1. It is a violation of the Sherman antitrust Act for labor
unions and their members, though furthering their own interests as
wage earners, to combine with employers and with manufacturers of
goods to restrain competition in, and to monopolize the marketing
of, such goods in interstate commerce. Pp.
325 U. S. 798,
325 U. S.
810.
2. Congress did not intend by the Clayton Act or the
Norris-LaGuardia Act that labor unions could, consistently with the
Sherman Act, aid nonlabor groups to create business monopolies and
to control the marketing of goods and services. P.
325 U. S.
808.
3. In § 6 of the Clayton Act, which provides that the Sherman
Act is not to be so construed as to forbid the "existence and
operation of labor, agricultural, or horticultural organizations
instituted for the purpose of mutual help," "the purpose of mutual
help" can not be deemed to extend to activities for the purpose of
"employer help" in controlling markets and prices. P.
325 U. S.
808.
4. Whether particular labor union activities violate the Sherman
Act may depend upon whether the union acts alone or in combination
with business groups. P.
325 U. S.
810.
5. It was the purpose of Congress in the antitrust legislation
to outlaw business monopolies; and a business monopoly is no less
such because a union participates. P.
325 U. S.
811.
6. The injunction against the union and its agents in this case
must be limited so as to enjoin only those prohibited activities
which were engaged in in combination with a nonlabor group. P.
325 U. S.
812.
145 F.2d 215, reversed.
CERTIORARI, 323 U.S. 707, to review a judgment which reversed a
judgment for the plaintiffs, 51 F. Supp. 3, in a civil suit to
enjoin alleged violations of the Sherman Act and ordered dismissal
of the suit.
Page 325 U. S. 798
MR. JUSTICE BLACK delivered the opinion of the Court.
The question presented is whether it is a violation of the
Sherman Anti-Trust Act [
Footnote
1] for labor unions and their members, prompted by a desire to
get and hold jobs for themselves at good wages and under high
working standards, to combine with employers and with manufacturers
of goods to restrain competition, in, and to monopolize the
marketing of, such goods.
Upon the complaint of petitioners and after a lengthy hearing,
the District Court held that such a combination did violate the
Sherman Act, entered a declaratory judgment to that effect, and
entered an injunction restraining respondents from engaging in a
wide range of specified activities.
41 F. Supp.
727,
51 F. Supp.
36. The Circuit Court of Appeals reversed the decision and
dismissed the cause, holding that combinations of unions and
business men which restrained trade and tended to monopoly were not
in violation of the Act where the
bona fide purpose of the
unions was to raise wages, provide better working conditions, and
bring about better conditions of employment for their members. 145
F.2d 215. The Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals having reached a
contrary conclusion in a similar case, 144 F.2d 546, we granted
certiorari in both cases. 323 U.S. 707.
The facts were sufficiently set out in the opinions below, and
need not be detailed again. The following summary will suffice for
our purposes.
Petitioners are manufacturers of electrical equipment. Their
places of manufacture are outside of New York City, and most of
them are outside of New York State as well. They have brought this
action because of their desire to sell their products in New York
City, a market area that has been closed to them through the
activities of respondents and others.
Page 325 U. S. 799
Respondents are a labor union, its officials and its members.
The union, Local No. 3 of the International Brotherhood of
Electrical Workers, has jurisdiction only over the metropolitan
area of New York City. It is therefore impossible for the union to
enter into a collective bargaining agreement with petitioners. Some
of petitioners do have collective bargaining agreements with other
unions, and in some cases even with other locals of the IBEW.
Some of the members of respondent union work for manufacturers
who produce electrical equipment similar to that made by
petitioners; other members of respondent union are employed by
contractors and work on the installation of electrical equipment,
rather than in its production.
The union's consistent aim for many years has been to expand its
membership, to obtain shorter hours and increased wages, and to
enlarge employment opportunities for its members. To achieve this
latter goal -- that is, to make more work for its own members --
the union realized that local manufacturers, employers of the local
members, must have the widest possible outlets for their product.
The union therefore waged aggressive campaigns to obtain closed
shop agreements with all local electrical equipment manufacturers
and contractors. Using conventional labor union methods, such as
strikes and boycotts, it gradually obtained more and more closed
shop agreements in the New York City area. Under these agreements,
contractors were obligated to purchase equipment from none but
local manufacturers who also had closed shop agreements with Local
No. 3; manufacturers obligated themselves to confine their New York
City sales to contractors employing the Local's members. In the
course of time, this type of individual employer-employee agreement
expanded into industrywide understandings, looking not merely to
terms and conditions of employment
Page 325 U. S. 800
but also to price and market control. Agencies were set up
composed of representatives of all three groups to boycott
recalcitrant local contractors and manufacturers and to bar from
the area equipment manufactured outside its boundaries. The
combination among the three groups, union, contractors, and
manufacturers, became highly successful from the standpoint of all
of them. The business of New York City manufacturers had a
phenomenal growth, thereby multiplying the jobs available for the
Local's members. Wages went up, hours were shortened, and the New
York electrical equipment prices soared, to the decided financial
profit of local contractors and manufacturers. The success is
illustrated by the fact that some New York manufacturers sold their
goods in the protected city market at one price and sold identical
goods outside of New York at a far lower price. All of this took
place, as the Circuit Court of Appeals declared, "through the
stifling of competition", and because the three groups, in
combination as "co-partners", achieved " a complete monopoly which
they used to boycott the equipment manufactured by the plaintiffs."
Interstate sale of various types of electrical equipment has, by
this powerful combination, been wholly suppressed.
Quite obviously, this combination of businessmen has violated
both Sections (1) and (2) of the Sherman Act [
Footnote 2] unless its conduct is immunized by the
participation of the union. For it intended to and did restrain
trade in and monopolize
Page 325 U. S. 801
the supply of electrical equipment in the New York City area to
the exclusion of equipment manufactured in and shipped from other
states, and did also control its price and discriminate between its
would-be customers.
Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader,
310 U. S. 469,
310 U. S. 512,
310 U. S. 513.
Our problem in this case is therefore a very narrow one -- do labor
unions violate the Sherman Act when, in order to further their own
interests as wage earners, they aid and abet business men to do the
precise things which that Act prohibits?
The Sherman Act, as originally passed, contained no language
expressly exempting any labor union activities. Sharp controversy
soon arose as to whether the Act applied to unions. One viewpoint
was that the only evil at which Congress had aimed was high
consumer prices achieved through combinations looking to control of
markets by powerful groups; that those who would have a great
incentive for such combinations would be the businessmen who would
be the direct beneficiaries of them; therefore, the argument
proceeded, Congress drafted its law to apply only to business
combinations, particularly the large trusts, and not to labor
unions or any of their activities as such. Involved in this
viewpoint were the following contentions: that the Sherman Act is a
law to regulate trade, not labor, a law to prescribe the rules
governing barter and sale, and not the personal relations of
employers and employees; that good wages and working conditions
helped, and did not hinder, trade, even though increased labor
costs might be reflected in the cost of products; that labor was
not a commodity; that laborers had an inherent right to accept or
terminate employment at their own will, either separately or in
concert; that, to enforce their claims for better wages and working
conditions, they had a right to refuse to buy goods from their
employer or anybody else; that what they could do to aid their
cause they had a right to persuade others to do;
Page 325 U. S. 802
and that the antitrust laws designed to regulate trading were
unsuitable to regulate employer-employee relations and
controversies. The claim was that the history of the legislation
supported this line of argument. [
Footnote 3]
The contrary viewpoint was that the Act covered all classes of
people and all types of combinations, including unions, if their
activities even physically interrupted the free flow of trade or
tended to create business monopolies, and that a combination of
laborers to obtain a raise in wages was itself a prohibited
monopoly. Federal courts adopted the latter view, and soon applied
the law to unions in a number of cases. [
Footnote 4] Injunctions were used to enforce the Act
against unions. At the same time, employers invoked injunctions to
restrain labor union activities even where no violation of the
Sherman Act was charged.
Vigorous protests arose from employee groups. The unions urged
congressional relief from what they considered to be two separate
but partially overlapping evils -- application of the Sherman Act
to unions and issuance of injunctions against strikes, boycotts and
other labor union weapons. Numerous bills to curb injunctions
were
Page 325 U. S. 803
offered. Other proposed legislation was intended to take labor
unions wholly outside any possible application of the Sherman Act.
All of this is a part of the well known history of the era between
1890 and 1914. [
Footnote 5]
To amend, supplement and strengthen the Sherman Act against
monopolistic business practices, and in response to the complaints
of the unions against injunctions and application of the Act to
them, Congress, in 1914, passed the Clayton Act. [
Footnote 6] Elimination of those "trade
practices" which injuriously affected competition was its first
objective. [
Footnote 7] Each
section of the measure prohibiting such trade practices contained
language peculiarly appropriate to commercial transactions, as
distinguished from labor union activities, but there is no record
indication in anything that was said or done in its passage which
indicates that those engaged in business could escape its or the
Sherman Act's prohibitions by obtaining the help of labor unions or
others. That this bill was intended to make it all the more certain
that competition should be the rule in all commercial transactions
is clear from its language and history.
In its treatment of labor unions and their activities the
Clayton Act pointed in an opposite direction. Congress in that Act
responded to the prolonged complaints [
Footnote 8] concerning application of the Sherman law to
labor groups by adopting Section 6; [
Footnote 9] for this purpose, and also drastically to
Page 325 U. S. 804
restrict the general power of federal courts to issue labor
injunctions, section 20 [
Footnote 10] was adopted. Section 6 declared that labor
was neither a commodity nor an article of commerce, and that the
Sherman Act should not be "construed to forbid the existence and
operation of labor, agricultural, or horticultural organizations,
instituted for the purposes of mutual help. . . ." Section 20
limited the power of courts to issue injunctions in a case
"involving, or growing out of, a [labor] dispute [over] terms or
conditions of employment. . . ." It declared that no restraining
order or injunction should prohibit certain specified acts, and
further declared that no one of these specified acts should be
"held to be violations of any law of the United States." This Act
was broadly proclaimed by many as labor's "Magna Carta", wholly
exempting labor from any possible inclusion
Page 325 U. S. 805
in the antitrust legislation; others, however, strongly denied
this.
This Court later declined to interpret the Clayton Act as
manifesting a congressional purpose wholly to exempt labor unions
from the Sherman Act.
Duplex Printing Press Co. v.
Deering, 254 U. S. 443;
Bedford Cut Stone Co. v. Journeymen Stone Cutters' Ass'n,
274 U. S. 37. In
those cases, labor unions had engaged in a secondary boycott; they
had boycotted dealers, by whom the union members were not employed,
because those dealers insisted on selling goods produced by the
employers with whom the unions had an existing controversy over
terms and conditions of employment. This Court held that the
Clayton Act exempted labor union activities only insofar as those
activities were directed against the employees' immediate employers
and that controversies over the sale of goods by other dealers did
not constitute "labor disputes" within the meaning of the Clayton
Act.
Again the unions went to Congress. They protested against this
Court's interpretation, repeating the arguments they had made
against application of the Sherman Act to them. Congress adopted
their viewpoint, at least in large part, and, in order to escape
the effect of the
Duplex and
Bedford decisions,
[
Footnote 11] passed the
Norris-La Guardia Act, 47 Stat. 71, 29 U.S.C. § 101
et
seq. That Act greatly broadened the meaning this Court had
attributed to the words "labor dispute", further restricted the use
of injunctions in such a dispute, and emphasized the public
importance under modern economic conditions of protecting the
rights of employees to organize into unions and to engage in
"concerted activities for the purpose of collective bargaining or
other mutual aid or protection." This congressional purpose found
further expression in the Wagner Act, 49 Stat. 449
Page 325 U. S. 806
We said in
Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, supra,
310 U. S. 488,
that labor unions are still subject to the Sherman Act to "some
extent not defined." The opinion in that case, however, went on to
explain that the Sherman Act
"was enacted in the era of 'trusts' and of 'combinations' of
businesses and of capital organized and directed to control of the
market by suppression of competition in the marketing of goods and
services, the monopolistic tendency of which had become a matter of
public concern:"
that its purpose was to protect consumers from monopoly prices,
and not to serve as a comprehensive code to regulate and police all
kinds and types of interruptions and obstructions to the flow of
trade. This was a recognition of the fact that Congress had
accepted the arguments made continuously since 1890 by groups
opposing application of the Sherman Acts to unions. It was an
interpretation commanded by a fair consideration of the full
history of antitrust and labor legislation.
United States v. Hutcheson, 312 U.
S. 219, declared that the Sherman, Clayton and Norris-La
Guardia Act must be jointly considered in arriving at a conclusion
as to whether labor union activities run counter to the antitrust
legislation. Conduct which they permit is not to be declared a
violation of federal law. That decision held that the doctrine of
the
Duplex and
Bedford cases was inconsistent
with the congressional policy set out in the three "interlacing
statutes."
The result of all this is that we have two declared
congressional policies which it is our responsibility to try to
reconcile. The one seeks to preserve a competitive business
economy; the other to preserve the rights of labor to organize to
better its conditions through the agency of collective bargaining.
We must determine here how far Congress intended activities under
one of these policies to neutralize the results envisioned by the
other.
Page 325 U. S. 807
Aside from the fact that the labor union here acted in
combination with the contractors and manufacturers, the means it
adopted to contribute to the combination's purpose fall squarely
within the "specified acts" declared by Section 20 not to be
violations of federal law. [
Footnote 12] For the union's contribution to the trade
boycott was accomplished through threats that, unless their
employers bought their goods from local manufacturers, the union
laborers would terminate the "relation of employment" with them and
cease to perform "work or labor" for them, and through their
"recommending, advising, or persuading others by peaceful and
lawful means" not to "patronize" sellers of the boycotted
electrical equipment. Consequently, under our holdings in the
Hutcheson case and other cases which followed it,
[
Footnote 13] had there been
no union-contractor-manufacturer combination, the union's actions
here, coming as they did within the exemptions of the Clayton and
Norris-La Guardia Acts, would not have been violations of the
Sherman Act. We pass to the question of whether unions can with
impunity aid and abet businessmen who are violating the Act.
On two occasions, this Court has held that the Sherman Act was
violated by a combination of labor unions and businessmen to
restrain trade. [
Footnote
14] In neither of them was
Page 325 U. S. 808
the Court's attention sharply called to the crucial questions
here presented. Furthermore, both were decided before the passage
of the Norris-La Guardia Act, and prior to our holding in the
Hutcheson case. It is correctly argued by respondents that
these factors greatly detract from the weight which the two cases
might otherwise have in the instant case.
See United States v.
Hutcheson, supra, 312 U. S. 236.
Without regard to these cases, however, we think Congress never
intended that unions could, consistently with the Sherman Act, aid
nonlabor groups to create business monopolies and to control the
marketing of goods and services.
Section 6 of the Clayton Act declares that the Sherman Act must
not be so construed as to forbid the "existence and operation of
labor, agricultural, or horticultural organizations, instituted for
the purposes of mutual help. . . ." But "the purposes of mutual
help" can hardly be thought to cover activities for the purpose of
"employer-help" in controlling markets and prices. And, in an
analogous situation where an agricultural association joined with
other groups to control the agricultural market, we said:
"The right of these agricultural producers thus to unite in
preparing for market and in marketing their products, and to make
the contracts which are necessary for that collaboration, cannot be
deemed to authorize any combination or conspiracy
with other
persons in restraint of trade that these producers may see fit
to devise."
United States v. Borden Co., 308 U.
S. 188,
308 U. S. 204,
308 U. S. 205
(italics supplied.)
We have been pointed to no language in any act of Congress or in
its reports or debates, nor have we found any, which indicates that
it was ever suggested, considered, or legislatively determined that
labor unions should be granted an immunity such as is sought in the
present case. It has been argued that this immunity can be
inferred
Page 325 U. S. 809
from a union's right to make bargaining agreements with its
employer. Since union members can, without violating the Sherman
Act, strike to enforce a union boycott of goods, it is said they
may settle the strike by getting their employers to agree to refuse
to buy the goods. Employers and the union did here make bargaining
agreements in which the employers agreed not to buy goods
manufactured by companies which did not employ the members of Local
No. 3. We may assume that such an agreement, standing alone, would
not have violated the Sherman Act. But it did not stand alone. It
was but one element in a far larger program in which contractors
and manufacturers united with one another to monopolize all the
business in New York City, to bar all other businessmen from that
area, and to charge the public prices above a competitive level. It
is true that victory of the union in its disputes, even had the
union acted alone, might have added to the cost of goods, or might
have resulted in individual refusals of all of their employers to
buy electrical equipment not made by Local No. 3. So far as the
union might have achieved this result acting alone, it would have
been the natural consequence of labor union activities exempted by
the Clayton Act from the coverage of the Sherman Act.
Apex
Hosiery Co. v. Leader, supra, 310 U. S. 503.
But when the unions participated with a combination of businessmen
who had complete power to eliminate all competition among
themselves and to prevent all competition from others, a situation
was created not included within the exemptions of the Clayton and
Norris-La Guardia Acts.
It must be remembered that the exemptions granted the unions
were special exemptions to a general legislative plan. The primary
objective of all the antitrust legislation has been to preserve
business competition and to proscribe business monopoly. It would
be a surprising thing if Congress, in order to prevent a
misapplication of that legislation to labor unions, had bestowed
upon
Page 325 U. S. 810
such unions complete and unreviewable authority to aid business
groups to frustrate its primary objective. For if business groups,
by combining with labor unions, can fix prices and divide up
markets, it was little more than a futile gesture for Congress to
prohibit price fixing by business groups themselves. Seldom, if
ever, has it been claimed before that, by permitting labor unions
to carry on their own activities, Congress intended completely to
abdicate its constitutional power to regulate interstate commerce
and to empower interested business groups to shift our society from
a competitive to a monopolistic economy. Finding no purpose of
Congress to immunize labor unions who aid and abet manufacturers
and traders in violating the Sherman Act, we hold that the district
court correctly concluded that the respondents had violated the
Act.
Our holding means that the same labor union activities may or
may not be in violation of the Sherman Act, dependent upon whether
the union acts alone or in combination with business groups. This,
it is argued, brings about a wholly undesirable result -- one which
leaves labor unions free to engage in conduct which restrains
trade. But the desirability of such an exemption of labor unions is
a question for the determination of Congress.
Apex Hosiery Co.
v. Leader, supra. It is true that many labor union activities
do substantially interrupt the course of trade, and that these
activities, lifted out of the prohibitions of the Sherman Act,
include substantially all, if not all, of the normal peaceful
activities of labor unions. It is also true that the Sherman Act
"draws no distinction between the restraints effected by violence
and those achieved by peaceful . . . means . . . ,"
Apex
Hosiery Co. v. Leader, supra, 310 U. S. 513,
and that a union's exemption from the Sherman Act is not to be
determined by a judicial
"judgment regarding the wisdom or unwisdom, the rightness or
wrongness, the selfishness or unselfishness of the end of
Page 325 U. S. 811
which the particular union activities are the means."
United States v. Hutcheson, supra, 312 U. S. 232.
Thus, these congressionally permitted union activities may restrain
trade in and of themselves. There is no denying the fact that many
of them do so, both directly and indirectly. Congress evidently
concluded, however, that the chief objective of antitrust
legislation, preservation of business competition, could be
accomplished by applying the legislation primarily only to those
business groups which are directly interested in destroying
competition. The difficulty of drawing legislation primarily aimed
at trusts and monopolies so that it could also be applied to labor
organizations without impairing the collective bargaining and
related rights of those organizations has been emphasized both by
congressional and judicial attempts to draw lines between
permissible and prohibited union activities. There is, however, one
line which we can draw with assurance that we follow the
congressional purpose. We know that Congress feared the
concentrated power of business organizations to dominate markets
and prices. It intended to outlaw business monopolies. A business
monopoly is no less such because a union participates, and such
participation is a violation of the Act.
This brings us to a consideration of the scope of the
declaratory judgment and the injunction granted by the district
court. We cannot sustain the judgment or the injunction in the form
in which they were entered. The judgment and the injunction apply
only to the union, its members, and its agents, since they were the
only parties against whom relief was asked. The judgment declared
that
"the combination and conspiracy and the acts done and being done
in furtherance thereof all as set forth in the findings of fact
herein are unlawful and contrary to the . . . Sherman Anti-Trust
Law, as amended and supplemented."
There were 374 findings
Page 325 U. S. 812
of fact which cover 111 pages of the printed record. These
findings were made from 25,000 pages of evidence. The declaratory
judgment, which was the foundation for the injunction, is thus
almost the equivalent of a statement that each fact "as set forth
in the 374 findings" constituted a violation of the Sherman Act.
And when we turn to the sweeping commands of the injunction, we
find that its terms, directed against the union and its agents
alone, restrained the union, even though not acting in concert with
the manufacturers, from doing the very things that the Clayton Act
specifically permits unions to do. We agree with the following
statement of the Circuit Court of Appeals:
"Indeed, the injunction is so far contrary to the statute that
its mandate might well have been stated in the converse of the
terms of the Clayton Act, § 20,
viz., as restraining Local
3 and its officers"
"from terminating any relation of employment, or from ceasing to
perform any work or labor . . . or from ceasing to patronize . . .
any party to such dispute, or from recommending, advising, or
persuading others by peaceful and lawful means so to do."
"29 U.S.C.A § 52,
supra. And the vague scope of the
declaratory judgment is even more indefinitely inclusive, in terms
reaching all the activities of the defendant set forth in the
findings."
Respondents objected to the form of the injunction and
specifically requested that it be amended so as to enjoin only
those prohibited activities in which the union engaged in
combination "with any person, firm or corporation which is a
nonlabor group. . . ." Without such a limitation, the injunction as
issued runs directly counter to the Clayton and the Norris-La
Guardia Acts. The district court's refusal so to limit it was
error.
The judgment of the Circuit Court of Appeals ordering the action
dismissed is accordingly reversed, and the cause is remanded to the
district court for modification and clarification
Page 325 U. S. 813
of the judgment and injunction consistent with this opinion.
Reversed and remanded.
[
Footnote 1]
26 Stat. 209; 50 Stat. 693.
[
Footnote 2]
Sections 1 and 2 provide in part as follows:
"Sec. 1. Every contract, combination in the form of trust or
otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among
the several States, or with foreign nations, is hereby declared to
be illegal. . . ."
"Sec. 2. Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to
monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or
persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the
several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of
a misdemeanor, . . ."
[
Footnote 3]
For a comprehensive discussion of the history of the Sherman
Act,
see 51 Cong.Rec. 13661-13668, 63rd Cong., 2nd Sess.
And see Ibid., 13969-13971, 14013-14016, 14020-14023.
See also Berman, Labor and The Sherman Act (1930), pp.
1-98; Mason, Organized Labor and The Law, Chapters 7 & 8;
Gompers, "The Sherman Law. Amend It Or End It", American
Federationist, Vol. 17, No. 3, March, 1910, pp. 197, 202. For prior
discussions in this Court of the dominant concern of Congress to
protect consumers from business combinations,
see United States
v. Trans-Missouri Freight Ass'n, 166 U.
S. 290;
Standard Oil Co. v. United States,
221 U. S. 1;
Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, 310 U.
S. 469;
United States v. South-Eastern Underwriters'
Ass'n, 322 U. S. 533.
[
Footnote 4]
See note 3
supra. See also 51 Cong.Rec. 9068-9077;
9081-9091;
United States v. Amalgamated Council, 54 F.
994;
Waterhouse et al. v. Comer, 55 F. 149;
United
States v. Debs, 64 F. 724;
Loewe v. Lawlor,
208 U. S. 274;
Lawlor v. Loewe, 235 U. S. 522.
And see Appendix to Berman,
op. cit. supra.
[
Footnote 5]
See authorities cited in footnotes
3 and |
3 and
S. 797fn4|>4,
supra. And see Frankfurter and
Greene, The Labor Injunction (1930); Berman,
op. cit.
supra, pp. 99-117.
[
Footnote 6]
38 Stat. 730.
[
Footnote 7]
Senate Report No. 698, 63rd Cong., 2nd Sess.
[
Footnote 8]
Ibid., 10-12.
[
Footnote 9]
Section 6 reads as follows:
"That the labor of a human being is not a commodity or article
of commerce. Nothing contained in the antitrust laws shall be
construed to forbid the existence and operation of labor,
agricultural, or horticultural organizations, instituted for the
purposes of mutual help, and not having capital stock or conducted
for profit, or to forbid or restrain individual members of such
organizations from lawfully carrying out the legitimate objects
thereof; nor shall such organizations, or the members thereof, be
held or construed to be illegal combinations or conspiracies in
restraint of trade, under the antitrust laws."
[
Footnote 10]
Section 20 reads in part as follows:
"And no such restraining order or injunction shall prohibit any
person or persons, whether singly or in concert, from terminating
any relation of employment, or from ceasing to perform any work or
labor, or from recommending, advising, or persuading others by
peaceful means so to do; or from attending at any place where any
such person or persons may lawfully be, for the purpose of
peacefully obtaining or communicating information, or from
peacefully persuading any person to work or to abstain from
working; or from ceasing to patronize or to employ any party to
such dispute, or from recommending, advising, or persuading others
by peaceful and lawful means so to do; or from paying or giving to,
or withholding from, any person engaged in such dispute, any strike
benefits or other moneys or things of value; or from peaceably
assembling in a lawful manner, and for lawful purposes; or from
doing any act or thing which might lawfully be done in the absence
of such dispute by any party thereto; nor shall any of the acts
specified in this paragraph be considered or held to be violations
of any law of the United States."
[
Footnote 11]
Milk Wagon Drivers' Union v. Lake Valley Farm Products,
Inc., 311 U. S. 91;
New Negro Alliance v. Sanitary Grocery Co., 303 U.
S. 552.
[
Footnote 12]
It has been argued that no labor disputes existed. The argument
is untenable. We do not have here, as we did in
Columbia River
Packers Association v. Hinton, 315 U.
S. 143, a dispute between groups of businessmen
revolving solely around the price at which one group would sell
commodities to another group. On the contrary, Local No. 3 is a
labor union, and its spur to action related to wages and working
conditions.
[
Footnote 13]
United States v. Building Trades Council, 313 U.S. 539;
United States v. United Brotherhood of Carpenters, 313
U.S. 539;
United States v. International Hod Carriers
Council, 313 U.S. 539;
United States v. American
Federation of Musicians, 318 U.S. 741.
[
Footnote 14]
United States v. Brims, 272 U.
S. 549;
Local 167 v. United States,
291 U. S. 293.
MR. JUSTICE ROBERTS.
While I should reverse the judgment, I am unable to concur in
the court's opinion. I think it conveys an incorrect impression of
the genesis and character of the conspiracy charged in the
complaint, and misapplies recent decisions of the court.
There is no doubt that the programme adopted by Local No. 3
envisaged the exclusion, from the entire New York City area, of any
electrical workers, whether engaged in manufacturing or installing
electrical devices and equipment, except members of the Local. The
organization from time to time increased the classes of members, so
as to add to its original membership of workers engaged in
fabricating and installing electrical devices, equipment, and
apparatus the additional categories of shop employes engaged in
manufacturing electrical equipment and all workers employed in
alterations, additions, and repairs involving electrical equipment.
It succeeded in unionizing and imposing closed shops employing only
members of Local 3 not only on all building contractors, but on all
repair contractors and their establishments and all manufacturers
of electrical equipment. Membership in the union was closely
restricted, and the campaign eventuated in a situation where no
electrical work could be done by persons other than members of the
union, no building construction could be done by other than union
men, no matter what their trade, and no manufactured electrical
appliance or apparatus could be installed in the New York area
without the consent of Local No. 3. That consent was given only if
the device, appliance or apparatus was manufactured, or work done
on it, by members of the Local. Complicated apparatus which had to
be manufactured
Page 325 U. S. 814
outside New York City, because no establishment making it
existed within the city, had to be dismantled and rebuilt by
members of the Local before it could be used in the New York
area.
It is true that, before Local No. 3 obtained this complete
control of the industry in its area of operation, certain
associated building contractors dealt jointly as an association
with the union. As respects certain manufacturers which came under
the dominance of the union, this is not true. Nor is it true of
repair businesses. On the contrary, it is the fact that each one of
these was individually coerced by the union's power to agree to its
terms. It is, therefore, inaccurate to say that the employers used
the union to aid and abet them to restrain interstate commerce.
Some of the employers, notably the building contractors, did
jointly cooperate with the union; other sorts of employers were
forced individually to comply with the union's demands, until all
of them had succumbed.
There can be no question of the purpose of the union. It was to
exclude from use in the City of New York articles of commerce made
outside the city and offered for sale to users within the city; it
was completely to monopolize the manufacture and sale of all
electrical equipment and devices within New York, and to exclude
from use in the area every such article manufactured outside the
city, whether in a closed union shop or not. The results of this
programme are obvious. Interstate commerce between New York City
and manufacturers having establishments outside the city was
completely broken off, and the monopoly created raised,
standardized and fixed the prices of merchandise and apparatus.
As I understand the opinion of the court, such a programme, and
such a result, is wholly within the law, provided only that
employers do not jointly agree to comply with the union's demands.
Unless I misread the opinion, the union is at liberty to impose
every term and
Page 325 U. S. 815
condition as shown by the record in this case, and to enforce
those conditions and procure an agreement from each employer to
such conditions by calling strikes, by lockout, and boycott,
provided only such employer agrees for himself alone, and not in
concert with any other.
I point out again, as respects certain employers here concerned,
that that is the situation, whereas, with respect to the building
construction employers, there was mutual agreement with the union.
But the opinion takes no note of the distinction in fact. It seems
to me that the law as announced by the court creates an impossible
situation such as Congress never contemplated, and leaves commerce
paralyzed beyond escape.
Until
Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, 310 U.
S. 469, was decided I had thought that a conspiracy by
laborers to interrupt the free flow of commerce was a violation of
the Sherman Act. That case, however, announced a narrower doctrine.
Its teaching is that only activity of labor which harms the
commercial competitive system through raising prices, restricting
production, or otherwise controlling the market falls within the
proscription of the Sherman Act. In that case, it was said:
"Furthermore, successful union activity, as for example
consummation of a wage agreement with employers, may have some
influence on price competition by eliminating that part of such
competition which is based on differences in labor standards.
Since, in order to render a labor combination effective, it must
eliminate the competition from nonunion-made goods,
see
American Steel Foundries v. Tri-City Central Trades Council,
257 U. S.
184,
257 U. S. 209, an
elimination of price competition based on differences in labor
standards is the objective of any national labor organization. But
this effect on competition has not been considered to be the kind
of curtailment of price competition prohibited by the Sherman Act.
"
Page 325 U. S. 816
It was added that the restraint there under examination was not
shown "to have any actual or intended effect on price or price
competition." The decision indicated that, in some undefined
circumstances, labor organizations might be subject to the
statute.
In
United States v. Hutcheson, 312 U.
S. 219, secondary boycotts by labor unions to keep out
of the market nonunion goods, or goods worked on by other unions,
were held immune from liability, civil or criminal, under the
Sherman Act. It was there said:
"So long as a union acts in its self-interest and does not
combine with nonlabor groups, the licit and the illicit under § 20
are not to be distinguished by any judgment regarding the wisdom or
unwisdom, the rightness or wrongness, the selfishness or
unselfishness of the end of which the particular union activities
are the means."
Thus, although a conspiracy between laborers is distinguished
from one between them and employers, it is intimated, as I think,
that a purpose on the part of a labor group to harm the commercial
competitive system, to raise prices, to restrict production, or
otherwise control the market, would not render the concerted action
illegal, provided only that no employer participated. The
reservation made in the
Apex case was discarded in the
Hutcheson case. This advance in the law was emphasized in
United States v. Building Trades Council, 313 U.S. 539,
and
United States v. Brotherhood of Carpenters, 313 U.S.
539, but the court went even farther, in
United States v.
American Federation of Musicians, 318 U.S. 741, and, as I
think, rendered a decision contrary to that now announced. There, a
motion to dismiss a bill of complaint was granted, and this court
sustained that action. The complaint charged a conspiracy by the
American Federation of Musicians, a nationwide organization, and
its officers, to obtain employment for its members by eliminating
entirely from interstate commerce all phonograph records
Page 325 U. S. 817
and electrical transcriptions of music and eliminating all
competition between transcribed music and that produced by living
musicians. The conspiracy charged was absolutely to prevent
manufacture or sale of phonograph records and electrical
transcriptions; to eliminate from the market all manufacturers,
distributors, jobbers or retailers of the same, and to prevent the
use of the articles, either in public places or private homes, and,
of course, to prevent their sale. In the bill, it was charged that
the conspiracy did not grow out of or involve any dispute
concerning terms or conditions of employment; that the purpose of
the conspiracy was to eliminate from the market, manufacture, sale
and use of mechanical recordings and records and transcriptions
unless the persons engaged in this business should enter into
agreements with the union, hiring useless and unnecessary labor, as
the union would demand. The further purpose of the conspiracy
charged was to exclude from the market competition by anyone who
failed exclusively to employ members of the union. The complaint
further charged that the purpose and effect of the conspiracy was
unlawfully to destroy all manufacture and sale, in interstate
commerce of phonograph records and electrical transcriptions,
eliminate all competition between music produced by mechanical
means and music produced by living musicians, to deprive the public
of an inexpensive means of entertainment in public places and in
the home.
This court's affirmance of the dismissal of this complaint can
only mean that every businessman who desires to stay in business
must, if a union so demands, enter into an agreement with the union
eliminating certain articles from his manufacture, from his sales,
or from his use. The decision must necessarily mean that it would
not be unlawful to enter into such an agreement with the union,
otherwise we should have the anomaly that the union's demand for
such an agreement is impeccable, but the employer's
Page 325 U. S. 818
acquiescence is unlawful. As shown by the opinion of the
District Court in that case (47 F.Supp. 304) the Government
contended that the Union's effort represented "an attempt by the
union to force employers to combine with it for the purpose of
restraining interstate trade. . . ." The District Court shortly
answered this contention (p. 309) by saying: "In the court's
opinion,
United States v. Brims, 272 U.
S. 549, and like cases, are not pertinent." This must
mean that each employer in the instant case is at liberty to agree
with the union on all the terms and conditions which create a
complete monopoly, a complete boycott, a complete closing of the
market, and a serious price fixing affecting competitive commercial
transactions. This is what I understand the court now holds. This
is what was accomplished with impunity by the Federation of
Musicians. But the situation created by such a holding is
unreal.
As I have pointed out, in two branches of the industry, the
manufacturers and employers, one by one, succumbed to union
pressure and entered into agreements. Was not such an action, in
each instance, a conspiracy? Are more than two parties required to
conspire, and did not each of those conspiracies, to some extent,
hinder and restrain interstate commerce and affect the market and
the competitive price situation? As each agreement was consummated,
the market was, to that extent, closed, and the boycott against
out-of-the-city manufactures tightened.
But more. The union did not conduct its campaign in a corner.
Albeit the findings are that manufacturers and repairers of
electrical appliances violently resisted the unionization of their
businesses, they, one by one, surrendered and signed. In doing so,
many must have had knowledge of what others were doing or had done.
And, as the coverage became complete, each one was enabled to
stifle out of town competition and to raise prices. In any action
against them and the union charging conspiracy, it
Page 325 U. S. 819
would be urged that a conspiracy need not consist of a written
or verbal agreement, but might be inferred from similarity of
action. And it would be little protection to the employers
concerned that, in each instance, a separate agreement was signed
between union and employer.
The course of decision in this court has now created a situation
in which, by concerted action, unions may set up a wall around a
municipality of millions of inhabitants against importation of any
goods if the union is careful to make separate contracts with each
employer, and if union and employers are able to convince the court
that, while all employers have such agreements, each acted
independently in making them -- this notwithstanding the avowed
purpose to exclude goods not made in that city by the members of
the union; notwithstanding the fact that the purpose and inevitable
result is the stifling of competition in interstate trade and the
creation of a monopoly.
The only answer I find in the opinion of the court is that
Congress has so provided. I think it has not provided any such
thing, and that the figmentary difference between employers
negotiating jointly with the only union with which they can deal --
which imposes like conditions on all employers -- and each employer
dealing separately with the same union is unrealistic and
unworkable. And the language of § 20 of the Clayton Act, 29 U.S.C.
§ 52, makes no such distinction.
This court, as a result of its past decisions, is in the
predicament that whatever it decides must entail disastrous
results. I can understand that the Circuit Court of Appeals felt
constrained by the prior decisions of this court to order the
judgment of the District Court reversed and the action dismissed.
If the present decision is, as I think, a retrogression from
earlier holdings, I welcome it; if it is but a limitation of them,
I concur in the partial
Page 325 U. S. 820
alleviation of an impossible situation. But I would not limit
the injunction as the opinion directs.
MR. JUSTICE MURPHY, dissenting.
My disagreement with the Court rests not so much with the legal
principles announced as with the application of those principles to
the facts of the case.
If the union in this instance had acted alone in its
self-interest, resulting in a restraint of interstate trade, the
Sherman Act concededly would be inapplicable. But if the union had
aided and abetted manufacturers or traders in violating the Act,
the union's statutory immunity would disappear. I cannot agree,
however, that the circumstances of this case demand the invocation
of the latter rule.
The union here has not in any true sense "aided" or "abetted" a
primary violation of the Act by the employers. In the words of the
union, it has been "the dynamic force which has driven the
employer-group to enter into agreements" whereby trade has been
affected. The fact that the union has expressed its self-interest
with the aid of others, rather than solely by its own activities,
should not be decisive of statutory liability. What is legal if
done alone should not become illegal if done with the assistance of
others and with the same purpose in mind. Otherwise, a premium of
unlawfulness is placed on collective bargaining.
Had the employers embarked upon a course of unreasonable trade
restraints, and had they sought to immunize themselves from the
Sherman Act by using the union as a shield for their nefarious
practices, we would have quite a different case. The union then
could not be said to be acting in its self-interest in combining
with the employers to carry out trade restraints primarily for the
employers' interests, even though incidental benefits might accrue
to the union. Under such conditions, the union fairly could
Page 325 U. S. 821
be said to be aiding and abetting a violation of the Act, and
its immunity would be lost. The facts of this case, however, do not
allow such conclusions to be drawn.
I would therefore affirm the judgment of the court below.