Since 1953, ingot molds have moved almost exclusively by
combination barge-truck service from Neville Island and Pittsburgh,
Pa. to Steelton, Ky. The overall service charge since 1960 has been
$5.11 per ton. In 1963, appellees Pennsylvania Railroad and the
Louisville & Nashville Railroad, in order to compete for this
traffic, lowered their joint rate from $11.86 to $5.11 per ton. The
barge lines, joined by intervening trucking interests, protested to
the Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC) that the new railroad rate
impaired or destroyed the barge-truck service's "inherent
advantage," and thus violated § 15a(3) of the Interstate Commerce
Act and the National Transportation Policy. Under § 15a(3), a
carrier's rates
"shall not be held up to a particular level to protect the
traffic of any other mode of transportation, giving due
consideration to the objectives of the national transportation
policy declared in this Act."
The congressional intent stated in the National Transportation
Policy is to provide for fair regulation of all transportation
modes subject to the Act, administered so as to preserve "the
inherent advantage of each." The ICC found that the per ton fully
distributed cost of moving the traffic was $7.59 for the railroads
and $5.19 for the barge-truck service, and the long-term
out-of-pocket cost was $4.69 for the railroads and estimated to be
about $5.19 for the barge-truck service and, in any event, higher
than $4.69. Uncontroverted shipper testimony was that price solely
determined which service would be used, but that all traffic would
go to the railroads if their rates were the same as those of the
barge-truck combination. The ICC rejected the railroads' contention
that out-of-pocket costs should be the
Page 392 U. S. 572
basis on which "inherent advantage" should be determined,
observing that it had regularly viewed fully distributed costs as
the proper basis for determining the lower cost mode of two
competing modes for particular traffic; that legislative history
indicated that Congress intended fully distributed costs to be the
basis for comparison when it inserted into § 15a(3) the reference
to the National Transportation Policy, and that a rulemaking
proceeding was pending involving the whole question of costing in
situations involving intermodal competition, and that a radical
departure from the fully distributed cost norm would not be
warranted on the record before it. Utilizing the fully distributed
costs comparison to determine inherent advantage, the ICC ordered
the railroads' rate canceled, having concluded that such a rate
would infringe upon the barge-truck carriers' ability competitively
to assert their inherent advantage because it would compel them to
go well below their own fully distributed costs to recapture the
traffic from the railroads. The District Court reversed. After
analyzing this Court's opinion construing § 15a(3) in
ICC v.
New York, N.H. & H. R. Co., 372 U.
S. 744 (1963) ("New Haven"), and the legislative history
of § 15a(3), it concluded that the ICC order contravened the Act,
and held that Congress intended that inherent advantage should be
determined in most cases by a comparison of out-of-pocket costs,
and that, therefore, competing carriers should generally be free to
offer any rates as long as they were compensatory. It also held
that the ICC had not articulated the reasons for deciding that
inherent advantage should be determined by reference to fully
distributed costs.
Held: The ICC properly exercised its discretion in
disallowing the rate reduction proposed by the appellee railroads
as inconsistent with § 15a(3) of the Interstate Commerce Act and
the National Transportation Policy, and adequately articulated its
reasons for disallowing the proposed rate. Pp.
392 U. S.
579-594
(a) Before enacting § 15a(3), following railroad complaints that
the ICC had maintained artificially high rates to protect competing
modes from being driven out of business by the railroads, Congress
rejected language that would have required looking only to the
effect of a rate reduction on the proponent carrier.
"The principal reason for [the reference to the National
Transportation Policy] . . . was to emphasize the power of the
Commission to prevent the railroads from destroying or impairing
the inherent advantages of other modes."
New Haven, supra, at
372 U. S. 758.
Pp.
392 U. S.
579-582.
Page 392 U. S. 573
(b) The District Court erred in concluding from the New Haven
decision and its own interpretation of § 15a(3) that the ICC had
the burden of justifying a departure from using out-of-pocket cost
to determine inherent cost advantage, since New Haven did not
require any particular method of costing to be used as a standard.
Pp.
392 U. S.
583-584.
(c) Section 15a(3), in conjunction with the National
Transportation Policy, was not enacted to enable the railroads to
price their services in such a way as to obtain the maximum revenue
therefrom. P.
392 U. S.
589.
(d) The ICC has the authority to exercise its informed judgment
in determining the method of costing which is to be used under §
15a(3), and has reasonable latitude to determine where and how it
will resolve that complex issue. Pp.
392 U. S.
590-592.
(e) The District Court erred in not recognizing the ICC's ample
authority to decline to deal with the railroads' broad contentions
in this individual case pending its evaluation in the context of a
rulemaking proceeding of the effects on the transportation industry
as a whole of the alternatives of a departure from the fully
distributed cost standard which the ICC had been using in passing
upon individual rate reductions.
See Permian Basin Area Rate
Cases, 390 U. S. 747. Pp.
392 U. S.
590-593.
(f) The ICC was not required to explain why it permitted
out-of-pocket ratemaking for unregulated carriers and not where the
competition was regulated, since § 15a(3), by its own terms,
applies only to regulated carriers. P.
392 U. S.
593.
(g) The ICC adequately explained how the railroads' rate would
impair the barge-truck inherent advantage, for, as the ICC pointed
out, the ratemaking principle proposed by the railroads would have
permitted them to capture all the traffic presently handled by the
barge-truck combination because the railroads' out-of-pocket costs
were lower than those of the barge-truck service. Pp.
392 U. S.
593-594.
268 F.
Supp. 71, reversed and remanded.
Page 392 U. S. 574
MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL delivered the opinion of the Court.
The basic issue in these cases is whether the action of the
Interstate Commerce Commission in disallowing a rate reduction
proposed by the appellee railroads, 326 I.C.C. 77 (1965), was
consistent with the provisions of § 15a(3) of the Interstate
Commerce Act, 49 U.S.C. § 15a(3), added by 72 Stat. 572 (1958),
which governs ratemaking in situations involving intermodal
competition. A subsidiary but related issue is whether the
Commission adequately articulated its reasons for disallowing the
proposed rate. A statutory three-judge court, upon appeal of the
Commission's decision by the appellee railroads, held that the
Commission's decision was erroneous on both of the foregoing
grounds.
268 F.
Supp. 71 (D.C.W.D. Ky.1967). Because of the importance of §
15a(3) as the primary guide to ICC resolution of rate controversies
involving intermodal competition, we noted probable jurisdiction of
the appeal taken by the Commission and the competing carriers from
the decision of the District
Page 392 U. S. 575
Court. [
Footnote 1] 389 U.S.
1032 (1968). For the reasons detailed below, we conclude that the
District Court erred in its rejection of the Commission's decision
and the grounds on which it was based, and we reverse.
I
Since 1953, the movement of ingot molds from Neville Island and
Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania, to Steelton, Kentucky, has been almost
exclusively by combination barge-truck service, and, since 1960,
the overall charge for this service has been $5.11 per ton. In
1963, the Pennsylvania Railroad and the Louisville & Nashville
Railroad lowered their joint rate for this same traffic from $11.86
to $5.11 per ton. The competing barge lines, joined by intervening
trucking interests, protested to the ICC that the new railroad rate
violated § 15a(3) of the Interstate Commerce Act because it
impaired or destroyed the "inherent advantage" [
Footnote 2] then enjoyed by the barge-truck
service. The Commission thereupon undertook an investigation of the
rate reduction.
In the course of the administrative proceedings that followed,
the ICC made the following factual findings, about which there is
no real dispute among the parties. The fully distributed cost
[
Footnote 3] to the railroads
of this service
Page 392 U. S. 576
was $7.59 per ton, and the "long-term out-of-pocket costs"
[
Footnote 4] were $4.69 per
ton. The fully distributed cost to the barge-truck service
[
Footnote 5] was $5.19 per ton.
[
Footnote 6] The out-of-pocket
cost [
Footnote 7] of the
barge-truck service was not separately computed, but was estimated,
without contradiction, to be approximately the same as the fully
distributed cost, and higher, in any event, than the out-of-pocket
cost of the railroads. The uncontroverted shipper testimony was to
the effect that price was virtually
Page 392 U. S. 577
the sole determinant of which service would be utilized, but
that, were the rates charged by the railroads and the barge-truck
combination the same, all the traffic would go to the
railroads.
The railroads contended that they should be permitted to
maintain the $5.11 rate, once it was shown to exceed the
out-of-pocket cost attributable to the service, on the ground that
any rate so set would enable them to make a profit on the traffic.
The railroads further contended that the fact that the rate was
substantially below their fully distributed cost for the service
was irrelevant, since that cost in no way reflected the
profitability of the traffic to them. The barge-truck interests, on
the other hand, took the position that § 15a(3) required the
Commission to look to the railroads' fully distributed costs in
order to ascertain which of the competing modes had the inherent
cost advantage on the traffic at issue. They argued that the fact
that the railroads' rate would be profitable was merely the minimum
requirement under the statute. The railroads, in response,
contended that inherent advantage should be determined by a
comparison of out-of-pocket, rather than fully distributed costs,
and they produced several economists to testify that, from the
standpoint of economic theory, the comparison of out-of-pocket, or
incremental, costs was the only rational way of regulating
competitive rates.
The ICC rejected the railroads' contention that out-of-pocket
costs should be the basis on which inherent advantage should be
determined. The Commission observed that it had in the past
regularly viewed fully distributed costs as the appropriate basis
for determining which of two competing modes was the lower cost
mode as regards particular traffic. It further indicated that the
legislative history of § 15a(3) revealed that Congress had in mind
a comparison of fully distributed costs when it inserted the
reference to the National Transportation
Page 392 U. S. 578
Policy into that section in place of language sought by the
railroads. The Commission also emphasized that there was a
rulemaking proceeding pending before it in which the whole question
of the proper standard of costing in situations involving
intermodal competition was being examined in depth, and stated that
"a radical departure from the fully distributed cost norm" would
not be justified on the basis of the record before it in this
case.
Having decided to utilize a comparison between fully distributed
costs to determine inherent advantage, the Commission then
concluded that the rate set by the railroads would undercut the
barge-truck combination's ability to exploit its inherent advantage
because the rate would force the competing carriers to go well
below their own fully distributed costs to recapture the traffic
from the railroads. Moreover, since the result sought by the
railroads was general permission to set rates on an out-of-pocket
basis, the Commission concluded that, eventually, the railroads
could take all the traffic away from the barge-truck combination
because the out-of-pocket costs of the former were lower than those
of the latter and, therefore, in any rate war, the railroads would
be able to outlast their competitors. Accordingly, the Commission
ordered that the railroads' rate be canceled.
The District Court read the statute and its accompanying
legislative history to reflect a congressional judgment that
inherent advantage should be determined in most cases by a
comparison of out-of-pocket costs, and that, therefore, railroads
should generally be permitted to set any individual rate they
choose, as long as that rate is compensatory. [
Footnote 8] The court also held that the
Page 392 U. S. 579
Commission had failed adequately to articulate its reasons for
deciding that the proper way of determining which mode of
transportation was the more efficient was by comparison of fully
distributed costs, rather than out-of-pocket costs. Although this
latter holding appears first in its opinion, it is evident that it
must logically follow its ruling on the meaning of § 15a(3), since,
if Congress in enacting that section had already decided that
inherent advantage should be determined by reference to fully
distributed costs, there would be no special burden on the
Commission to justify its use of them.
II
This Court has previously had occasion to consider the meaning
and legislative history of § 15a(3) of the Interstate Commerce Act
in
ICC v. New York, N.H. & H. R. Co., 372 U.
S. 744 (1963) ("
New Haven"), and both the ICC
and the District Court have relied heavily on that decision as
support for the conflicting results reached by them in these cases.
Because the statute and its relevant legislative history were so
thoroughly canvassed there, we shall not undertake any extended
discussion of the same material here. Instead, we shall refer to
that opinion for most of the relevant history.
So far as relevant here. § 15a(3) provides that:
"[r]ates of a carrier shall not be held up to a particular level
to protect the traffic of any other mode of transportation, giving
due consideration to the objectives of the national transportation
policy declared in this Act."
The National Transportation Policy, 49 U.S.C. preceding § 1,
states that it is the intention of the Congress:
"to provide for fair and impartial regulation of all modes of
transportation subject to the provisions of this act, so
administered as to recognize and preserve the inherent advantages
of each. . . . "
Page 392 U. S. 580
The enactment of § 15a(3) in 1958 was due primarily to
complaints by the railroads that the ICC had maintained rates at
artificially high levels in older to protect competing modes from
being driven out of business by railroad competition. [
Footnote 9] The bill that eventuated in
the language that is presently § 15a(3) originally provided that
the ICC, in considering rate reductions, should, in a proceeding
involving competition with another mode of transportation,
"consider the facts and circumstances attending the movement of the
traffic by railroad, and
not by such other mode."
(Emphasis added.) 372 U.S. at
372 U. S. 754.
This language was objected to strongly by both the ICC and
representatives of those carriers with which the railroads were in
competition.
See Hearings on S. 3778 before the Senate
Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, 85th Cong., 2d Sess.
(1958). The basic ground of objection was that, by looking only to
the effect of a rate reduction on the carrier proposing it, the ICC
would be unable to protect the "inherent advantages" enjoyed by
competing carriers on the traffic to which a rate reduction was to
be applied.
Page 392 U. S. 581
Unfortunately, the meaning of the term "inherent advantage,"
which is what the Commission is supposed to protect, is nowhere
spelled out in the statute. The railroads argue, and the District
Court held, that Congress intended by the term to refer to
situations in which one carrier could transport goods at a lower
incremental cost than another. The fallacy of this argument is that
it renders the term "inherent advantage" essentially meaningless in
the context of the language and history of § 15a(3).
Since the pricing of railroad services below out-of-pocket or
incremental cost would result in a net revenue loss to the railroad
on the carriage, the ICC could prohibit such practices without
reference to the costs of any other competing carrier. And this is
precisely what the language of the bill, as originally endorsed by
the railroads, would have provided by its use of the phrase "and
not by such other mode."
See supra at
392 U. S. 580.
This language was, however, rejected by the Congress, and the
alternative formulation proposed by the ICC,
see Hearings,
supra, at 169, was substituted for it.
As this Court said in the
New Haven case:
"The principal reason for this reference [to the National
Transportation Policy] . . . was to emphasize the power of the
Commission to prevent the railroads from destroying or impairing
the inherent advantages of other modes. And the precise example
given to the Senate Committee, which led to the language adopted,
was a case in which the railroads, by establishing on a part of
their operations a compensatory rate below their fully distributed
cost, forced a smaller competing lower cost mode to go below its
own fully distributed cost, and thus, perhaps, to go out of
business."
372 U.S. at
372 U. S.
758.
Page 392 U. S. 582
Since these cases are identical to the example just described,
it would seem that, at the very least, the result reached by the
Commission here is presumptively in accord with the language of the
statute and with the intent of Congress in utilizing that language.
[
Footnote 10]
Page 392 U. S. 583
The District Court, however, ignored the above portion of the
New Haven opinion and seized on certain other language
therein to the effect that:
"It may be, for example, that neither a comparison of
'out-of-pocket' nor a comparison of 'fully distributed' costs, as
those terms are defined by the Commission, is the appropriate
method of deciding which of two competing modes has the cost
advantage on a given movement."
372 U.S. at
372 U. S. 760.
It coupled this language with its interpretation of 15a(3) as
having the purpose to promote "hard competition," and concluded
that the Commission had the burden of justifying any departure from
using out-of-pocket cost as the means of determining inherent cost
advantage.
We think that the District Court erred in its reading both of
the prior
New Haven decision and of the extent to which
Congress intended to foster intermodal competition. We note first
that nothing in the language of the
New Haven opinion
indicates a preference for either out-of-pocket or fully
distributed costs as a measure of inherent advantage; rather, all
that is said is that the appropriate measure "may be" neither.
Given the fact that the insertion of the reference to inherent
advantage into
Page 392 U. S. 584
§ 15a(3) came about at the insistence of carriers that were
demanding that fully distributed costs be the sole measure of that
advantage, [
Footnote 11] we
think that the clear import of the foregoing statement in the
New Haven opinion was that the Commission could, after due
consideration, decide that some other measure of comparative costs
might be more satisfactory in situations involving intermodal
competition than the one it had traditionally utilized. [
Footnote 12] That is a far cry from
saying that it must.
The District Court apparently believed that the Commission was
required to exercise its judgment in the direction of using
out-of-pocket costs as the rate floor
Page 392 U. S. 585
because that would encourage "hard" [
Footnote 13] competition. We do not deny that the
competition that would result from such a decision would probably
be "hard." Indeed, from the admittedly scanty evidence in this
record, one might well conclude that the competition resulting from
out-of-pocket ratemaking by the railroads would be so hard as to
run a considerable number of presently existing barge and truck
lines out of business.
We disagree, however, with the District Court's reading of
congressional intent. The language contained in § 15a(3) was the
product of a bitter struggle between the railroads and their
competitors. One of the specific fears of those competitors that
prompted the change from the original language used in the bill was
that the bill, as it then read, would permit essentially
unregulated competition between all the various transportation
modes. It was argued with considerable force that permitting the
railroads to price on an out-of-pocket basis to meet competition
would result in the
Page 392 U. S. 586
eventual complete triumph of the railroads in intermodal
competition because of their ability to impose all their constant
costs [
Footnote 14] on
traffic for which there was no competition.
The economists who testified for the railroads in this case all
stated that such an unequal allocation of constant costs among
shippers on the basis of demand for railroad service,
i.e., on the existence of competition for particular
traffic, [
Footnote 15] was
economically sound and desirable. Apart from the merits of this
contention as a matter of economic theory, [
Footnote 16] it is quite clear that it was
Page 392 U. S. 587
a contention that was not by any means wholly accepted by the
Congress that enacted § 15a(3). One of the specific examples given
of an undesirable practice, and accepted by the members of the
Commerce Committee
Page 392 U. S. 588
that drafted the statute as such, was a case in which certain
railroads had engaged in day-to-day differential pricing on the
carriage of citrus fruit from Florida depending on whether
competitive carriage was available
Page 392 U. S. 589
by ship that day.
See Hearings,
supra, at
153-155. Similar complaints were made about seasonal variations in
rates by railroads depending on whether winter conditions
interfered with the carriage of freight by water.
Id. at
162-163 . Yet, from an economic standpoint, such rate variations
make perfect competitive sense insofar as maximization of railroad
revenues is concerned. [
Footnote
17]
The simple fact is that 15a(3) was not enacted, as the railroads
claim, to enable them to price their services in such a way as to
obtain the maximum revenue therefrom. The very words of the statute
speak of "preserv[ing]" the inherent advantages of each mode of
transportation. If all that was meant by the statute was to prevent
wholly noncompensatory pricing by regulated carriers, language that
was a good deal clearer could easily have been used. And, as we
have shown above,
Page 392 U. S. 590
at least one version of such clear language was proposed by the
railroads and rejected by the Congress. If the theories advanced by
the economists who testified in this case are as compelling as they
seem to feel they are, Congress is the body to whom they should be
addressed. The courts are ill-qualified indeed to make the kind of
basic judgments about economic policy sought by the railroads here.
And it would be particularly inappropriate for a court to award a
carrier, on economic grounds, relief denied it by the legislature.
Yet this is precisely what the District Court has done in this
case.
We do not mean to suggest by the foregoing discussion that the
Commission is similarly barred from making legislative judgments
about matters of economic policy. It is precisely to permit such
judgments that the task of regulating transportation rates has been
entrusted to a specialized administrative agency, rather than to
courts of general jurisdiction. Of course, the Commission must
operate within the limits set out by Congress in enacting the
legislation it administers. But nothing we say here should be taken
as expressing any view as to the extent that § 15a(3) constitutes a
categorical command to the ICC to use fully distributed costs as
the only measure of inherent advantage in intermodal rate
controversies. As was stated in the
New Haven case, it
"may be" that, after due consideration, another method of costing
will prove to be preferable in such situations as the present one.
All we hold here is that the initial determination of that question
is for the Commission.
It is in this connection that the timing of this case takes on
particular significance. We have already observed that the ICC has
presently pending before it a broad-scale examination of the whole
question of the cost standards to be used where comparisons of
intermodal cost advantages are required. Rather than await the
result of that rulemaking proceeding, the railroad
Page 392 U. S. 591
appellees here determined to attempt to raise precisely the same
issues in a much more circumscribed proceeding by unilaterally
reducing their rates on one item of traffic. The District Court
totally ignored the temporary nature of the ICC's action in this
case and the pendency of the rulemaking proceeding. Instead, it
went ahead and, in the guise of resolving this particular
controversy over a single rate reduction, rendered a decision
which, for all practical purposes, made the rulemaking proceeding
moot. While there might be some justification for such a course
when the applicable statute clearly requires the agency to arrive
at a given result, this case is emphatically not such a situation.
As this Court stated in
New Haven, "[t]hese and other
similar questions should be left for initial resolution to the
Commission's informed judgment." 372 U.S. at
372 U. S.
761.
The Commission stated here that it intended to exercise its
informed judgment by considering the issues presented here in the
context of a rulemaking proceeding where it could evaluate the
alternatives on the basis of a consideration of the effects of a
departure from a fully distributed cost standard on the
transportation industry as a whole. Until that evaluation was
completed, the Commission took the position that it would continue
to follow the practice it had observed in the past of dealing with
individual rate reductions on a fully distributed cost basis. The
District Court, in effect, refused to permit the Commission to deal
with the complex problems of developing a general standard of
costing to use in determining inherent advantage in situations
involving intermodal competition in the broad context of a
rulemaking proceeding. Instead, it ordered the Commission to
resolve those problems in the narrow context of this individual
rate reduction proceeding.
We have already observed that the District Court erred in
interpreting the
New Haven decision to require
Page 392 U. S. 592
the Commission to permit out-of-pocket pricing in most
instances. Given the fact that
New Haven indicated that
the Commission was to exercise its informed judgment in ultimately
determining what method of costing was preferable, it is clear that
the District Court also erred in refusing to permit the Commission
to exercise that judgment in a proceeding it reasonably believed
would provide the most adequate record for the resolution of the
problems involved. We can see no justification for denying the
Commission reasonable latitude to decide where it will resolve
these complex issues, in addition to how it will resolve them. The
action by the District Court here not only deprives the Commission
of the opportunity to make the initial resolution of the issues,
but also prevents it from doing so in a more suitable context.
This Court has just recently held that the Federal Power
Commission had the authority to fix rates on an area-wide basis,
rather than on an individual producer basis, and that, in order to
make such a procedure feasible, it had statutory authority to
impose a moratorium upon rate increases by producers for a period
of 2 1/2 years after the setting of the area rate.
Permian
Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 U. S. 747
(1968). The basis for this holding was the principle that the
"legislative discretion implied in the ratemaking power
necessarily extends to the entire legislative process, embracing
the method used in reaching the legislative determination, as well
as that determination itself."
Id. at
390 U. S. 776.
That principle is equally applicable to rate regulation carried out
by the ICC, especially where, as here, the determination made on an
interim basis is in general accord with both the legislative
history of the statute involved and the results in prior cases
decided by the agency. Accordingly, we hold that the Commission had
ample authority to decline to deal with the broad contentions
advanced by the railroads in
Page 392 U. S. 593
this individual rate case, and that the District Court erred in
failing to recognize that authority.
The District Court also objected to the failure of the
Commission to explain why it permitted out-of-pocket ratemaking
where the competing carrier was unregulated, and not where the
competitor was regulated. The short answer to this is that §
15a(3), by its own terms, applies only to "modes of transportation
subject to this Act," which, by definition, means regulated
carriers. As a result, any arbitrariness that may flow from the
distinction recognized by the Commission between regulated and
unregulated carriers in situations of intermodal competition is the
creation of Congress, not of the Commission.
The District Court also appears to have held that the Commission
did not adequately explain how the rate set by the railroads would
impair or destroy the barge-truck inherent advantage. Yet the
Commission pointed out that the principle proposed by the railroads
would, if recognized, permit the railroads to capture all the
traffic here that is presently carried by the barge-truck
combination because the railroads' out-of-pocket costs were lower
than those of the combined barge-truck service. The District Court
seems to have been impressed by the fact that the railroads were
merely meeting the barge-truck rate, despite the uncontroverted
evidence that, given equal rates, all traffic would move by train.
Given a service advantage, it seems somewhat unrealistic to suggest
that rate parity does not result in undercutting the competitor
that does not possess the service advantage. In any event,
regardless of the label used, it seems self-evident that a
carrier's "inherent advantage" of being the low cost mode on a
fully distributed cost basis is impaired when a competitor sets a
rate that forces the carrier to lower its own rate below its fully
distributed costs in order to retain the traffic. In addition, when
a
Page 392 U. S. 594
rate war would be likely to eventually result in pushing rates
to a level at which the rates set would no longer provide a fair
profit, the Commission has traditionally, and properly, taken the
position that such a rate struggle should be prevented from
commencing in the first place. Certainly there is no suggestion
here that the rate charged by the barge-truck combination was
excessive, and in need of being driven down by competitive
pressure. We conclude, therefore, that the Commission adequately
articulated its reasons for determining that the railroads' rate
would impair the inherent advantage enjoyed by the barge-truck
service.
The judgment of the District Court is reversed, and the cases
are remanded to that court with directions to enter a judgment
affirming the Commission's order.
It is so ordered.
* Together with No. 804,
American Trucking Assns., Inc., et
al. v. Louisville & Nashville Railroad Co. et al., No.
808,
American Waterways Operators, Inc. v. Louisville &
Nashville Railroad Co. et al., and No. 809,
Interstate
Commerce Commission v. Louisville & Nashville Railroad Co. et
al., also on appeal from the same court.
[
Footnote 1]
The United States, a statutory defendant in the District Court,
supported the railroads' position there and has participated in
support of them in the proceedings before this Court.
[
Footnote 2]
The term "inherent advantage" comes from the National
Transportation Policy, 49 U.S.C. preceding § 1, and is incorporated
by reference into § 15a(3) of the Interstate Commerce Act. The
meaning of the term is the central issue in these cases and will be
discussed in considerable detail,
infra at
392 U. S.
579-594.
[
Footnote 3]
Fully distributed costs are defined broadly by the ICC as
the
"out-of-pocket costs plus a revenue-ton and revenue ton-mile
distribution of the constant costs, including deficits, [that]
indicate the revenue necessary to a fair return on the traffic,
disregarding ability to pay."
New Automobiles in Interstate Commerce, 259 I.C.C. 475,
513 (1945).
[
Footnote 4]
The long-term out-of-pocket costs were computed under an
ICC-sponsored formula which generally holds that 80% of rail
operating expenses, rents and taxes are out-of-pocket, in that they
will vary with traffic. To this is added a return element of 4% on
a portion of the investment (all the equipment and 50% of the road
property), which is apportioned to all traffic on a proportional
basis.
Compare n 3,
supra.
[
Footnote 5]
This figure is not precisely a cost figure. Rather, it is the
barge fully distributed cost, plus the charge made for the truck
portion of the service and the charge for barge-truck transfer.
Since all parties seem willing to treat the figure as one of fully
distributed cost for the barge-truck combination, no further
mention will be made of its disparate elements.
[
Footnote 6]
Because the barge-truck rate of $5.11 was below the fully
distributed cost of the service, Division 2 of the ICC initially
concluded that the barge-truck combination had forfeited its right
to claim that its inherent advantage of lower fully distributed
cost was being impaired by the railroads' setting of a matching
rate. On reconsideration, the full Commission reversed this ruling
by Division 2, observing that there was no evidence that the
failure of the barge-truck rate to equal fully distributed cost was
due to anything but the barge lines' ignorance of the precise
amount of their fully distributed cost for this service. This
determination is not challenged here by any party, and we express
no opinion on it.
[
Footnote 7]
Out-of-pocket costs have been regarded generally in these cases
as equivalent to what economists refer to as "incremental" or
"marginal" costs. Accordingly, we shall equate the terms likewise,
although we have no intention of vouching for the accuracy of that
equation as a matter of pure economics.
Cf. n 4,
supra. Such costs are defined
generally as the costs specifically incurred by the addition of
each new unit of output, and do not include any allocation to that
unit of preexisting overhead expenses.
[
Footnote 8]
A rate is compensatory in the sense used by the District Court
any time it is greater than the out-of-pocket cost of the service
for which the rate is set. The term fully compensatory is sometimes
used to describe a rate in excess of fully distributed costs.
[
Footnote 9]
An illustration of such a case is the decision of the ICC that
was reversed in the
New Haven case. There, the ICC had
refused to permit the railroads to set a rate which was not only
above their out-of-pocket cost for the service, but was also above
their fully distributed cost for approximately half of the
movements involved. The Commission did not rely on a determination
of which of the competing carriers had the inherent advantage as to
costs, but instead decided broadly that the rate would eventually
destroy the coastwise shipping industry, and therefore should be
prohibited. This Court held that, in general, the ICC was required
to determine which of the competing carriers possessed the inherent
advantage before a rate could be ordered cancelled in order to
protect a carrier's present rate. While the Court indicated that
the Nation's defense needs might permit protection of even a higher
cost carrier in some cases, it held that the ICC had not adequately
shown
New Haven to be such a case.
[
Footnote 10]
The appellees also contend, and the District Court held, that
the statements in the legislative history of § 15a(3) that Congress
intended to compel the Commission to return to the approach to
competitive rate regulation it had utilized in the case of
New
Automobiles in Interstate Commerce, 259 I.C.C. 475 (1945),
indicate that out-of-pocket ratemaking was intended to be the rule
in such cases. However, the passage quoted from
New
Automobiles simply states that the rates of one mode of
transportation should not be held up merely to protect competing
modes. It says nothing at all about inherent advantages.
The railroads argue that the basic thrust of the
New
Automobiles case was to compare costs on an out-of-pocket
basis. And it is true that many of the comparisons there made were
on that basis. However, an examination of what the Commission
actually said and did in
New Automobiles compels the
conclusion that no flat rule of comparison of out-of-pocket costs
was there laid down. For example, the Commission concluded that, on
the basis of a comparison with the railroads' out-of-pocket costs
for shipping automobiles, the truckers were the lower cost mode
only up to 120 miles. On a fully distributed cost comparison, the
truckers were the lower cost mode up to 230 miles. 259 I.C.C. at
528. After discussing at some length the concept of reasonable
minimum rates, the Commission ultimately concluded that, generally,
the truckers had the cost advantage at distances up to 200 miles,
and that the railroads should be permitted to set rates that would
permit them to compete for the longer-haul traffic. 259 I.C.C. at
539.
Given the fact that the Commission was dealing with an attempt
by the truckers to get it to hold up railroad rates for distances
even greater than 600 miles, it is not surprising that the issue of
measuring inherent advantage as between fully distributed and
out-of-pocket costs did not receive detailed consideration, since,
by either method, the truckers were the low cost mode only up to a
little more than 200 miles. Thus, it cannot fairly be said that
New Automobiles represents a considered choice between the
two methods of cost comparison. Rather, what it stands for is the
principle emphasized in the
New Haven case that the rates
of one mode should not be held up to protect the revenues of a
competitor without regard to which is the low cost carrier.
In any event, what matters so far as § 15a(3) is concerned is
not what the Commission meant in
New Automobiles, but what
Congress thought it meant in 1958, when the section was enacted. As
we have shown in the text of the opinion above, Congress considered
New Automobiles to stand for the principle that the rate
structure of a competing mode should not be protected by the
Commission simply to prevent it from losing business through
competition.
[
Footnote 11]
The District Court also relied on the rejection of a similar
proposal by truck and barge interests that fully distributed costs
be the floor for reasonable minimum rates in the course of the
enactment of the National Transportation Policy in 1940. It seems
clear, however, that one of the major reasons for the rejection of
the so-called Miller-Wadsworth amendment by Congress was the
possibility that its enactment would prevent low-value industrial
and agricultural commodities from being carried at a rate low
enough to make it economically feasible to ship them in interstate
commerce.
See generally Nelson, Rate-Making In
Transportation -- Congressional Intent, 1960 Duke L.J. 221, 228
238.
[
Footnote 12]
While it is true that, for varying and sometimes unexplained
reasons, the Commission has not invariably used fully distributed
costs as the basis for cost comparison.s in situations involving
intermodal competition,
see 268 F. Supp. at 78, it is also
true that it has generally declared fully distributed cost
comparisons to be preferable. Thus, in the hearings on the bill
that was to become § 15a(3), Commissioner Freas stated:
"Whenever conditions permit, given transportation should return
the full cost of performing carrier service. . . . In many
instances, however, the full cost of the low-cost form of
transportation exceeds the out-of-pocket cost of another. If, then,
we are required to accept the rates of the high cost carrier merely
because they exceed its out-of-pocket costs, we see no way of
preserving the inherent advantages of the low cost carrier."
Quoted at 372 U.S. at
372 U. S.
755.
[
Footnote 13]
The District Court ascertained the legislative purpose to
promote "hard competition" from the following passage from the
New Haven opinion:
"Section 15a(3), in other words, made it clear that something
more than even hard competition must be shown before a particular
rate can be deemed unfair or destructive. The principal purpose of
the reference to the National Transportation Policy, as we have
seen, was to prevent a carrier from setting a rate which would
impair or destroy the inherent advantages of a competing carrier,
for example, by setting a rate, below its own fully distributed
costs, which would force a competitor with a cost advantage on
particular transportation to establish an unprofitable rate in
order to attract traffic."
372 U.S. at
372 U. S. 759.
Since the sentence following the term "hard competition" described
an example of the competition prohibited by the National
Transportation Policy that is identical to the facts of the present
case, the District Court's use of the term to reverse the ICC's
decision here seems somewhat peculiar.
[
Footnote 14]
Constant costs are, broadly speaking, those items of expense
which are incurred by a business regardless of the scale of its
operations. They are essentially the equivalent to what is commonly
called overhead expenses. For railroads, constant costs include
such items as real estate taxes, certain rents, much right-of-way
maintenance expense, and similar expenses.
[
Footnote 15]
Unequal allocation of constant costs as an element of the rate
charged also occurs commonly where a bulky commodity is so low
valued on a per ton basis that setting a rate by reference to the
fully distributed cost of carrying the commodity would make it
uneconomic to ship it.
See n 11,
supra.
[
Footnote 16]
This Court is not particularly suited to pass on the merits of
the economic arguments made by the railroads' expert witnesses in
these cases. Moreover, their soundness is not especially relevant
to the result we reach in the present posture of this controversy.
However, because the economic testimony is emphasized so heavily by
both the railroads and the United States in their arguments to us,
we shall venture a few observations on it.
Most of the economic testimony is directed towards proving that
the utilization of out-of-pocket costs in setting rates permits the
railroads to maximize their profits. To the extent that
out-of-pocket costs are accurately computed, that proposition
appears uncontrovertible. The economists then go on to argue, in
effect, that what is good for the railroads is good for the
country. This argument is developed as follows. Whenever a railroad
lowers its rate, the shipper to whom that rate is available
benefits. As long as the rate is above the out-of-pocket cost of
the service, the railroad benefits by obtaining the profits from
traffic it formerly did not carry. The fact that a competing
carrier may lose the revenue it previously earned by carrying the
traffic is immaterial because the railroad's ability to make a
profit by charging the lower rate shows that it is, in some sense,
more efficient than its competitor.
In order to evaluate the foregoing argument, certain other
aspects of a railroad's operation must be kept in mind. The reason
why a railroad's fully distributed costs are substantially greater
than its out-of-pocket costs on any given traffic is,
inter
alia, because certain constant costs,
see n 14,
supra, are allocated
to that traffic on a proportional basis despite the fact that those
costs will be incurred by the railroad whether it carries the
particular traffic or not. These constant costs must be earned if
the railroad is to stay in business. They are allocated
proportionally on the theory that, all other factors being equal,
such an allocation will be the best way of assuring that each
shipper contributes his fair share towards covering the constant
costs. Obviously, to the extent that any shipper pays more of the
constant costs than another without any good reason for so doing
that shipper is, in some sense, discriminated against.
The railroad economists point out that, because constant costs,
by definition, are not attributable to the carriage of any
particular traffic, it is to some extent arbitrary to allocate them
to particular traffic. They further contend that all shippers
presently utilizing a railroad's services are benefited when the
railroad obtains additional traffic at a profit to it, because that
profit can be used to pay a portion of the constant costs currently
being charged wholly to them. The fact that charging a rate less
than its fully distributed cost of carrying the traffic results in
the shipper of that freight paying a disproportionally low share of
the railroad's constant costs is considered to be outweighed by the
overall benefit to the other shippers of having the absolute amount
borne by them of the constant costs decreased by the profit earned
on the traffic.
It seems apparent, however, that, in a case where the sole
reason that a rate below fully distributed cost is necessary to
attract such additional traffic is the competition of another mode
of transportation, the continued existence of that competition is
also the sole economic justification for maintaining the rate at a
relative level that favors one shipper over others. If the
competing carrier is driven out of business because of its
inability to match the railroad's lower rates set on an
out-of-pocket basis, the economic justification for permitting the
continuation of those low rates would seem to disappear. Yet the
railroad economists assert that, in such a situation, the railroad
should be required by the ICC to maintain the rate at its original
level. The obvious reason for this position is that permitting a
railroad to raise its rates once it had effectively destroyed a
competitor in one area would enable it to price on an out-of-pocket
basis in competition with another carrier in a different area
thereafter, and, in turn, drive that carrier out of business.
Eventually a railroad could eliminate all its competitors whose
out-of-pocket costs were higher than its own. After this was
accomplished, the railroad could re-price all its services on a
fully distributed cost basis, thereby eliminating all
discrimination between its shipper customers.
Of course, the shippers formerly served by competing modes at
rates profitable to them but lower than the railroad's fully
distributed costs would, at that point, have lost the advantage of
the low cost service. The only way to perpetuate the advantage
previously enjoyed by those shippers would be, as the railroad
economists recognized, artificially to maintain their rates at the
former level despite the absence of present economic justification
for such a low rate. (It is true that, were the barriers to reentry
into the transportation market low, as asserted by the railroad
economists, the potential competition created by the possibility of
such reentry by a competing mode could furnish an economic
justification for the continuance of the original low rate.
However, there is no factual evidence in this record from which it
can be concluded that barriers to reentry are low enough to create
such potential competition.)
If the only justification for the maintenance of a
disproportionally low rate to some shippers is the fact that
competition existed once upon a time for their business, would it
be irrational to conclude that it would be preferable to keep the
original competition in business to serve those shippers and to
require the railroad to look elsewhere for additional revenue?
Would it, for example, be possible for railroads to increase their
revenues instead by increasing, through selective rate decreases,
the volume of traffic shipped by persons who presently pay amounts
in excess of the fully distributed cost for the service afforded
them? These are only a few of the questions that come to mind when
we attempt to evaluate the economic arguments made in this case. We
do not pretend to be able to answer them. We merely note their
existence as evidence that we do not find the arguments made to the
ICC here as compelling as did the District Court.
Our discussion here should not be interpreted as a rejection of
the basic economic points made by the railroads. It is merely
intended to illustrate the desirability of having the initial
resolution of these issues made by a tribunal, and in a proceeding,
more suitable than the present one.
[
Footnote 17]
It is, of course, true that such discriminations need have no
necessary relationship to a railroad's cost of service, whether
that is computed on a fully distributed or out-of-pocket basis. On
the other hand, it is also evident that what is basically at issue
is a carrier's right to price discriminatorily, either between
shipments or shippers, in order to maximize revenues by
competition. By contrast, it can be noted that the railroads have
apparently retained their prior rate of $11.86 per ton on ingot
molds in areas where they have no competition from barge-truck
service. The discrimination thus created is not too dissimilar from
that embodied in the above examples.
MR. JUSTICE HARLAN, concurring in the result.
As I understand the Court's position, it is that the Commission
has not decided, and thus the Court need not decide, the question
expressly left open in
ICC v. New York, N.H. & H. R.
Co., 372 U. S. 744:
whether out-of-pocket costs, fully distributed costs, or some third
standard, should be the criterion for determining, under § 15a(3)
of the Interstate Commerce Act, 49 U.S.C. § 15a(3), and the
National Transportation Policy, preceding § 1 of the Act, which
mode of transportation has the inherent advantage. The reasoning of
the Court's opinion is, I take it, that the Commission may properly
adhere to a fully distributed costs standard pending its decision
in a separate rulemaking proceeding, entitled Rules Governing the
Assembling and Presenting of Cost Evidence, Docket No. 34013.
Although I do not doubt that an administrative agency may, where
the orderly processes of adjudication or rulemaking
Page 392 U. S. 595
require, defer the resolution of issues to more appropriate
proceedings, [
Footnote 2/1] I
should have had the greatest difficulty in saying that, in fact,
this had occurred, or had been intended to occur, in these cases.
[
Footnote 2/2] Nonetheless,
Page 392 U. S. 596
given both the Court's conclusion and the isolated statements in
the Commission's opinion consistent with that conclusion, I believe
it best to acquiesce in the result reached by the Court, rather
than to express my views
Page 392 U. S. 597
as a single Justice upon the issue which the Court shuns.
[
Footnote 2/3]
I would be less than candid if I did not say that I regard this
disposition of these cases as unsatisfactory, for what is now done
leaves this important question just where our decision of five
years ago in the
New Haven case left it, and new
litigation will now be necessary to resolve the issue.
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS, dissenting.
I would affirm the judgment below for the reasons stated by the
District Court in
268 F.
Supp. 71.
[
Footnote 2/1]
I do not, however, believe that the Court's position is really
supported by its references to the area pricing and moratoria
systems approved by the Court in the
Permian Basin Area Rate
Cases, 390 U. S. 747. The
Court's opinion in those cases emphasized that those administrative
devices were warranted in light of the terms of the Natural Gas Act
and of the extraordinary difficulties of regulating independent
producers of that commodity. I should not have thought it useful or
desirable to extrapolate from those unusual circumstances any
general extension of the discretion of administrative agencies. Of
course, the specific proposition taken by the Court today from the
opinion in those cases, which had, in turn, been taken from
Los
Angeles Gas Co. v. Railroad Commission, 289 U.
S. 287,
289 U. S. 304,
may be regarded as a general principle sustained by a number of the
Court's opinions. The difficulty, I should have supposed, is that
even that general proposition is only dimly relevant to the
questions now before us.
[
Footnote 2/2]
The appearance and disappearance of the suggestion that these
questions must be deferred pending the Commission's rulemaking
proceedings on the presentation of cost evidence deserves a more
complete chronicle than the Court has given. In 1965, more than
three years after the Commission initiated its rulemaking
proceeding, 27 Fed.Reg. 4102, and some two months before it decided
these cases, the Commission held that "a comparison of
out-of-pocket costs is the most appropriate method for ascertaining
. . . inherent competitive advantage" where one of the competing
modes is unregulated. The Commission found it unnecessary to defer
that question, or even to mention its separate rulemaking
proceeding.
Grain in Multiple-Car Shipments -- River Crossings
to the So., 325 I.C.C. 752, 772.
In the present case, the report and order of the Commission's
Division 2 indicated that it
"adhere[d] to the utilization of fully distributed costs as the
standard for determining the inherent advantage of low cost in the
situation presented."
323 I.C.C. 758, 762-763. The opinion did not pause to refer to
the rulemaking proceeding. In the report and order of the full
Commission on reconsideration, the only reference to the rulemaking
proceeding was the brief passage quoted by the Court from the
opinion's final section. 326 I.C.C. 77, 84. The three dissenting
members of the Commission found it unnecessary to refer to the
rulemaking proceeding.
Id. at 85, 86, 90.
One year after its decision in these cases, the Commission had
occasion to review its approach to these problems. Although the
Commission adhered to its decisions in these cases and in
Grain
in Multiple-Car Shipments -- River Crossings to the So.,
supra, it did not find it necessary to advert to its separate
rulemaking proceedings. It concluded that, where the competition
from a regulated carrier is "relatively limited," it would apply
the rule from
Grain in Multiple-Car Shipments, and not
that from these cases. There is no evidence whatever that the
Commission regarded these two lines of authority merely as
temporary expedients, useful only until more careful analysis is
possible.
Wine, Pacific Coast to the East, 329 I.C.C. 167,
171-175.
And see the concurring opinions of Vice Chairman
Tucker and Commissioner Freas,
id. at 176, as well as the
separate opinion of Commissioner Murphy, dissenting in part,
id. at 177.
Although the three-judge District Court set aside the
Commission's order in these cases, it did not mention the
rulemaking proceeding.
268 F.
Supp. 71.
In its jurisdictional statement to this Court, the Commission
adverted to the rulemaking proceeding only in a single sentence,
with an identifying footnote, contained in the statement's
conclusion. Jurisdictional Statement in No. 809, at 17. In the
memorandum of the United States, urging that probable jurisdiction
be noted, it was said that these cases "present a major issue
reserved by this Court" in
New Haven, which was
"whether out-of-pocket costs, fully distributed costs, or 'some
different measure' should be the criterion for determining which
mode of transportation has the inherent advantage. . . ."
Memorandum for the United States 3-4. In the various briefs
presented to the Court in these four cases, including the briefs of
the United States and of the Commission, I have looked in vain for
any suggestion that, as the Court now holds, the Commission's
opinion was intended merely to defer resolution of the question
reserved in
New Haven. Indeed, I have searched
unsuccessfully in the Commission's brief for any reference, however
fleeting, to the rulemaking proceeding. One might have supposed
that, if, as the Court now finds, the existence of the rulemaking
proceeding was, in the Commission's view, decisive to the result of
this case, the Commission would have found room in its brief of 51
pages at least to cite those proceedings. It is difficult to escape
the inference that the Court has, on a basis that will doubtless
prove as surprising to the parties as it did to me, simply
postponed decision of a difficult issue.
[
Footnote 2/3]
It is, however, proper to add that I have found no support in
the record for the Court's suggestion that
"the railroad appellees here determined to attempt to raise
precisely the same issues [as in the rulemaking proceeding] in a
much more circumscribed proceeding by unilaterally reducing their
rates on one item of traffic."
Ante at
392 U. S.
590-591.