Following its notice of proposed rulemaking "propos[ing]
prospectively to exempt from regulation under the Natural Gas Act
all existing and all future jurisdictional sales made by small
producers . . . ," and the filing of comments and informal
conferences, the Federal Power Commission (FPC) issued Order No.
428, which exempted all existing and future sales by "small
producers" from direct rate regulation, and provided that they
could thereunder contract for the sale of their gas at any
obtainable rates, without refund obligations with respect to
increased rates, if any, collected for sales regulated thereunder
to the pipelines. The FPC asserted that the order did not amount to
"deregulation of sales by small producers," but was intended to
regulate small producers' sales in the course of regulating the
rates of pipeline and large producer customers of the small
producers. Pipelines purchasing from small producers above ceiling
prices were to be allowed "tracking increases" in their rates, but
those rates would be subject to refund
"with respect to new small producer sales, but only as to that
part of the rate which is unreasonably high considering appropriate
comparisons with highest contract prices for sales by large
producers or the prevailing market price for intrastate sales in
the same producing area."
The FPC asserted its intention of reviewing small producer
prices to maintain reasonable rates, and specified that small
producers remain subject to § 7(b) of the Natural Gas Act. The
Court of Appeals set aside the FPC order, holding that the small
producer blanket certificate procedure contravened the FPC's
statutory responsibilities under §§ 4 and 5 of the Act to ensure
"just and reasonable rates." It viewed the order as merely calling
for rates that were not unreasonably high as compared with the
highest contract prices for large producer sales or the prevailing
market price in the intrastate market, and
Page 417 U. S. 381
the court held unacceptable the possible contention that market
prices themselves would produce just and reasonable rates.
Held:
1. The scheme for regulating small producer rates indirectly did
not exceed the FPC's statutory authority. Pp.
417 U. S.
386-393.
(a) Order No. 428 is not invalid because it does not initially
consider each company and the reasonableness of its rates, or
because it has a two-tier system for small producers and large
producers.
Cf. Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 U.
S. 747. P.
417 U. S.
390.
(b) Since pipeline rates are subject to refund to the extent
that the purchased gas component of their rates is excessive, there
is an incentive "to bargain prices down." Pp.
417 U. S.
390-391.
(c) Requiring the pipelines and the large producers to assume
risks in bargaining for reasonable prices from small producers that
might entail refunds unrecoverable from the small producers, is not
an abuse of the FPC's discretion under § 4(e) in balancing the
interests involved. Pp.
417 U. S.
391-392.
(d) It is premature to assert that the indirect regulation
contemplated by Order No. 428 is confiscatory, especially since the
FPC is to maintain a close review of the avowedly experimental
scheme. Pp.
417 U. S.
392-393.
2. But it is not clear from the wording of Order No. 428 that it
satisfies the statutory requirement that the sale price for gas
sold in interstate commerce be just and reasonable; at the least,
the order is too ambiguous to satisfy the standard of clarity that
an administrative order must exhibit, and the implication that the
reasonableness of the small producers' rates would be judged by the
assertion that the FPC "would consider all relevant factors" in
determining whether the proposed rates comported with the "public
convenience and necessity," is insufficient to sustain the order.
Pp.
417 U. S.
394-397.
3. The FPC lacks authority to rely exclusively on market prices
as the final measure of "just and reasonable" rates mandated by the
Act; moreover, the FPC order made no finding as to the actual
impact the market price increases would have on consumer gas
expenditures. Pp.
417 U. S.
397-399.
154 U.S.App.D.C. 168, 474 F.2d 416, vacated and remanded.
WHITE, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which all
Members joined except STEWART, J., who took no part in the
consideration or decision of the cases.
Page 417 U. S. 382
MR. JUSTICE WHITE delivered the opinion of the Court.
This litigation involves the validity of Order No. 428 of the
Federal Power Commission, 45 F.P.C. 454 (1971), which provides a
blanket certificate procedure for small producers of natural gas,
and relieves them of almost all filing requirements. The rates of
small producers would no longer be directly regulated, but would be
subjected to indirect regulation through the review of purchased
gas costs of the pipelines and large producers to whom these
Page 417 U. S. 383
small producers sell. The Court of Appeals, with one judge
dissenting, set aside the order, 154 U.S.App.D.C. 168, 474 F.2d 416
(1972), concluding hat the Commission's order amounted to
"deregulation" of small producers and was unauthorized by the
Natural Gas Act (the Act), 52 Stat. 821, 15 U.S.C. § 717
et
seq. Because the validity of the order is of obvious
importance, we granted the petition for a writ of certiorari filed
by the Commission in No. 72-1490 and by the estate of Mrs. James R.
Dougherty, an intervenor in the Court of Appeals, in No. 72-1491.
414 U.S. 817 (1973).
I
On July 23, 1970, the Federal Power Commission issued a notice
of proposed rulemaking
"propos[ing] prospectively to exempt from regulation under the
Natural Gas Act all existing and all future jurisdictional sales
made by small producers. . . ."
35 Fed.Reg. 12,220 (1970). Following the filing of comments and
informal conferences, the Commission, noting that one of its
important responsibilities was "to assure maintenance of an
adequate gas supply for the interstate market," issued Order No.
428, aimed at encouraging
"small producers [
Footnote
1] to increase their exploratory efforts which are so important
to the discovery of new sources of gas . . . to facilitate the
entry of the small producer into the interstate market and to
stimulate competition among producers to sell gas in interstate
commerce. [
Footnote 2]"
The small
Page 417 U. S. 384
producer was to be assured that
"when he enters into a new contract for the interstate sale of
gas, the provisions of his contract will not be subject to change.
We also want to relieve the small producer of the expenses and
burdens relating to regulatory matters."
45 F.P.C. at 455. Accordingly, the order provided for a
nationwide blanket certificate for small producers and relieved
them, with some exceptions, from all filing requirements under the
Act. Unlike large producers, subject to Commission-fixed ceilings
on rates charged, the small producers could sell gas at the price
the market would bear, even though in excess of maximum rates set
for producers in pertinent area rate proceedings. Furthermore, they
would have "no refund obligations with respect to increased rates,
if any, collected for sales regulated hereunder to pipelines. . .
."
Id. at 457.
The order nevertheless asserted that the "action taken here, in
our view, does not constitute deregulation of sales by small
producers,"
id. at 455, and that the Commission would
continue to regulate such sales in the course of regulating the
rates of pipelines and large producers to whom the small producers
sell their gas. Pipelines purchasing from small producers at prices
in excess of existing ceilings were to be permitted to file
"tracking increases" in their rates, but those rates would be
subject to refund
"with respect to new small producer sales, but only as to that
part of the rate which is unreasonably high considering appropriate
comparisons with highest contract prices for sales by large
producers or the prevailing market price for intrastate sales in
the same producing area."
Id. at 457. The issue would be resolved either in
pipeline rate cases, a proceeding limited to the tracking increase,
or in
Page 417 U. S. 385
certificate cases. "The Commission shall consider all relevant
factors."
Id. at 458. Review of tracking increases by
pipelines was not anticipated as to existing contracts with small
producers; the order authorized small producers to increase their
rates under these contracts, terms permitting.
Large producers buying from small producers would be permitted
tracking increases to the extent authorized by their contracts and
without refund obligation
"as long as the price differential is consistent with prevailing
price differentials in the area, and as long as the small producer
prices for new gas are not unreasonably high, considering
appropriate comparisons with highest contract prices by large
producers or the prevailing market price for intrastate sales in
the same producing area."
Id. at 456. To the extent that they reflected small
producer prices in excess of that standard, large producer tracking
increases would be subject to refund.
The Commission finally asserted that
"[w]e intend to review the prices established in new contracts
or contract amendments relating to sales by small producers to as
sure the reasonableness of the rates charged by such producers
pursuant to the action we are taking herein. In the event we
determine that this approach is inimical to the interests of
consumers, we shall take further action to protect the
consumers."
Id. at 459. The Commission apparently remained free to
institute separate proceedings under § 5(a) of the Act, 15 U.S.C. §
717d(a), to reduce the producer's rates prospectively.
The Commission also made clear that small producers remain
subject to the requirements of § 7(b) of the Act, 15 U.S.C. §
717f(b), with respect to the abandonment of jurisdictional sales,
including those sales dealt with in the order. The order also
limited the use of indefinite price escalation clauses in small
producer contracts, and
Page 417 U. S. 386
excluded from the reach of the order small producer sales made
from reserves transferred by large producers. [
Footnote 3]
The Court of Appeals set aside the Commission order, holding
that, under the statute,
all natural gas sold in
interstate commerce must carry just and reasonable rates, and that,
even if indirect regulation was permissible under the statute,
Order No. 428 was infirm because nothing in it satisfied the
Commission's "duty to insure that all rates are
just and
reasonable.'" 154 U.S.App.D.C. at 173, 474 F.2d at 421. Instead,
the order was thought merely to call for rates that were not
unreasonably high as compared with the highest contract prices for
large producer sales or the prevailing market price in the
intrastate market -- "factors which [the Commission] does not
regulate or which derive solely from market forces." Ibid.
Nor could the court accept the possible argument that market forces
themselves would produce just and reasonable rates, particularly
when it understood the Commission itself to take the position that
the just and reasonable standard was in no event mandatory. The
Court of Appeals accordingly set aside the Commission's
order.
II
The Commission does not contend in this Court that the Act
permits it to exempt small producer rates from regulation or to
regulate those rates by any criterion less demanding than the just
and reasonable standard mandated by §§ 4 and 5 of the Act, 15
U.S.C. §§ 717c and 717d. Its major propositions are, first, that
Order No. 428, when properly understood, provides for just and
Page 417 U. S. 387
reasonable rates, but through the means of indirect, rather than
direct, regulation; and, second, that the Act does not forbid this
kind of indirect regulation. Respondents, on the other hand,
contend that the duty imposed by the Act to provide just and
reasonable rates cannot be satisfied by indirect regulation, and
that Order No. 428, in any event, abandons the just and reasonable
standard with respect to small producer rates.
We face first the issue as to the validity of indirect
regulation of small producer rates: on the assumption that Order
No. 428 allows pipelines and large producers to reflect in their
rates only just and reasonable charges for gas purchased from small
producers, is the order valid? We hold that it is, for we see
nothing in the Act which requires the Commission to fix the rates
chargeable by small producers by orders directly addressed to them
or which proscribes the kind of indirect regulation undertaken
here.
The Act directs that all producer rates be just and reasonable,
but it does not specify the means by which that regulatory
prescription is to be attained. That every rate of every natural
gas company must be just and reasonable does not require that the
cost of each company be ascertained, and its rates fixed with
respect to its own costs. Although for a time following
Phillips Petroleum Co. v. Wisconsin, 347 U.
S. 672 (1954), the Commission proceeded to regulate
rates company by company, there was soon a shift to the technique
of setting area rates based on composite cost considerations. We
sustained this mode of rate regulation.
In
Wisconsin v. FPC, 373 U. S. 294,
373 U. S. 309
(1963), the Court affirmed the Commission's decision to abandon the
individual cost of service method of fixing rates and to substitute
area ratemaking. The Court said:
"To declare that a particular method of rate regulation is so
sanctified as to make it highly unlikely that
Page 417 U. S. 388
any other method could be sustained would be wholly out of
keeping with this Court's consistent and clearly articulated
approach to the question of the Commission's power to regulate
rates. It has repeatedly been stated that no single method need be
followed by the Commission in considering the justness and
reasonableness of rates. . . ."
This was wholly consistent with the Court's prior views,
see
FPC v. Natural Gas Pipeline Co., 315 U.
S. 575 (1942);
FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co.,
320 U. S. 591
(1944);
Colorado Interstate Gas Co. v. FPC, 324 U.
S. 581 (1945), and reaffirmed the principle which had
been clearly stated in the
Hope case: "Under the statutory
standard of
just and reasonable,' it is the result reached not
the method employed which is controlling." 320 U.S. at 320 U. S.
602.
The principles of these prior cases were recognized and applied
in the
Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 U.
S. 747 (1968), where we sustained a two-tier system of
rates for natural gas producers. In the course of doing so, we
recognized that encouraging the exploration for and development of
new sources of natural gas was one of the aims of the Act and one
of the functions of the Commission. The performance of this role
obviously involved the rate structure, and implied a broad
discretion for the Commission. The Court summarized the principles
controlling the judicial review of Commission orders in terms very
pertinent here:
"The Act was intended to create, through the exercise of the
national power over interstate commerce, 'an agency for regulating
the wholesale distribution to public service companies of natural
gas moving interstate;'
Illinois Gas Co. v. Public Service
Co., 314 U. S. 498,
314 U. S.
506; it was for this purpose expected to 'balanc[e] . .
. the investor and the consumer
Page 417 U. S. 389
interests.'
FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co. [320 U.S.] at
320 U. S. 603. This Court
has repeatedly held that the width of administrative authority must
be measured in part by the purposes for which it was conferred;
see, e.g., Piedmont & Northern R. Co. v. Comm'n,
286 U. S.
299;
Phelps Dodge Corp. v. Labor Board,
313 U. S.
177,
313 U. S. 193-194;
National Broadcasting Co. v. United States, 319 U. S.
190;
American Trucking Assns. v. United States,
344 U. S.
298,
344 U. S. 311. Surely the
Commission's broad responsibilities therefore demand a generous
construction of its statutory authority. [Footnote omitted.]"
"Such a construction is consistent with the view of
administrative rate making uniformly taken by this Court. The Court
has said that the"
"legislative discretion implied in the rate making power
necessarily extends to the entire legislative process, embracing
the method used in reaching the legislative determination as well
as that determination itself."
"
Los Angeles Gas Co. v. Railroad Comm'n, 289 U. S.
287,
289 U. S. 304.
And see
San Diego Land & Town Co. v. Jasper, 189 U. S.
439,
189 U. S. 446. It follows
that ratemaking agencies are not bound to the service of any single
regulatory formula; they are permitted, unless their statutory
authority otherwise plainly indicates, 'to make the pragmatic
adjustments which may be called for by particular circumstances.'
FPC v. Natural Gas Pipeline Co., [315 U.S.] at
315 U. S. 586."
390 U.S. at
390 U. S.
776-777. It followed that Commission action taken in the
pursuit of a legitimate statutory goal enjoyed the presumption of
validity,
id. at
390 U. S. 767,
and that he who would upset the rate order under the Act carries
"
the heavy burden of making a convincing showing that it is
invalid because it is unjust and unreasonable in its
consequences.'" Ibid.
Page 417 U. S. 390
Accepting these views of our role as a court sitting in review,
we cannot at this point say that the Commission has exceeded its
powers by instituting a regime of indirect regulation of small
producer rates. Surely it is not fatal to Order No. 428 that it
does not, as an initial matter, consider the costs of each company
and the reasonableness of its rates. Nor is the order vulnerable
because there will be one level of just and reasonable rates for
small producers and another for large producers. As previously
noted, the Court approved two sets of just and reasonable rates in
the
Permian Basin cases, the justification being the
necessity to stimulate exploration for and the development of new
supplies of natural gas.
Id. at
390 U. S.
796-797.
Indirect regulation through the mechanism of controlling large
producer costs will not merely recreate the situation which the
Court in the
Phillips case found to be inconsistent with
the Natural Gas Act. In the pre-
Phillips era, although
asserting the right to pass on the prudentiality of various items
of the pipelines' costs, the Commission did not purport to regulate
the rates of producers with the aim of keeping them within just and
reasonable limits, as the Commission now asserts it is doing under
Order No. 428.
It is argued that permitting the small producers initially to
charge what the market will bear and relying on later regulation of
pipeline rates to protect the consumer is contrary to
Atlantic
Refining Co. v. Public Service Comm'n, 360 U.
S. 378 (1959) (CATCO). But pipelines and large producers
must file with the Commission their new contracts with the small
producers, and their rates will be subject to suspension and refund
within the limits set out in Order No. 428. As the Court noted in
FPC v. Sunray DX Oil Co., 391 U. S.
9,
391 U. S. 26
(1968), the basic assumption which must have underlain the Court's
CATCO decision was
"that the purchasing pipeline,
Page 417 U. S. 391
whose cost of purchase is a current operating expense which the
pipeline is entitled to pass on to its customers as part of its
rates, lacks sufficient incentive to bargain prices down."
Here, on the other hand, the incentive is provided -- pipeline
rates are subject to refund to the extent that the purchased gas
cost component of their rates is excessive.
This leads to the contention of the pipelines and the large
producers that the scheme of indirect regulation envisioned by
Order No. 428 unfairly subjects them to the risk of later
determination that their gas costs are unjust and unreasonable and
to the obligation to make refunds which they cannot in turn recover
from the small producers whose rates have been found too high.
[
Footnote 4] But those whose
rates are regulated characteristically bear the burden and the risk
of justifying their rates and their costs. Rate regulation
unavoidably limits profits as well as income.
"The fixing of prices, like other applications of the police
power, may reduce the value of the property which is being
regulated. But the fact that the value is reduced does not mean
that the regulation is invalid."
FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. at
320 U. S. 601.
All that is protected against, in a constitutional sense, is
Page 417 U. S. 392
that the rates fixed by the Commission be higher than a
confiscatory level.
FPC v. Natural Gas Pipeline Co., 315
U.S. at
315 U. S. 585.
In the context of the Act's rate regulation, whether any rate is
confiscatory, or for that matter "just and reasonable," can only be
judged by "the result reached, not the method employed."
FPC v.
Hope Natural Gas Co., supra, at
320 U. S. 602.
In the
Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 U.S. at
390 U. S. 769,
we stated a truism of rate regulation:
"Regulation may, consistently with the Constitution limit
stringently the return recovered on investment, for investors'
interests provide only one of the variables in the constitutional
calculus of reasonableness."
Here, requiring pipelines and the large producers to assume the
risk in bargaining for reasonable prices from small producers is
within the Commission's discretion in working out the balance of
the interests necessarily involved. The consumer would be protected
from current excessive rates, but at the expense of the pipeline,
rather than the producer, who is engaged in necessary exploratory
activity, thus serving the public interest in getting greater gas
production but at just and reasonable rates. Under such
circumstances, it is surely not an abuse of the discretion the
Commission retains under § 4(e) of the Act,
see Permian Basin
Area Rate Cases, supra, at
390 U. S.
826-827, to refrain from imposing a refund obligation on
the small producers.
Any broadside assertion that indirect regulation will be
confiscatory is premature. The consequences of indirect regulation
can only be viewed in the entirety of the rate of return allowed on
investment, and this effect will be unknown until the Commission
has applied its scheme in individual cases over a period of time.
Moreover, the "regulation of producer prices is avowedly still
experimental,"
id. at
390 U. S. 772,
and Order No. 428 asserts the
Page 417 U. S. 393
Commission's intention to keep the experiment under close
review. The Commission claims, and is entitled to, no license to be
arbitrary or capricious in disallowing purchased gas costs of large
producers and pipelines. The Commission may not exceed its
authority under the Act; its orders are subject to judicial review;
and reviewing courts must determine whether Commission orders,
issued pursuant to indirect regulation, are supported by
substantial evidence and whether it is rational to expect them
"to maintain financial integrity, attract necessary capital, and
fairly compensate investors for the risk they have assumed, and yet
provide appropriate protection to the relevant public interests,
both existing and foreseeable."
Id. at
390 U. S.
792.
If, in the course of the necessary bargaining with small
producers, the large producers and the pipelines are given no
guidance whatsoever as to what the standards of the Commission may
be, the risk of incurring unrefundable expenses that may later be
disallowed is considerably enhanced. The scope of this possible
difficulty is measured by the standards, or lack of them, by which
the Commission will review the purchased gas costs of the large
producers and the pipelines. As Order No. 428 reveals, the
Commission is surely aware of the problem, and we would expect
additional attention to be given this question in the course of the
remand proceedings which, as explained in Part III, we think are
necessary here. [
Footnote
5]
Page 417 U. S. 394
III
We turn now to whether Order No. 428 is invalid for failure to
comply with the Act's requirement that the sale price for gas sold
in interstate commerce be just and reasonable. The Court of Appeals
rejected what it apparently understood was
"the Commission's basic contention all along . . . that the
'just and reasonable' standard was not mandatory, and that the FPC
can simply choose not to regulate rates."
154 U.S.App.D.C. at 175, 474 F.2d at 422. Whatever the position
of the Commission heretofore has been, it wisely does not challenge
that aspect of the Court of Appeals judgment. Sections 4 and 5 of
the Act require that all gas rates be just and reasonable; and the
Court held in
Phillips that this very prescription applies
to the rates of all gas producers. The Commission may have great
discretion as to how to insure just and reasonable rates, but it is
plain enough to us that the Act does not empower it to exempt small
producer rates from compliance with that standard.
Section 16, 15 U.S.C. § 7170, upon which the Commission relies,
is not to the contrary. It authorizes the Commission to perform any
and all acts and to issue any and all rules and regulations "as it
may find necessary or appropriate to carry out the provisions of
this Act"; and,
"[f]or the purposes of its rules and regulations, the Commission
may classify persons and matters within its jurisdiction and
prescribe different requirements for different classes of persons
or matters."
But § 16 obviously does not vest authority in the Commission to
set unjust and unreasonable rates, even for small producers. It
does not authorize the Commission to set at naught an explicit
provision of the Act. No producer is exempt from §§ 4 and 5.
Neither the
Permian Basin Area Rate Cases nor
FPC v.
Louisiana Power & Light Co., 406 U.
S. 621 (1972),
Page 417 U. S. 395
on which the Government relies, suggests or holds that § 16
permits the Commission to ignore the specific mandates of those
sections. [
Footnote 6]
The Court of Appeals also read Order No. 428 as failing to
provide a mechanism for insuring that small producer rates will be
just and reasonable. In its view, the order provided a pure market
standard for the approval of the purchased gas costs of large
producers and pipelines, a standard which fell short of the
requirements of the Act. Accordingly, it set aside the order. The
Commission does not assert here that it is free under the Act to
equate just and reasonable rates with the prices for gas prevailing
in the market place. Its major remaining contention is that the
Court of Appeals misread Order No. 428, and that the order,
properly understood, contemplates a scheme of indirect regulation
that would assure just and reasonable small producer rates for
natural gas and that would judge small producer rates not only by
market factors, but by all the relevant considerations necessary to
arrive at the considered judgment contemplated by the Act. For
present purposes, then, the Commission accepts the Court of
Appeals' construction of the Act, but insists that the order is
consistent with the statute as so construed. In this posture of the
case, we think it clear that Order No. 428 cannot stand in its
present form, and that the cases should be remanded for further
proceedings before the Commission. We have studied the order with
care, and we cannot accept the construction of it that the
Commission now presses upon us. At the very least, the order is so
ambiguous that it falls short of that standard
Page 417 U. S. 396
of clarity that administrative orders must exhibit. The
Commission was bound to exercise its discretion within the limits
of the standards expressed by the Act; and
"for the courts to determine whether the agency
has
done so, it must 'disclose the basis of its order' and 'give clear
indication that it has exercised the discretion with which Congress
has empowered it.'"
Burlington Truck Lines v. United States, 371 U.
S. 156,
371 U. S.
167-168 (1962), quoting in part from
Phelps Dodge
Corp. v. NLRB, 313 U. S. 177,
313 U. S. 197
(1941). We shall indicate briefly our basis for this
conclusion.
In the first place, Order No. 428 does not expressly mention the
just and reasonable standard. It comes no closer than to subject
pipeline rates to reduction and refund
"only as to that part of the rate which is
unreasonably
high considering appropriate comparisons with highest contract
prices for sales by large producers or the prevailing market price
for intrastate sales. . . ."
45 F.P.C. at 457. (Emphasis added.) The order took a very
similar approach to the tracking increases by large producers.
Moreover, under the order, contractually authorized increases in
rates for flowing gas under existing contracts could be
automatically passed through by the pipelines and would not be
subject to examination under the standard proposed by the order
with respect to new sales by small producers. There was no finding
that these contemplated increased rates for flowing gas would be
just and reasonable. The Commission merely asserts in its brief
here that it was familiar with the existing contracts, and must
have considered the rates reserved to be acceptable under the
Act.
It is true that pipeline and large-producer costs for new small
producer gas were not to be "unreasonable," but the implication
appears to be that reasonableness would be judged by the standard
of the marketplace. It
Page 417 U. S. 397
is also true that the Commission asserted that it was not
deregulating small producer rates, that the Commission "shall
consider all relevant factors" in determining whether proposed
rates were consistent with the "public convenience and necessity,"
and that the Commission intended to review new contract prices
charged by small producers "to assure . . . the reasonableness of
the rates charged by such producers pursuant to the action we are
taking herein." But these generalities do not supply the requisite
clarity to the order or convince us that it should be
sustained.
Had the order unambiguously provided what the Commission now
asserts it was intended to provide, [
Footnote 7] we would have a far different case to decide.
But as it is, we cannot "accept appellate counsel's
post
hoc rationalizations for agency action"; for an agency's order
must be upheld, if at all, "on the same basis articulated in the
order by the agency itself."
Burlington Truck Lines, 371
U.S. at
371 U. S.
168-169;
SEC v. Chenery Corp., 332 U.
S. 194,
332 U. S. 196
(1947).
IV
For the purposes of the proceedings that may occur on remand, we
should also stress that, in our view, the prevailing price in the
marketplace cannot be the final measure of "just and reasonable"
rates mandated by the Act. It is abundantly clear from the history
of the Act and from the events that prompted its adoption that
Congress considered that the natural gas industry was heavily
concentrated and that monopolistic forces were
Page 417 U. S. 398
distorting the market price for natural gas. [
Footnote 8] Hence, the necessity for
regulation and hence the statement in
Sunray DX, 391 U.S.
at
391 U. S. 25,
that, if contract prices for gas were set at the market price,
this
"would necessarily be based on a belief that the current
contract prices in an area approximate closely the 'true' market
price -- the just and reasonable rate. Although there is doubtless
some relationship, and some economists have urged that it is
intimate, such a belief would contradict the basic assumption that
has caused natural gas production to be subjected to regulation. .
. ."
(Footnote omitted.)
Page 417 U. S. 399
In subjecting producers to regulation because of anticompetitive
conditions in the industry, Congress could not have assumed that
"just and reasonable" rates could conclusively be determined by
reference to market price. Our holding in
Phillips implies
just the opposite. This does not mean that the market price of gas
would never, in an individual case, coincide with just and
reasonable rates or not be a relevant consideration in the setting
of area rates,
see Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 U.S.
at
390 U. S.
793-795; it may certainly be taken into account along
with other factors,
Southern Louisiana Area Rate Cases,
428 F.2d 407, 441 (CA5),
cert. denied sub nom. Associated Gas
Distributors v. Austral Oil Co., 400 U.S. 950 (1970). It does
require, however, the conclusion that Congress rejected the
identity between the "true" and the "actual" market price.
The Court is not unresponsive to the special needs of small
producers who play a critical role in exploratory efforts in the
natural gas industry and ameliorating the supply shortage. The
requirements of the Act, however, do not distinguish between small
and large producers with respect to just and reasonable rates. Even
if the effect of increased small producer prices would make a small
dent in the consumer's pocket, when compared with the rates charged
by the large producers, the Act makes unlawful all rates which are
not just and reasonable, and does not say a little unlawfulness is
permitted. Moreover, there is no finding in the Commission's order
as to the actual impact the projected market price increases would
have on consumer expenditures for gas, and the Commission is
previously on record in its Permian decision, as stating: "[T]he
impact of small producer prices on consumers is by no means
de
minimis on an area basis, and is of great impact in some
situations." 34 F.P.C. 159, 235 (1965).
Page 417 U. S. 400
V
In concluding that the Commission lacks the authority to place
exclusive reliance on market prices, we bow to our perception of
legislative intent. It may be, as some economists have persuasively
argued, [
Footnote 9] that the
assumptions of the 1930's about the competitive structure of the
natural gas industry, if true then, are no longer true today. It
may also be that control of prices in this industry, in a time of
shortage, if such there be, is counterproductive to the interests
of the consumer in increasing the production of natural gas. It is
not the Court's role, however, to overturn congressional
assumptions embedded into the framework of regulation established
by the Act. This is a proper task for the Legislature, where the
public interest may be considered from the multifaceted points of
view of the representational process.
Attempts have been made in the past to exempt producers from the
coverage of the Act, but these attempts have been unsuccessful. The
Court realized as much in the
Phillips case. 347 U.S. at
347 U. S. 685,
and n. 14. In 1950, Congress had passed a bill, H.R. 1758, 81st
Cong., 2d Sess., to exempt gas producers from the Act, but
President Truman vetoed the bill stating that
"there is a clear possibility that competition will not be
effective, at least in some cases, in holding prices to reasonable
levels. Accordingly, to remove the authority to regulate, as this
bill would do, does not seem to me to be wise public
Page 417 U. S. 401
policy."
The President made this judgment despite the arguments that
imposition of price control would discourage exploration and
development of new wells. Public Papers of the Presidents, Harry S.
Truman, 1950, p. 257 (1965). For the Court to step outside its role
in construing this statute, and insert itself into the debate on
economics and the public interest, would be an unwarranted
intrusion into the legislative forum where the debate again rages
on the question of deregulation of natural gas producers.
We do, however, make clear that, under the present Act, the
Commission is free to engage in indirect regulation of small
producers by reviewing pipeline costs of purchased gas, providing
that it insures that the rates paid by pipelines, and ultimately
borne by the consumer, are just and reasonable. It may be, as some
of the respondents suggest, that ensuring just and reasonable rates
by means of indirect regulation will not be administratively
feasible, but this is a matter for the Commission to consider.
We agree with the Court of Appeals that the order of the
Commission must be set aside; but, for reasons previously stated,
we vacate the judgment of the Court of Appeals and remand the cases
to that court with instructions to remand the cases to the
Commission for further proceedings consistent with this
opinion.
Vacated and remanded.
MR. JUSTICE STEWART took no part in the consideration or
decision of these cases.
* Together with No. 72-1491,
Dougherty, Executor, et al. v.
Texaco Inc. et al., also on certiorari to the same court.
[
Footnote 1]
A "small producer" was defined as an independent producer, not
affiliated with a natural gas pipeline company, whose total
jurisdictional sales on a nationwide basis, together with sales of
affiliated producers, did not exceed 10,000,000 Mcf at 14.65 psia
during any calendar year. New small producer sales included any
sale made pursuant to a contract dated after March 18, 1971.
[
Footnote 2]
The Commission found that small producers produce about 10% of
the gas purchased by pipelines, excluding all pipeline-to-pipeline
sales. It appears, however, that they also account for 80% of the
natural gas exploration in this country.
[
Footnote 3]
Subsequently, the Commission issued two supplemental orders,
Order No. 428-A, 45 F.P.C. 548, revising the annual statement
requirements for small producers and Order No. 428-B, 46 F.P.C. 47,
which denied applications for rehearing and modified Order No. 428
in respects that need not be mentioned here.
[
Footnote 4]
The large producers also contend that they are put at a
disadvantage by the Commission's order because their contracts may
not permit them to pass on the increased costs of gas purchased
from small producers, whereas the pipelines will be in a position
to do so. This is, however, a function of the producers' contracts,
and the Commission has no authority, absent a finding that the
existing contract rate "is so low as to have an adverse effect on
the public interest," to permit large producers or pipelines to
raise their rates in excess of the maximum authorized in their
contracts,
FPC v. Sierra Pacific Power Co., 350 U.
S. 348,
350 U. S. 355
(1956);
United Gas Co. v. Mobile Gas Corp., 350 U.
S. 332 (1956). We think other claims of the large
producers, as to unfair treatment or discrimination, are equally
ill-founded.
[
Footnote 5]
The New York Public Service Commission also questions whether it
is administratively feasible for the FPC, on review of individual
pipelines' costs, to make sure rates are just and reasonable,
claiming that this would be a return with a vengeance to the
administrative morass which led to the adoption of area rates for
producers in the first instance. This claim is also premature in
light of possible regulatory approaches the FPC may take on
remand.
[
Footnote 6]
The Commission's position is not advanced by
FPC v.
Hunt, 376 U. S. 515,
376 U. S. 527
(1964). The Court in that case merely questioned whether exemption
might prove, after study, to be an available alternative.
[
Footnote 7]
The Commission, in its brief, has indicated that the standard
will not be limited to comparisons with appropriate market prices,
but will include (1) producer's costs, (2) the pipeline's need for
gas, (3) the availability of other gas supplies, (4) the amount of
gas dedicated under the contract, and (5) the rates of other recent
small producer sales previously approved for flow-through.
[
Footnote 8]
As appears from § 1(a) of the Act, 15 U.S.C. § 717(a), the
legislation stemmed from the 1935 Report of the Federal Trade
Commission. S.Doc. No. 92, pt. 84-A, 70th Cong., 1st Sess.
(published 1936). That report concluded that there was heavy
concentration both in the production and distribution of natural
gas. "The 4 largest producer groups account for about 72 percent of
the output of natural gas produced by 32 holding company groups in
1930."
Id. at 589. The heavy concentration of pipeline
ownership "accentuates whatever control the pipeline interests have
of the available gas supply."
Id. at 590. The Commission
concluded, on the basis of its detailed investigation of the
industry, that
"[t]he prime characteristic of the situation described is that
of a steadily developing concert of interests dominating the
producing, transporting, and distributing branches of the
industry."
Id. at 600. The heart of the problem was at the
pipeline end, since the concentration of ownership there allowed
the concert of interests
"to determine the amount of natural gas which may be marketed by
fixing the amount which may be transported. That, in turn, gives it
power to say how much shall be produced."
Ibid. Based upon these findings, the Commission singled
out as "Specific Evils Existing in the Natural Gas Industry" both
the "[u]nregulated monopolistic control of certain natural gas
production areas" and the "[u]nregulated control of pipeline
transmission and of wholesale distribution."
Id. at 615.
It concluded that regulation, at least of pipelines,
see
id. at 616, was required.
[
Footnote 9]
See C. Hawkins, Structure of the Natural Gas Producing
Industry, and P. MacAvoy, The Regulation-Induced Shortage of
Natural Gas, in Regulation of the Natural Gas Producing Industry
137-191 (K. Brown ed.1972).
See also Statement of John N.
Nassikas, Chairman, Federal Power Commission, Hearing on the
Natural Gas Industry before the Subcommittee on Antitrust and
Monopoly of the Senate Committee on the Judiciary, 93d Cong., 1st
Sess., 43-72 (1973).