has some
advantage not shared by his competitors in the market for the tying
product.
Without any such advantage differentiating his product from that
of his competitors, the seller's product does not
Page 429 U. S. 621
have the kind of uniqueness considered relevant in prior
tying-clause cases. [
Footnote
14] The Court made this point explicitly when it remanded this
case for trial:
"We do not mean to accept petitioner's apparent argument that
market power can be inferred simply because the kind of financing
terms offered by a lending company are 'unique and unusual.' We do
mean, however, that uniquely and unusually advantageous terms can
reflect a creditor's unique economic advantages over his
competitors."
394 U.S. at
394 U. S. 505.
An accompanying footnote explained:
"Uniqueness confers economic power only when other competitors
are in some way prevented from offering the distinctive product
themselves. Such barriers may be legal, as in the case of patented
and copyrighted products,
e.g., International Salt;
Loew's, or physical, as when the product is land,
e.g.,
Northern Pacific. It is true that the barriers may also be
economic, as when competitors are simply unable to produce the
distinctive product profitably, but the uniqueness test in such
situations is somewhat confusing, since the real source of economic
power is not the product itself, but rather the seller's cost
advantage in producing it."
Id. at
394 U. S. 505
n. 2.
Quite clearly, if the evidence merely shows that credit terms
are unique because the seller is willing to accept a lesser profit
-- or to incur greater risks -- than its competitors,
Page 429 U. S. 622
that kind of uniqueness will not give rise to any inference of
economic power in the credit market. Yet this is, in substance, all
that the record in this case indicates.
The unusual credit bargain offered to Fortner proves nothing
more than a willingness to provide cheap financing in order to sell
expensive houses. [
Footnote
15] Without any evidence that the Credit Corp. had some cost
advantage over it competitors -- or could offer a form of financing
that was significantly differentiated from that which other lenders
could offer if they so elected -- the unique character of its
financing doe not support the conclusion that petitioners had the
kind of economic power which Fortner had the burden of proving in
order to prevail in this litigation.
The judgment of the Court of Appeals is reversed.
So ordered.
[
Footnote 1]
As explained at the outset of the opinion,
Fortner I
involved
"a variety of questions concerning the proper standards to be
applied by a United States district court in passing on a motion
for summary judgment in a civil antitrust action."
394 U.S. at
394 U. S. 496.
Petitioners do not ask us to reexamine
Fortner I, which
left only the economic power question open on the issue of whether
a
per se violation could be proved. On the other hand,
Fortner has not pursued the suggestion in
Fortner I that
it might be able to prove a § 1 violation under the "rule of
reason" standard. 394 U.S. at
394 U. S. 500.
Thus, with respect to § 1, only the economic power issue is before
us.
In
Fortner I, the Court noted that Fortner also alleged
a § 2 violation, namely, that petitioners "conspired together for
the purpose of . . . acquiring a monopoly in the market for
prefabricated houses." 394 U.S. at
394 U. S. 500.
The District Court held that a § 2 violation had been proved.
Although the Court of Appeals did not reach this issue, a remand is
unnecessary. It is clear that neither the District Court's findings
of fact nor the record supports the conclusion that § 2 was
violated. The District Court found only that
"the defendants did combine or conspire to
increase
sales of prefabricated house packages by United States Steel
Corporation by the making of loans to numerous builders containing
the tie-in provision"
and that
"the sole purpose of the loan programs of the Credit Corporation
was specifically and deliberately to
increase the share of the
market of United States Steel Corporation in prefabricated
house packages. . . ."
App. 1603 (emphasis added). But "increasing sales" and
"increasing market share" are normal business goals, not forbidden
by § 2 without other evidence of an intent to monopolize. The
evidence in this case does not bridge the gap between the District
Court's findings of intent to increase sales and its legal
conclusion of conspiracy to monopolize. Moreover, petitioners did
not have a large market share or dominant market position.
See n 3,
infra. No inference of intent to monopolize can be drawn
from the fact that a firm with a small market share has engaged in
nonpredatory competitive conduct in the hope of increasing sales.
Yet, as we conclude
infra at
429 U. S.
621-622, that is all the record in this case shows.
[
Footnote 2]
26 Stat. 209, as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 1.
[
Footnote 3]
In 1960, for example, the Home Division sold a total of 1,793
houses for $6,747,353. There were at least four larger
prefabricated home manufacturers, the largest of which sold 16,804
homes in that year. In the following year, the Home Division's
sales declined while the sales of each of its four principal
competitors remained steady or increased.
[
Footnote 4]
After reviewing extensive evidence taken from the files of the
Credit Corp., including a memorandum stating that "our only purpose
in making the loan . . . is shipping houses," the District Court
expressly found "that the Credit Corporation was not so much
concerned with the risks involved in loans but whether they would
help sell houses." App. 1588-1589.
[
Footnote 5]
This figure is not stated in the District Court's findings; it
is derived from the finding of total sales and the finding that 68%
of the sales in 1960 were made to dealers receiving financial
assistance from the Credit Corp.
See id. at 1589-1590.
[
Footnote 6]
The prime rate at the time was 5% or 5 1/2%.
[
Footnote 7]
See Bowman, Tying Arrangements and the Leverage
Problem, 67 Yale L.J.19 (1957).
[
Footnote 8]
See e.g., United Shoe Machinery v. United States,
258 U. S. 451;
International Business Machines v. United States,
298 U. S. 131;
International Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.
S. 392. In his article in the 1969 Supreme Court Review
16, Professor Dam suggests that this kind of leverage may also have
been present in
Northern Pacific R. Co. v. United States,
356 U. S. 1.
[
Footnote 9]
Fortner's expert witness agreed with the statement:
"The amount of the loan as a percentage of the collateral or
security is only one element in determining its advantage to a
borrower. The other relevant factors include the rate of interest
charged, whether the lender discounts the amount loaned or charges
service for [
sic] other fees and maturity in terms of
repayment."
App. 1686.
[
Footnote 10]
Relying on
Advance Business Systems & Supply Co. v. SCM
Corp., 415 F.2d 55 (CA4 1969),
cert. denied, 397 U.S.
920, Fortner contends that acceptance of the package by a
significant number of customers is itself sufficient to prove the
seller's economic power. But this approach depends on the absence
of other explanations for the willingness of buyers to purchase the
package.
See 415 F.2d at 68. In the
Northern
Pacific case, for instance, the Court explained:
"The very existence of this host of tying arrangements is itself
compelling evidence of the defendant's great power, at least where,
as here, no other explanation has been offered for the existence of
these restraints. The 'preferential routing' clauses conferred no
benefit on the purchasers or lessees. While they got the land they
wanted by yielding their freedom to deal with competing carriers,
the defendant makes no claim that it came any cheaper than if the
restrictive clauses had been omitted. In fact, any such price
reduction in return for rail shipment would have quite plainly
constituted an unlawful rebate to the shipper. So far as the
Railroad was concerned, its purpose obviously was to fence out
competitors, to stifle competition."
356 U.S. at
356 U. S. 7-8
(footnote omitted). As this passage demonstrates, this case differs
from
Northern Pacific because use of the tie-in in this
case can be explained as a form of price competition in the tied
product, whereas that explanation was unavailable to the
Northern Pacific Railway.
[
Footnote 11]
The Court in
Northern Pacific concluded that the
railroad "possessed substantial economic power by virtue of its
extensive landholdings" and then described those holdings as
follows:
"As pointed out before, the defendant was initially granted
large acreages by Congress in the several northwestern States
through which its lines now run. This land was strategically
located in checkerboard fashion amid private holdings and within
economic distance of transportation facilities. Not only the
testimony of various witnesses but common sense makes it evident
that this particular land was often prized by those who purchased
or leased it and was frequently essential to their business
activities."
Id. at
356 U. S. 7.
[
Footnote 12]
"Since one of the objectives of the patent laws is to reward
uniqueness, the principle of these cases was carried over into
antitrust law on the theory that the existence of a valid patent on
the tying product, without more, establishes a distinctiveness
sufficient to conclude that any tying arrangement involving the
patented product would have anticompetitive consequences."
United States v. Loew's Inc., 371 U. S.
38,
371 U. S.
46.
[
Footnote 13]
"Accordingly, the proper focus of concern is whether the seller
has the power to raise prices, or impose other burdensome terms
such as a tie-in, with respect to any appreciable number of buyers
within the market."
394 U.S. at
394 U. S.
504.
Professor Dam correctly analyzed the burden of proof imposed on
Fortner by this language. In his article in the 1969 Supreme Court
Review 226, he reasoned:
"One important question in interpreting the
Fortner
decision is the meaning of this language. Taken out of context, it
might be thought to mean that, just as the 'host of tying
arrangements' was 'compelling evidence' of 'great power' in
Northern Pacific, so the inclusion of tie-in clauses in
contracts with 'any appreciable numbers of buyers' establishes
market power. But the passage, read in context, does not warrant
this interpretation. For the immediately preceding sentence makes
clear that market power, in the sense of power over price, must
still exist. If the price could have been raised but the tie-in was
demanded in lieu of the higher price, then -- and presumably only
then -- would the requisite economic power exist. Thus, despite the
broad language available for quotation in later cases, the
treatment of the law on market power is on close reading not only
consonant with the precedents, but, in some ways, less far-reaching
than
Northern Pacific and
Loew's, which could be
read to make actual market power irrelevant."
(Footnotes omitted.)
[
Footnote 14]
One commentator on
Fortner I noted:
"The Court's uniqueness test is adequate to identify a number of
situations in which this type of foreclosure is likely to occur.
Whenever there are some buyers who find a seller's product uniquely
attractive, and are therefore willing to pay a premium above the
price of its nearest substitute, the seller has the opportunity to
impose a tie to some other good."
Note, The Logic of Foreclosure: Tie-In Doctrine after
Fortner v. U.S. Steel, 79 Yale L.J. 86, 994 (1969).
[
Footnote 15]
The opinion of the Court in
Fortner I notes that
smaller companies might not have the "financial strength to offer
credit comparable to that provided by larger competitor under tying
arrangement." 394 U.S. at
394 U. S. 509.
Fortner's expert witness was unaware of the financing practices of
competing sellers of prefabricated homes, App. 1691-1692, but there
is nothing to suggest that they were unable to offer comparable
financing if they chose to do so.
MR. CHIEF JUSTICE BURGER, with whom MR. JUSTICE REHNQUIST joins,
concurring
I concur in the Court's opinion and write only to emphasize what
the case before us does
not involve; I join on the basis
of my understanding of the scope of our holding. Today's decision
does not implicate ordinary credit sales of only a single product
and which therefore cannot constitute a tying arrangement subject
to
per se scrutiny under § 1 of the Sherman Act. In
contract to such transactions, we are dealing here with a peculiar
arrangement expressly found by the Court in
Fortner I to
involve two separate products sold by