1. The restrictions of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act are aimed
against such restraints of interstate commerce as are unreasonable.
P.
297 U. S.
597.
2. The Act does not forbid cooperative adoption by competitors
of reasonable means to protect their trade from injurious practices
and to promote competition on a sound basis, and such legitimate
cooperation is not limited to the removal of evils which are in
themselves infractions of positive law. P.
297 U. S.
598.
3. The mere fact that correction of abuses in a business by
cooperative action of those competing in it may tend to stabilize
the business, or to produce fairer price levels, does not stamp
their action as unreasonable restraint of trade. P.
297 U. S.
598.
4. But concerted action which produces unreasonable restraint
cannot be justified by pointing to evils affecting the industry or
to a laudable purpose to remove them. P.
297 U. S.
599.
5. While the collection and dissemination of trade statistics
are in themselves permissible, and may be a useful adjunct of fair
commerce, a combination to gather and supply information as part of
a plan to impose unwarrantable restrictions on competition, as, for
example, to curtail production and raise prices, is unlawful. P.
297 U. S.
599.
6. In applying the Sherman Act, each case demands a close
scrutiny of its own facts, and questions of reasonableness are
necessarily questions of relation and degree. P.
297 U. S.
600.
7. Fifteen companies, which refined nearly all of the imported
raw cane sugar processed in this country and supplied from 70 to
80% of the refined sugar consumed in it, formed a trade
association, called The Sugar Institute, ostensibly for the purpose
of doing away with unfair merchandizing practices, especially the
granting of secret concessions and rebates to customers, which had
grown up in the trade. They agreed that all discriminations between
customers should be abolished, and, to that end, that each company
should publicly announce in advance its prices, terms, and
conditions of sale and adhere to them strictly until it publicly
changed them. They also agreed upon a number of supplementary
restrictions (which are considered in detail in this opinion),
among which were
Page 297 U. S. 554
(a) restrictions on the employment of brokers and warehousemen
(
infra, 297 U. S.
587); (b) restrictions concerning transportation,
absorption of freight charges, etc. (
infra, 297 U. S.
589); (e) limitation of the number of consignment points
at which sugar was placed for distribution to surrounding areas and
limitation of ports of entry to be used (
infra,
297 U. S.
591); (d) prohibition of long-term contracts and
restriction of quantity discounts on sales to customers
(
infra, 297 U. S.
593); (e) withholding from the purchasing trade of part
of the statistical information collected by the Institute for its
members and not otherwise available (
infra, 297 U. S.
596). Owing to the position of these refiners in the
sugar industry, maintenance of competition between them was a
matter of serious public concern, and, since refined sugar is a
highly standardized product, that competition must relate mainly to
prices, terms, and conditions of sales. The strong tendency toward
uniformity of price resulting from the uniformity of the commodity
made it the more important that such opportunities as existed for
fair competition should not be impaired.
Held:
(1) The agreement and supporting requirements went beyond the
removal of admitted abuses and imposed unreasonable restraints. P.
297 U. S.
601.
(2) The vice of the agreement was not in the mere open
announcement in advance of prices and terms -- a custom previously
existing which had grown out of the special character of the
industry and did not restrain competition -- nor in the relaying of
such announcements, but in the steps taken to secure undeviating
adherence to the prices and terms announced, whereby opportunities
for variation in the course of competition, however fair and
appropriate, were cut off. P.
297 U. S.
601.
(3) In ending the restraint, the beneficial and curative agency
of publicity should not be unnecessarily hampered; publicity of
prices and terms should not be confined to closed transactions; if
the requirement that there must be adherence to prices and terms
openly announced in advance be abrogated and the restraints which
followed that requirement be removed, the just interests of
competition will be safeguarded, and the trade will still be left
with whatever advantage may be incidental to its established
practice. P.
297 U. S.
601.
(4) The refiners should be enjoined from gathering and
disseminating among themselves exclusively statistical information
which is not readily, fully, and fairly available to the purchasing
and distributing trade, and in which that trade has a legitimate
interest,
Page 297 U. S. 555
but the command should not be so broad as to include information
in relation to the affairs of refiners which may rightly be treated
as having a confidential character and in which distributors and
purchasers have no proper interest. P.___.
15 F. Supp.
817 modified and affirmed.
Appeal from a decree of injunction in a suit by the Government
under the Anti-Trust Act. The bill named as defendants an
incorporated trade association called The Sugar Institute, the
fifteen sugar refining corporations composing it, and various
individuals. The decree below did not dissolve the Institute, as
was prayed, but permanently enjoined the defendants from engaging
in forty-five stated activities found to be in restraint of
competition in the sugar trade.
Page 297 U. S. 570
MR. CHIEF JUSTICE HUGHES delivered the opinion of the Court.
This suit was brought to dissolve the Sugar Institute, Inc., a
trade association, and to restrain the sugar refining companies
which composed it, and the individual defendants, from engaging in
an alleged conspiracy in restraint
Page 297 U. S. 571
of interstate and foreign commerce in violation of the Sherman
Anti-Trust Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1. Final decree was entered which,
while it did not dissolve the Institute, permanently enjoined the
defendants from engaging directly or indirectly in forty-five
stated activities. Defendants bring a direct appeal to this Court
under the Act of February 11, 1903, 15 U.S.C. § 29.
The record is unusually voluminous. [
Footnote 1] The court rendered an exhaustive opinion and
made detailed findings of fact (218 in number), with conclusions of
law, describing and characterizing the transactions involved.
Numerous assignments of error broadly challenge its rulings, and
the case has been presented here in extended oral arguments and
elaborate briefs. We shall attempt to deal only with the salient
and controlling points of the controversy. These involve (1) the
special characteristics of the sugar industry and the practices
which obtained before the organization of the Sugar Institute, (2)
the purposes for which the Institute was founded, (3) the agreement
and practices of the members of the Institute, and (4) the
application of the Anti-Trust And and the provisions of the
decree.
First. The sugar industry and practices prior to the
formation of the Sugar Institute. Domestic refined sugar, beet
sugar, and foreign and insular refined sugar, known in the trade as
"off-shore" refined, constitute about 99 percent of the nation's
supply. The remainder, consisting of domestic cane sugar, refined
particularly in Louisiana, does not appear to be an important
factor in the national markets. The fifteen defendant companies,
members of the Institute, refine practically all the imported
Page 297 U. S. 572
raw sugar processed in this country. Their product is known as
"domestic refined." Prior to the organization of the Institute in
1927, they provided more than 80 percent of the sugar consumed in
the United States, and they have since supplied from 70 to 80
percent. Their proportion of the supply is even greater in the New
England and Middle Atlantic States, being more than 90 percent,
while, in all but a few states, their share is more than 55
percent. Each of the refiners is engaged extensively in interstate
commerce. Their refineries are in the vicinity of Boston, New York,
Philadelphia, Baltimore, Savannah, New Orleans, Galveston, and San
Francisco. The raw cane sugar which they use is imported
principally from Cuba, and, to some extent, from the insular
possessions.
Beet sugar for many years has been an important factor in the
domestic market. It is produced and sold chiefly in the middle and
far West, providing in some states over 75 percent of the supply,
and it competes with other sugars in a number of Southern and
Middle Atlantic States. Off-shore sugar is refined principally in
Cuba and to some extent in the insular possessions. Its important
trade areas have been the Middle, Atlantic, and Southern States; in
some states, it constitutes from 25 to 40 percent of the total
supply. Both beet sugar and off-shore sugar are sold at a small
differential below defendants' sugar. The trial court found that
there was no agreement between defendants and the beet sugar
manufacturers, or with the off-shore interests, to maintain any
differential.
The court found that the defendants' refined can sugar "is a
thoroughly standardized commodity in physical and chemical
properties." In exceptional cases and localities, certain of the
defendants had built up a preference for brand names
"sufficient before and after the Institute was organized to
enable such brands to command a higher
Page 297 U. S. 573
price than the sugar of the other defendants in sales from sugar
dealers to their trade."
In sales by refiners to manufacturers of products containing
sugar -- about one-third of the sugar consumed -- "price, not
brand, was always the vital consideration." And in the other
sales,
"one refiner could not ordinarily, by virtue of preference for
his brand, obtain a higher price except insofar as another refiner
might be giving a lower price by secret concessions."
The court further found that the "basis prices" [
Footnote 2] quoted by the several refiners in
any particular trade area
"were generally uniform, both before and after the Institute,
because economically the defendants' sugar, save for exceptional
instances, was and is a thoroughly standardized product."
It is a fundamental and earnest contention of defendants that
the occasion for the formation of the Institute was the existence
of grossly unfair and uneconomical practices in the trade, and that
a proper appraisal of the motives and transactions of defendants
cannot be made without full appreciation of the sorry condition
into which the industry had fallen.
During the years 1917 to 1919, when the industry was under
governmental control, prices were fixed, and all forms of
concessions and rebates were forbidden. The court found that,
perhaps as early as 1921 and increasingly thereafter, the practice
developed on the part of some, but not all, refiners of giving
secret concessions. There were five refiners [
Footnote 3] who never indulged in that
practice,
Page 297 U. S. 574
but the others, called "unethical" refiners, did so to such an
extent that at least 30 percent of all the sugar sold by the
refiners in 1927 carried secret concessions of some kind. The need
of secrecy was urgent, for, as soon as it was known that a specific
concession was granted, it would be generally demanded. That
concessions were widely granted was generally known in the trade,
and while each refiner was able to find out in a general way the
approximate prices and terms of his competitors, it was impossible
to know with any degree of accuracy the actual prices and terms
granted in the innumerable transactions. The court also found that
various causes contributed to the development of these selling
methods on the part of the unethical refiners, chief among which
was an overcapacity since the war of at least 30 percent. Other
probable causes were the lack of statistical information as to
amount of production, deliveries, and stocks on hand, leading to
overproduction, the uncertainties prevailing in the market for raw
sugar which made the refined sugar industry highly speculative, the
fact that, since 1922, most sugar has been sold through brokers,
and the standardization of defendants' products, which made their
sales almost entirely dependent upon prices, terms, and conditions.
The concessions granted were largely, although not entirely,
arbitrary. They were given principally to large buyers, but no
system was followed in that respect. Even though there may not have
been extensive resort to misrepresentations,
"defendants entertained genuine fears that purchasers were
falsely representing prices which they said they could procure from
competing sellers."
Consumption of sugar in the United States decreased in 1927. The
public "slimness campaign" of that year had substantial effect in
discouraging the use of sugar. Certain distributors refrained from
pushing sales because they could not sell profitably, but others
were aggressive,
Page 297 U. S. 575
and sugar was generally available. While certain smaller
distributors suffered because of the advantage enjoyed by some
larger ones, that advantage was attributable in the greatest
measure to efficiency, and the larger distributors did not obtain
monopolies. The court found that there was "no substantial evidence
that the situation caused, or would cause, substantial injury to
the
ethical' refiners as a class," although they may have been
inconvenienced and probably believed that the sales methods of
their competitors were harmful. The declining profits for the year
1927 were attributable, at least in large part, the court found, to
causes other than the secret concession system, such as the
"slimness campaign," overproduction, and dumping.
But, whatever question there may be as to particulars, the
evidence and findings leave no doubt that the industry was in a
demoralized state which called for remedial measures. The court
summed up the facts in the following finding:
"29. The industry was characterized by highly unfair and
otherwise uneconomic competitive conditions, arbitrary, secret
rebates and concessions were extensively granted by the majority of
the companies in most of the important market areas, and the
widespread knowledge of the market conditions necessary for
intelligent, fair competition were lacking. The refiners were
disturbed economically and morally over the then prevailing
conditions. At least one refiner, American, [
Footnote 4] was concerned about the possibility of
liability under the Clayton Act because of the discriminations
resulting from the various concessions."
Second. The purposes for which the Institute was
founded. Defendants emphasize the nature of the proceedings
taken in the formation of the Institute. The
Page 297 U. S. 576
court found that the refiners held a series of meetings,
beginning in the summer of 1927, for a discussion of conditions
"with particular reference to undesirable practices and secret
concessions." In September of that year, there was submitted to the
Department of Justice a proposed certificate of incorporation and
bylaws for a trade association, together with a number of
suggestions respecting trade practices. A "Code of Ethics" was
likewise submitted to the Department of Justice and discussed with
its officials, with the result that some changes were made, and the
Code as concertedly adopted in January, 1928, was substantially
identical with that worked out when those discussions were held.
The court found that, "with the exception of two minor changes, the
Code has retained its original form." It has been supplemented from
time to time by "Interpretations" -- that is, rulings interpreting
or amplifying the provisions of the Code. The Department of Justice
made three investigations of the Institute in 1928, 1929, and 1930,
and had complete access to the files of the Institute. As new
issues of the "Code" and "Interpretations" were printed, copies
were forwarded to the Department.
Defendants stress their dealings with the Department of Justice
as evidence of their good faith and of the propriety and legality
of their purposes. "The functionings of the Institute," they
insist, "were always under the eye of the Department." The court,
however, found that the Department "was not notified of various
important steps taken by the Institute in connection with illegal
restraints," nor was it notified "as to those activities charged by
the Government and denied by defendants in this case." The
Department did not conduct a comprehensive investigation of the
restraints here involved until the end of 1930.
Defendants urge that the abolition of the vicious and
discriminatory system of secret concessions, through the
Page 297 U. S. 577
adoption of the principle of open prices publicly announced,
without discrimination, was their dominant purpose in forming the
Institute, and that other purposes were the supplying of accurate
trade statistics, the elimination of wasteful practices, the
creation of a credit bureau, and the institution of an advertising
campaign. The court recognized the existence of these purposes in
its finding:
"35. Among the purposes of the defendants in organizing the
Institute were: (a) the selling of sugar on open, publicly
announced prices, terms, and conditions; (b) the gathering of trade
statistics not previously available; (c) the elimination of
practices which they deemed wasteful, and (d) the institution of an
advertising campaign to increase consumption. But these purposes
were for the most part only incidental to defendants' actual
dominant purposes in forming and operating under the
Institute."
The "dominant purposes" were found to be as follows:
"36. I find that defendants' dominant purposes in organizing the
Institute were: to create and maintain a uniform price structure,
thereby eliminating and suppressing price competition among
themselves and other competitors; to maintain relatively high
prices for refined, as compared with contemporary prices of raw,
sugar; to improve their own financial position by limiting and
suppressing numerous contract terms and conditions, and to make as
certain as possible that no secret concessions should be granted.
In their efforts to accomplish these purposes, defendants have
ignored the interests of distributors and consumers of sugar."
Defendants charge that the finding as to the illegality of their
dominant purposes was "wholly without foundation." They charge that
the finding was built upon an "inherent suspicion," and not upon
the evidence. The Government answers by pointing to the elaborate
review
Page 297 U. S. 578
of the evidence in the court's opinion and findings. We think
that it is manifest that the findings as to dominant purposes was
not based upon any assumption
a priori, but was an
inference of fact which the court drew from the facts it deemed to
be established with respect to the scope of the agreement between
the members of the Institute and the actual nature and effect of
their concerted action. The court found that the defendants, "in
most of their activities," had
"gone much further than was reasonably necessary to accomplish
their professed aims of eliminating fraud, waste and secret,
unfair, or illegal discrimination."
The pith of the matter is in the following finding:
"37. At the inception of the Institute, defendants adopted a
general agreement, ostensibly to abolish all discriminations
between customers, but which, in general purpose and effect,
amounted to an agreement not to afford different treatment to
different customers, regardless of the varying circumstances of
particular transactions or classes of transactions and regardless
of the varying situation of particular refiners, distributors, or
customers or classes thereof. Under the guise of performing the
agreement against discriminations, defendants limited and
suppressed numerous important contract terms and conditions in the
particulars herein set forth, chiefly for the purpose and with the
effect of accomplishing the objectives described in finding
36."
We turn to the transactions from which the inference of purpose
is drawn.
Third. The agreement and practices of the members of the
Institute. The evidence consists of the "Code of Ethics" and
"Interpretations," oral testimony, the minutes of the Institute,
and correspondence. Eliminating charges not sustained, the findings
of restraints of trade rest upon the basic agreement of the
refiners to
Page 297 U. S. 579
sell only upon prices and terms openly announced, and upon
certain supplementary restrictions.
1.
The "basic agreement." The "Code of Ethics" provided
as follows:
"All discriminations between customers should be abolished. To
that end, sugar should be sold only upon open prices and terms
publicly announced."
There was nothing new in the mere advance announcement of
prices. The court found that, prior to the Institute,
"general price changes were listed on the Refiners' Bulletin
Boards, and brokers, customers and news agencies were notified, and
frequently, as a courtesy, competitors would be telephoned. Except
for notifying the Institute, price changes during the
post-Institute period have been announced in this way. . . . Before
the Institute, general price changes, including general changes in
the selling bases of the 'unethical' refiners, were disseminated
and became known to the entire trade very quickly."
These price announcements must be considered in the light of the
trade practice known as "moves." The great bulk of sugar, as the
court found,
"always was and is purchased on what is known in the trade as
'moves,' although very substantial quantities are sold from time to
time apart from moves."
A "move" takes place when the refiners make public announcements
that, at a fixed time, they will advance their selling price to a
named figure, either higher than the presently current selling
price or higher than a reduced price which the announcements offer
before the advance. Some period of grace was always allowed during
which sugar could be bought at the price prevailing before the
advance. And, in order to obtain their sugar at the lower price,
the trade, unless it was felt that the move occurred at too high a
price, would then enter into contracts covering their needs for
Page 297 U. S. 580
at least the next thirty days. Defendants point out that, in
actual practice, the initial announcements might be made by any one
of the refiners, and that the move actually takes place only if all
refiners follow a similar course. If anyone fails to follow with a
like announcement, the others must withdraw their advance, since
sugar is a completely standardized commodity.
Under the system of the Institute, there was no obligation to
give the Institute the first notice of a change in price. The open
announcements to the trade were to be made in the customary manner
and notified to the Institute, which would relay the announcements.
Prior to the Institute, when an advance in price was announced, the
period of grace allowed for purchasing at the old price was
uncertain. Sometimes it was very short -- a matter of hours;
sometimes sugar buyers who did not learn of the move in time sent
their orders in too late to buy at the old price. By an
"interpretation," the Institute recommended that the members
"announce changes in price not later than three o'clock." In its
earlier form, this hour was to be that "of the day before the
changed price becomes effective." But these words were deleted in
1929, and thereafter the announced price advances could be made
effective at once. In practice, however, price advances continued
to be announced to become effective the following day or even
later. The court found that the effect of the "Three o'clock Rule,"
in and of itself, "seems to have been advantageous to the trade in
case of a price advance in that the uncertain period of grace has
been replaced by a definite one."
The court further found that the refiners
"did not consult with one another after an advance had been
announced by one of them, and that the grace period was not in fact
used by them to persuade a reluctant member to follow the example
set, despite the business necessity of withdrawing an advance
unless it were followed by
Page 297 U. S. 581
all."
The court found
"no agreement among defendants on basis prices in the sense of
an agreement to adopt a certain basis price from time to time and
to maintain it during any period. Frequently an announcement by one
refiner of an advance would result in a series of announcements by
others, ultimately leading to a decline. Often, too, the advance
would be withdrawn because one refiner would refrain from following
the announcement. Except in a few instances, a decline announcement
was followed by all."
"Data respecting price changes have been circulated by the
Institute without comment," and there appear to have been no "price
discussions" at Institute meetings.
There had been a practice in the trade called "repricing" -- of
"making price declines retroactive to sales made at previous higher
price." That occurred usually when a decline was announced late in
the day and was applied to all of that day's business. The court
found that, during the first few months of the Institute,
defendants attempted to prevent repricing, but the prohibition
proved impracticable, and was abandoned. By a ruling in November,
1928, it was provided that
"the custom of the trade permits the customer the benefit of the
refiner's lowest price during the day -- that is, a contract
entered into or sugar delivered in the morning may be repriced at
any lower price announced during the day."
The court, in its finding on this point, stated that the ruling
was evidently intended to prevent repricing beyond the period
stated, and "must have had some effect in discouraging it."
Defendants challenge this criticism in view of the fact also found
that refiners occasionally have repriced beyond the stated period,
a practice which defendants say "had never prevailed in the
pre-Institute period," and defendants insist that what the Code
actually did was
"to insure that repricing should be done publicly, with the
benefit extended to all customers alike,
Page 297 U. S. 582
and not done secretly for the benefit only of the
concessionaries."
The distinctive feature of the "basic agreement" was not the
advance announcement of prices, or a concert to maintain any
particular basis price for any period, but a requirement of
adherence, without deviation, to the prices and terms publicly
announced. Prior to the Institute, the list prices which many of
the "unethical" refiners announced
"were merely nominal quotations and bore no relation to the
actual 'selling bases' at which their sugar was sold. . . . The
selling price was the price at which they purported to sell; the
secret concessions were from this basis."
And, in the case of some of the "unethical" refiners, changes in
selling bases were made from time to time without formal public
announcement in advance. The Institute sought to prevent such
departures. As defendants put it:
"Having adopted the principle of open prices and terms, without
discrimination among customers, as the means of remedying the evils
of the secret concession system, the defendants lived up to the
principle."
The court found:
"40. Under the Institute, defendants agreed to sell, and in
general did sell sugar only upon open prices, terms and conditions
publicly announced in advance of sales, and they agreed to adhere
and in general did adhere without deviation, to such prices, terms
and conditions until they publicly announced changes."
It was because of the range and effect of this restriction, and
the consequent deprivation of opportunity to make special
arrangements, that the court found that the agreement and the
course of action under it constituted an unreasonable restraint of
trade. The court deemed it to be reasonably certain that "any
unfair method of competition caused by the secret concession
system" could have been prevented by "immediate
Page 297 U. S. 583
publicity given to the prices, terms, and conditions in all
closed transactions," without an agreement to sell only on the
basis "of open public announcement in advance of sales." A "purpose
and effect" of that agreement, the court found, was to aid
defendants in preventing and limiting "certain types of
transactions in which private negotiations are essential." Its
operation "tended in fact as it naturally would tend, toward
maintenance of price levels relatively high as compared with
raws."
The court found that "the number of price changes for refined as
compared to raw sugar" had been relatively less since the Institute
than before. This was "too marked to be explained by the drop in
raw prices." There was "a marked increase in margin and a
substantial increase in profits despite a concededly large excess
capacity." The relatively higher price level for the refined sugar,
as compared with raw, was such "as to negate the prevalence of free
competition." Factors "largely responsible" for this relative
stability of prices "and for the maintenance of price levels
regardless of supply and demand, observable since the Institute,"
were the dissemination among the refiners of statistical
information, "while withholding it in large part from the buyers,"
and the steps taken by defendants
"to eliminate the possibilities of price various to distributors
or ultimate purchasers at any given time and thereby to deprive
them of the opportunity, by underselling, to disturb the price
structure."
Other factors were "the friendly cooperative spirit which the
Institute brought to the Industry" and the assurance to each
refiner that he need meet only the prices, terms, and conditions
announced by his competitors in advance of sales.
The court also took note of the fact that the Institute, in
connection with practically all of its activities, had
Page 297 U. S. 584
obtained a high degree of cooperation" with the Domestic Sugar
Bureau," the trade association of the domestic beet sugar
manufacturers. That association had its "Code of Ethics,"
substantially identical with that of the Institute. There was also
cooperation with the "offshore interests." But in neither case was
there any agreement as to prices or price differentials.
Contending that the trial court fell into "fundamental error,"
defendants assert that the Institute made no change in the historic
marketing system of the sugar industry. They say, first, that the
code and its interpretations did not in terms call for price
announcements in advance of sales. As to sales on "moves," they say
that the code principle and price announcement interpretations
"of course worked out in actual practice into sales only on
prices and terms announced in advance of sales, because of the very
nature and conditions of a sugar move."
As to the "small day-to-day sales between moves," they say that,
while it was probably "the general understanding" that strict
observance of the principle required public announcements of a
lowered price or better terms before sale, there was no evidence as
to the actual practice in that regard. They explain that the
Institute continued to operate "under the move system" because it
is "a natural growth essential to the economical conduct of the
sugar business." The cost of raw sugar makes up about four-fifths
of the cost of the refined sugar. Raw prices fluctuate widely from
day to day, and substantially control the price of refined.
Wholesale and retail distributors sell on a narrow margin of 5 or
10 cents a bag. They cannot afford to stock large supplies because
of storage costs, dangers of deterioration, and the hazardous
nature of the business. But, on the other hand, distributors have
to buy considerable quantities in order to take advantage of
carload freight rates and handling costs. The result of all these
forces is the system "of buying on
Page 297 U. S. 585
moves every month or two." To this, both large and small dealers
have adapted themselves. By reason of the general practice, they
are all on an equal footing as to the periodic fluctuations in
price. On each move, they have laid in a supply for a month or
more. Having bought their current supplies at the same general
market level, the distributors must "sell out their current
supplies with due regard to that level in order to avoid crippling
losses from an intervening decline." This, defendants say, is "one
of the greatest economic advantages of the move system."
Defendants concede the correctness of the statement of the trial
court that, if immediate publicity had been given to prices and
terms in all "closed transactions," competitive pressure would have
been so great that the refiners "would either have had to abandon
the discriminatory concessions or extend them to all." They concede
that it is "
publicity" that prevents such concessions, and
"not the sequence in time between the sale and the publicity." But
they raise the fundamental objection that the proposal is not
adaptable to the sugar industry. They say that, in an industry
which
"has traditionally, and for good reason, sold its products on
'moves,' through the mechanism of announcing price changes in
advance of sales in order that buyers may have an opportunity to
buy before the price rises, it is not helpful to suggest a system
of announcing price changes
after sales."
Defendants' argument on this point is a forcible one, but we
need not follow it through in detail. For the question, as we have
seen, is not really with respect to the practice of making price
announcements in advance of sales, but as to defendants'
requirement of adherence to such announcements without the
deviations which open and fair competition might require or
justify. The court below did not condemn mere open price
announcements in advance of sales. The court was careful to say
Page 297 U. S. 586
in its opinion that it found it "unnecessary to pass upon the
legality of the use of the Institute" for relaying such
announcements, "if each refiner, entirely independently of the
others, voluntarily made his own announcements without obligation
to adhere thereto."
Defendants also review at length the relative prices and profits
in the periods before and during the Institute. They insist that it
is unfair to include in the comparison the earnings for either 1927
or 1928, because each year was abnormal, and they contend that, if
a truly representative comparison of results were obtained by using
the years 1925 and 1926 as the pre-Institute years, and those for
1929 and 1930, as the post-Institute years, it would appear that
the increase in the later period of the net earnings of the
refiners was less than one-half of one percent. Accordingly, they
reach the conclusion that their activities did not actually
restrain, or tend to restrain, effective competition.
But we are not left to inferences from trends of prices and
profits. The "basic agreement" cannot be divorced from the steps
taken to make it effective, and the requirements of the Institute
must be viewed in the light of the particular opportunities which
they cut off or curtailed. The crucial question -- whether, in the
ostensible effort to prevent unfair competition, the resources of
fair competition have been impaired -- is presented not abstractly,
but in connection with various concrete restrictions to which the
decree below was addressed.
2.
Supplementary restrictions. The requirements and
practices designed to support the basic agreement, and which the
trial court condemned, relate to the employment of brokers and
warehousemen, transportation, consignment points, long-term
contracts, quantity discounts, and other contract terms and
conditions, and to the withholding of statistical information.
Page 297 U. S. 587
(a)
Brokers and warehousemen. Most of defendants' sales
are negotiated through brokers who receive their commissions from
the refiners. The court found that, prior to the Institute, a
broker and a warehouseman "were frequently one," and might also be
"a merchant or other sugar user;" that concerns which thus combined
distribution functions frequently performed a valuable service to
the industry; that defendants required an election of but one of
these activities and the complete cessation of each of the others;
that defendants made and rigorously enforced an agreement that
refiners should refuse to deal with a broker, warehouseman, or
customer who acted directly or indirectly for any of them, or for
any other sugar interest, "in other than the one elected capacity;"
that each refiner submitted to the Institute lists of its brokers
and warehouses, which were then circulated among the refiners, and
those disqualified were dropped from the lists; that this policy
was carried out in a harsh and arbitrary manner without regard to
the effect upon third parties; that the commissions to be paid
brokers were agreed upon, but there was no substantial evidence
that the commissions were not fair, the object being to prevent a
growing competition in bidding for brokers' services; that
defendants agreed that they would not deal with any broker or
warehouseman who did not sign a contract according to a form
recommended by the Institute; that the warehouse agreement provided
that, if the warehouseman granted any concession or rebate, secret
or otherwise, to any customer without granting it to all, an equal
amount should be forfeited to the employing refiner; that the
brokers' agreement prohibited concessions and imposed an obligation
to uphold the Institute's code and its interpretations. This course
of dealing, the court held, unreasonably restrained trade.
Defendants urge that the broker is the refiner's agent to sell
to customers, and the warehouseman is the refiner's
Page 297 U. S. 588
agent for storage and delivery; that these agents act as a check
on each other; that the refiners' concerted adoption of the
principle against storing in customers' and brokers' warehouses was
essential both to prevent discrimination among customers and to
avoid impositions and frauds upon the refiners; that, if the
warehouseman is himself the purchaser of the sugar, the refiner is
deprived of his independence and disinterestedness and the
purchaser has control of the sugar with the power of withdrawing it
at will and reporting that withdrawal at his pleasure; that,
similarly, storage with brokers facilitated fraudulent practices,
and that, where the warehouseman and the broker were the same,
neither was under any supervision, and the broker-warehouseman
could do practically what he pleased with the refiner's property
and business.
To a considerable degree, the court recognized the force of
these contentions. The court found that a combination of
distribution functions facilitated secret concessions, difficult of
detection, and created opportunities for double dealing. But,
despite this, it had been common for refiners, before the
Institute, to employ brokers and warehousemen engaged in other
distribution functions, and that such arrangements, from the
refiners' viewpoint, were not infrequently entirely successful, and
that concerns in substantial numbers, which combined distribution
functions, maintained entire good faith in their dealings with the
refiners. The court concluded that there was a definite possibility
of lower prices to ultimate consumers as a result of combination of
functions, because the increased income thus made possible, even
apart from advantages obtained through secret concessions and
fraudulent practices, gave opportunity "to outsell competitors who
engage in only one occupation." The most important purpose of
defendants, the court found, in compelling the separation of
occupations was to aid in preserving "the uniformity of price
structure," which would
Page 297 U. S. 589
otherwise be threatened. The court deemed it reasonably certain
that defendants could have secured adequate protection against
illicit practices by means far less drastic -- that is, through
investigations, inspections, and publicity -- for which the
Institute had unlimited resources.
The finding of purpose and of the adequacy of alternative
measures is sharply contested. But, while the parties present their
respective views as to the details of evidence, there is no room
for doubt as to the nature and effect of the restrictions actually
imposed through the Institute. The findings of the court as to
agreement and practice are fully supported.
(b)
Transportation. The custom of the trade was to
quote sugar f.o.b. refinery. Since the price was usually the same
or varied but slightly, individual refiners sold in areas enjoying
lower freight rates from other refineries by paying or absorbing
part of the transportation charges. That is, the refiner added to
the refinery price the amount of his "ruling freight basis" or
"freight application," which was the amount the customer was to
pay, as distinguished from the actual cost of the transportation.
The freight situation was complicated by the existence of
differential routes, involving all-water or a combination of water
and rail transportation. Traditionally in the industry, refiners'
freight applications on sugar delivered at Great Lakes ports openly
broke down during the season of open navigation to the Philadelphia
lake and rail rate, and, during 1926 and 1927, the freight
application on sugar sold in the Warrior River area (Alabama,
Tennessee, Kentucky, and parts of Indiana) had openly broken down
to New Orleans barge rates, regardless of the way in which the
sugar actually moved. The areas affected by these breakdowns were
of vital importance, as competition there was especially keen.
In the effort to prevent the "sale" of transportation below
"cost," the Code of Ethics, paragraph 3(c), condemned
Page 297 U. S. 590
"the use of differential rates on consignments, or otherwise
than on direct shipments over differential routes at customers'
request." This policy was amplified by an interpretation. The trial
court found that but "slight effort was made to enforce Code 3(c)
after the summer of 1928," that it "was abandoned at least by the
fall of 1929 ,and probably much earlier," and that the code
interpretation was finally rescinded in September, 1930.
The court found that the transportation problems in the Great
Lakes and Warrior River areas were finally solved by a system of
delivered prices, with denial of the privilege of purchasing f.o.b.
refinery. The court did not find that there was an agreement in
introducing the delivered prices, but did find that defendants
"agreed to maintain and concertedly maintained the system of
delivered prices" in both the areas above mentioned; also that,
through the Institute, defendants "concertedly policed delivered
prices and investigated alleged departures therefrom;" and that
these prices were "patently unreasonable." Defendants vigorously
deny that delivered prices were either introduced or maintained
through any concert of action. They submit that the evidence not
only does not warrant that finding, but shows affirmatively that
delivered prices were introduced independently by individual
refiners, and resulted solely from unrestrained competition.
As the court said in its opinion, the controversy was chiefly
about what defendants had actually done during the Institute
period, and the facts were frequently "bitterly disputed." We need
not discuss the rival contentions. The court found that
defendants'
"adoption of Code 3(c), their actions pursuant thereto, and
their concerted maintenance of delivered prices constituted undue
and unreasonable restraint of trade."
Defendants have waived their assignment of error as to this
finding in
Page 297 U. S. 591
order to reduce the issues presented on this appeal. And
defendants have also waived their assignments of error as to the
provisions in the decree enjoining concerted action in "determining
transportation charges or freight applications to be collected from
customers, or limiting freight absorptions" and in "selling only on
delivered prices or on any system of delivered prices, including
zone prices, or refusing to sell f.o.b. refinery."
Questions are presented with respect to miscellaneous
"transportation activities." They relate to defendants' agreement
to prevent transiting and diversion by customers when these would
defeat freight applications; to concerted action in obtaining an
agreement from transportation companies operating on the New York
State Barge Canal that they would carry sugar only on the basis of
openly announced rates and terms from which they would not deviate
without open announcement; to recommendations of the Institute,
concertedly observed, that none of the members should ship sugar on
his own account by private charter except when the charter was
arranged directly between refiner and carrier and refiner was
satisfied that no broker, buyer, or warehouseman was participating
in the rate, and that the terms of every such private charter
should be submitted to the scrutiny of the executive secretary of
the Institute; to defendants' concerted refusal to participate in
pool shipments, with sugar shipped on their own account, in order
to aid customers in making up the required minima for cargo or
carload rates, and to defendants' agreement "to use only trucking
concerns not affiliated with any buyer, broker, or warehouse and
then only under nonrebating contracts." The court found that
defendants' action went further than was necessary to prevent
secret rebating, and amounted to unreasonable restraints. We see no
reason for disturbing the findings on these subjects.
(c)
Consignment points. Prior to 1925, the refiners
maintained, on their respective accounts, stocks at
Page 297 U. S. 592
a few strategic points from which sugar was distributed to the
surrounding areas. During the period 1925 to 1927, refiners placed
stocks at numerous points solely for the local trade. Defendants
regarded this increase as an outstanding evil, and made a concerted
effort to bring about reductions. To this end, the Institute
obtained the cooperation of the Domestic Sugar Bureau and other
nonmembers. In recommending consignment points in the South, ports
of entry like reconsignment points were separately classified, and
Wilmington, N.C. was eliminated.
Defendants insist that the expense involved in maintaining an
excessive number of consignment points was an economic waste
without any substantial compensating advantage to the consuming
public, and that the effort at reduction was a legitimate function
of the Institute. The economic questions were fully considered by
the trial court, which found that the refiners' consignment service
"was valuable and beneficial to substantial elements in the trade;"
that limitation of ports of entry was more serious than elimination
of ordinary consignment points insofar as it shut a competitor out
of a particular territory; that, while the cost of increased
consignment points might well be reflected in a higher general
basis price, there was no assurance that the savings through some
reductions would be passed on to consumers generally; that the
result in either case was "largely speculative;" that communities
eliminated as consignment points "suffered as against neighboring
ones" because of the advantage accruing to the latter, and that
there were also eliminated from distributing agencies one type of
jobber called the "desk jobber," who was able to do business
without any stock of his own. In summary, the court found that
defendants' "concerted conduct with respect to elimination and
reduction of consignment points, reconsignment points and ports of
entry" unreasonably restrained
Page 297 U. S. 593
trade. The controlling facts are established, and the question
again is one of justification.
(d)
Various contract terms and conditions. One question
relates to "
long-term contracts" -- that is, those
permitting the buyer to take delivery more than thirty days after
date. Prior to the World War, thirty-day contracts were customary
for all except manufacturers, who were granted sixty days. While
there was no definite practice after the war, long-term contracts
were not infrequent. They were granted by California refiners to
Pacific Coast canners. The court found that long-term contracts had
"a real economic value to refiner and to consumer;" that some of
them tend to bring about greater evenness of production through the
year, thus effectuating economics and enabling manufacturers
promptly to know the cost of this element of their finished
products.
Defendants contest the finding of the court that they engaged in
concerted action "in prohibiting all long-term contracts," and
assert that "they never have had and do not now have any desire to
prohibit them." Hence, they add, the court's injunction against
such action "does not disturb them." But they object to the finding
that concerted action in insisting upon open announcement in
advance of entering into such contracts was without justification.
This, as defendants say, is but a condemnation of a particular
application of their basic principle that sugar should be sold only
upon open prices and terms without discrimination. In the view of
the trial court, this application is an illustration of its point
that an obligation to adhere to such advance announcements "would
tend to prevent many entirely fair contracts." Of similar import is
the finding that defendants were not justified in acting
concertedly to determine whether and to what extent "the rigid
enforcement of the thirty day contract" should be relaxed.
Page 297 U. S. 594
Another question which has received extended consideration is
that of "
quantity discounts." Prior to the Institute,
there was no systematic practice in this respect. The majority of
discounts were given to the large buyer, but they were often
granted to the smaller buyer as well, and the amount of the
discount "bore little relation to the amount of the purchases or
the method of taking delivery." This, the court found, was the
natural result of the "secret concession system" which had
prevailed. Carrying out its policy as to discriminations, the
Institute condemned "as unbusinesslike, uneconomic and unsound,
concessions made to purchasers on the basis of quantity purchased."
The court found that this agreement and the practice under it
prohibited not only "unsystematic and secret quantity discounts,"
but also discounts "systematically graded according to quantity."
The court examined defendants' contention that quantity discounts
would effect no economics. If, said the court, the facts were as
defendants insisted, the question would arise whether such a
concerted restraint was reasonable. But the court considered the
actual facts to be "entirely inconsistent with defendants'
position." As to direct costs, the court found that the refiners
got no discount for quantity purchases of raws, which constitute
about 80 percent of the cost of refined; that quantity sales
effected no appreciable direct savings in manufacturing costs and
no savings in brokerage; but that, in sales to those who could take
deliveries in carload lots direct from the refinery, there were
substantial savings "in delivery, storage, bookkeeping, and other
incidental expenses." And as to indirect costs, the court found
that sales which distribute production more evenly through the year
effect substantial savings to the refiners, and that the demand for
sugar is elastic, so that encouragement of large sales through
quantity discounts might reasonably be expected to build up total
production, and thus effect economies.
Page 297 U. S. 595
Also, that a quantity discount to wholesalers selling to
manufacturers, as well as to manufacturers buying directly from
refiners, might well result in a substantial increase in sugar
consumption.
Defendants contest these economic conclusions. But we are not
convinced that the findings are contrary to the evidence. Moreover,
the limited provision of the decree should be regarded. In this
relation, the decree enjoins defendants from concerted action
in
"preventing, restraining or refusing to grant quantity or other
discounts where such discounts reflect, effect, or result in
economics to refiners either in direct or indirect costs."
With a single exception, defendants do not ask the court to
review the findings with respect to credit arrangements known as
"the four payment plan," "split billing," and "cash discount," or
as to "price guarantee" and "second-hand sugar or resales." They
say that, in each case, questions of fact alone are raised, and
they disclaim having taken, or having any desire to take, any
action with respect to these subjects which is enjoined by the
decree. The exception refers to the practice of "requiring buyers
to elect and specify at the time of entering contract, without
privilege of change, the prices and/or terms in cases where the
refiner had more than one price or different terms in different or
the same territories." This restriction is defended as a necessary
corollary of the principle of open prices and terms without
discrimination, and the question is as to the legality of the
restraint in the application of that principle.
Other questions concern practices in relation to "damaged sugar
and frozen stocks," "tolling," "used bag allowances," and "private
brands." The court found that the restraints imposed in these
matters were unreasonable. They appear to be of minor importance,
and we think it unnecessary to state the particular facts.
Page 297 U. S. 596
(e)
Statistical information. Some statistical
information collected by the Institute was supplied only to its
members; some was supplied as well to representatives of off-shore
refiners. The data disseminated by the Institute to the purchasing
trade consisted of weekly statistics as to the total melt
(production) and total deliveries, and monthly statistics of total
deliveries, of all sugar, divided so as to show the amount of
domestic cane, imported cane, and beet sugar delivered during the
period. These statistics were widely distributed through news
agencies, banks and brokers. The total refined stocks on hand could
be computed by subtracting from the total melt of each week the
total deliveries. During recent years, when refined stocks were
greatly increasing, defendants continued to supply to the trade
weekly statistics on melt and deliveries from which the trade could
readily calculate the increase. Data as to the capacity of the
several refiners were available to the public in substantially
similar form to that obtained by the Institute. It also appeared
that, in May, 1931, after the present suit was begun, statistics
were released to the trade showing the total consumption of cane,
beet, foreign, and insular refined sugar by States for the years
1928, 1929, and 1930, together with figures showing the per capita
consumption of each state during the same years.
The trial court found that none of the other statistics supplied
to members or offshore refiners were available except through the
Institute, and none were supplied or available to the trade. What
the court considered to be "vital data" relating to production and
deliveries of individual refiners, to deliveries by states, to
deliveries by states by all the important differential routes, to
consigned and in-transit stocks for the several states, "which
would have illuminated the situation in the several trade areas
where the competitive set-ups differed widely," were withheld from
purchasers. The court concluded
Page 297 U. S. 597
that, by collecting and circulating only among themselves that
information, defendants obtained an unfair advantage with respect
to purchasers and effected an unreasonable restraint.
The court took the view that the statistics relating to total
production, total deliveries, and calculable stocks, which
defendants did make available, could have had only limited
significance for the individual purchaser, and were even likely to
mislead him. Such information reflected only the general situation
for the country as a whole and for all refiners. Defendants
challenge this criticism, and emphasize the value of the
information they gave. And, with respect to the statistics not
disseminated, they say that it did not appear how buyers were
prejudiced, and that the sole reason that the information was not
published was "because the refiners had no reason to believe that
the buyers wanted it." We cannot say, however, that the finding of
the trial court, in connection with its exhaustive examination of
conditions in the trade, is without adequate support. We shall
presently consider the criticism from a legal standpoint of the
breadth of the provision in the decree relating to the duty of
dissemination.
Fourth. The application of the Anti-Trust Act and the
provisions of the decree. The restrictions imposed by the
Sherman Anti-Trust Act are not mechanical or artificial. We have
repeatedly said that they set up the essential standard of
reasonableness.
Standard Oil Co. v. United States,
221 U. S. 1;
United States v. American Tobacco Co., 221 U. S.
106. They are aimed at contracts and combinations
which,
"by reason of intent or the inherent nature of the contemplated
acts, prejudice the public interests by unduly restricting
competition or unduly obstructing the course of trade."
Nash v. United States, 229 U.
S. 373,
229 U. S. 376;
United States v. American Linseed Oil Co., 262 U.
S. 371,
262 U. S.
388-389. Designed to frustrate unreasonable
Page 297 U. S. 598
restraints, they do not prevent the adoption of reasonable means
to protect interstate commerce from destructive or injurious
practices and to promote competition upon a sound basis. Voluntary
action to end abuses and to foster fair competitive opportunities
in the public interest may be more effective than legal processes.
And cooperative endeavor may appropriately have wider objectives
than merely the removal of evils which are infractions of positive
law. Nor does the fact that the correction of abuses may tend to
stabilize a business, or to produce fairer price levels, require
that abuses should go uncorrected or that an effort to correct them
should for that reason alone be stamped as an unreasonable
restraint of trade. Accordingly, we have held that a cooperative
enterprise otherwise free from objection, which carries with it no
monopolistic menace, is not to be condemned as an undue restraint
merely because it may effect a change in market conditions where
the change would be in mitigation of recognized evils and would not
impair, but rather foster, fair competitive opportunities.
Appalachian Coals v. United States, 288 U.
S. 344,
288 U. S.
373-374. Further, the dissemination of information is
normally an aid to commerce. As free competition means a free and
open market among both buyers and sellers, competition does not
become less free merely because of the distribution of knowledge of
the essential factors entering into commercial transactions. The
natural effect of the acquisition of the wider and more scientific
knowledge of business conditions on the minds of those engaged in
commerce, and the consequent stabilizing of production and price,
cannot be said to be an unreasonable restraint or in any respect
unlawful.
Maple Flooring Association v. United States,
268 U. S. 563,
268 U. S.
582-583. In that case, we decided that trade
associations which openly and fairly gather and disseminate
information as to the cost of their
Page 297 U. S. 599
product, the volume of production, the actual price which the
product has brought in past transactions, stocks of merchandise on
hand, approximate costs of transportation, without reaching or
attempting to reach an agreement or concerted action with respect
to prices or production or restraining competition, do not fall
under the interdiction of the Act.
Id., p.
268 U. S. 586.
See also Cement Manufacturers' Protective Ass. v. United
States, 268 U. S. 588,
268 U. S.
604-606.
The freedom of concerted action to improve conditions has an
obvious limitation. The end does not justify illegal means. The
endeavor to put a stop to illicit practices must not itself become
illicit. As the statute draws the line at unreasonable restraints,
a cooperative endeavor which transgresses that line cannot justify
itself by pointing to evils afflicting the industry or to a
laudable purpose to remove them. The decisions on which defendants
rely emphasize this limitation. In
Chicago Board of Trade v.
United States, 246 U. S. 231, the
Court found the assailed rule to be a reasonable regulation in a
limited field. In the case of
Appalachian Coals, supra, p.
288 U. S. 375,
the Court found that abundant competitive opportunities would exist
in all markets where defendants' coal was sold, and that nothing
had been shown to warrant the conclusion that defendants' plan
would have an injurious effect upon competition in those markets.
In
Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 283 U.
S. 163, relating to contracts concerning patents for
cracking processes in producing gasoline, an examination of the
transactions involved led to the conclusion "that no monopoly of
any kind, or restraint of interstate commerce" had been effected
"either by means of the contracts or in some other way."
Id., p.
283 U. S. 179.
And, while the collection and dissemination of trade statistics are
in themselves permissible and may be a useful adjunct of
Page 297 U. S. 600
fair commerce, a combination to gather and supply information as
a part of a plan to impose unwarrantable restrictions -- as, for
example, to curtail production and raise prices -- has been
condemned.
American Column Co. v. United States,
257 U. S. 377,
257 U. S.
411-412;
United States v. Linseed Oil Company,
supra; Maple Flooring Association v. United States, supra, pp.
268 U. S.
584-585.
We have said that the Sherman Anti-Trust Act, as a charter of
freedom, has a generality and adaptability comparable to that found
to be desirable in constitutional provisions. It does not go into
detailed definitions. Thus, in applying its broad prohibitions,
each case demands a close scrutiny of its own facts. Questions of
reasonableness are necessarily questions of relation and degree. In
the instant case, a fact of outstanding importance is the relative
position of defendants in the sugar industry. We have noted that
the fifteen refiners, represented in the Institute, refine
practically all the imported raw sugar processed in this country.
They supply from 70 to 80 percent of the sugar consumed. Their
refineries are in the East, South, and West, and their agreements
and concerted action have a direct effect upon the entire sugar
trade. While their product competes with beet sugar and "offshore"
sugar, the maintenance of fair competition between the defendants
themselves in the sale of domestic refined sugar is manifestly of
serious public concern. Another outstanding fact is that
defendants' product is a thoroughly standardized commodity. In
their competition, price, rather than brand, is generally the vital
consideration. The question of unreasonable restraint of
competition thus relates in the main to competition in prices,
terms, and conditions of sales. The fact that, because sugar is a
standardized commodity, there is a strong tendency to uniformity of
price, makes it the more important that such opportunities as may
exist for fair competition should not be impaired.
Page 297 U. S. 601
Defendants point to the abuses which existed before they formed
the Institute, and to their remedial efforts. But the controversy
that emerges is not as to the abuses which admittedly existed, but
whether defendants' agreement and requirements went too far and
imposed unreasonable restraints. After a hearing of extraordinary
length, in which no pertinent fact was permitted to escape
consideration, the trial court subjected the evidence to a thorough
and acute analysis which has left but slight room for debate over
matters of fact. Our examination of the record discloses no reason
for overruling the court's findings in any matter essential to our
decision.
In determining the relief to be afforded, appropriate regard
should be had to the special and historic practice of the sugar
industry. The restraints, found to be unreasonable, were the
offspring of the basic agreement. The vice in that agreement was
not in the mere open announcement of prices and terms in accordance
with the custom of the trade. That practice, which had grown out of
the special character of the industry, did not restrain
competition. The trial court did not hold that practice to be
illegal, and we see no reason for condemning it. The unreasonable
restraints which defendants imposed lay not in advance
announcements, but in the steps taken to secure adherence, without
deviation, to prices and terms thus announced. It was that
concerted undertaking which cut off opportunities for variation in
the course of competition, however fair and appropriate they might
be. But, in ending that restraint, the beneficial and curative
agency of publicity should not be unnecessarily hampered. The trial
court left defendants free to provide for immediate publicity as to
prices and terms in all closed transactions. We think that a
limitation to that sort of publicity fails to take proper account
of the practice of the trade in selling on "moves," as already
described,
Page 297 U. S. 602
a practice in accordance with which the court found that "the
great bulk of sugar always was and is purchased." That custom
involves advance announcements, and it does not appear that
arrangements merely to circulate or relay such announcements
threaten competitive opportunities. On the other hand, such
provision for publicity may be helpful in promoting fair
competition. If the requirement that there must be adherence to
prices and terms openly announced in advance is abrogated and the
restraints which followed that requirement are removed, the just
interests of competition will be safeguarded and the trade will
still be left with whatever advantage may be incidental to its
established practice.
The decree. The court below did not dissolve the
Institute. The practices which had been found to constitute
unreasonable restraints were comprehensively enjoined. The
injunction restrains defendants "individually and collectively, in
connection with the sale, marketing, shipment, transportation,
storage, distribution or delivery of refined sugar," from engaging
with one another or with any competitor through any "program" in
any of the activities separately described. The decree defines
"program" as
"any agreement, understanding or concerted action, including,
but without limiting the generality of the foregoing, any rule,
policy or code provision or interpretation, concertedly adopted or
maintained."
Then follow forty-five specifications of prohibited action. As
to seventeen of these paragraphs, defendants have withdrawn their
assignments of error.
Paragraphs 1 and 2 of the specifications enjoin the carrying out
of the open price plan so far as it seeks to compel uniform terms,
regardless of circumstances, and
Page 297 U. S. 603
an adherence to prices, terms, etc., announced in advance. These
paragraphs cover any agreement or concerted action in
"1. Effectuating any general plan to give the same terms,
conditions, or freight applications to customers, regardless of the
varying circumstances of particular transactions or classes of
transactions or regardless of the varying situation of particular
refiners, distributors or customers or classes thereof;"
"2. Selling only upon or adhering to prices, terms, conditions,
or freight applications announced, reported, or relayed in advance
of sale or refraining from deviating therefrom."
In view of those provisions, and of the other forty specified
restrictions, we think that paragraphs 3, 4, and 5 with respect to
the reporting or relaying of information as to current or future
prices should be eliminated. These paragraphs are as follows:
"3. Effectuating any system for or systematically reporting to
or among one another or competitors or to a common agency,
information as to current or future prices, terms, conditions, or
freight applications, or lists or schedules of the same;"
"4. Relaying by or through The Sugar Institute, Inc., or any
other common agency, information as to current or future prices,
terms, conditions or freight applications or any list or schedule
of the same;"
"5. Giving any prior notice of any change or contemplated change
in prices, terms, conditions or freight applications, or relaying,
reporting or announcing any such change in advance thereof."
Such reporting or relaying, as we have said, permits voluntary
price announcements by individual refiners, in accordance with
trade usage, to be circulated, and subject
Page 297 U. S. 604
to the restrictions imposed by the decree does not appear to
involve any unreasonable restraint of competition.
Paragraph 7 relates to the collection and dissemination of
statistical information, as follows:
"7. Effectuating any system of gathering and/or disseminating
statistical information regarding melt, sales, deliveries, stocks
on hand, stocks on consignment, stocks in transit, volume of sugar
moved by differential or other particular routes or types of
routes, new business or any other statistical information of a
similar character, wherever and to the extent that said information
is not made, or is not readily, fully and fairly available to the
purchasing and distributing trade."
This provision was based upon the finding that
"perfect competition and defendants' professed policy of
fostering such competition require that the purchasing trade as
well as the sellers have the full, detailed information which
defendants withheld."
That ruling has appropriate reference to the statistical data
which are specified in paragraph 7 and to the withholding of which
we have referred. In those data, the purchasing and distributing
trade have a legitimate interest. But it does not follow that the
purchasing and distributing trade have such an interest in every
detail of information which may be received by the Institute.
Information may be received in relation to the affairs of refiners
which may rightly be treated as having a confidential character and
in which distributors and purchasers have no proper interest. To
require, under the penalties of disobedience of the injunction, the
dissemination of everything that the Institute may learn might well
prejudice, rather than serve, the interests of fair competition and
obstruct the useful and entirely lawful activities of the
refiners.
In this view, we think that the clause in paragraph 7 "or any
other statistical information of a similar
Page 297 U. S. 605
character" should be eliminated. The preceding specifications as
to melt, sales, deliveries, stocks on hand, on consignment, or in
transit, and as to transportation and new business, appear to be
adequate. The words "of a similar character" have no clearly
defined meaning, and would place the defendants under an equivocal
restriction which may do more harm than good. With the removal of
that clause and the placing of the word "and" before the words "new
business," paragraph seven is approved.
Following the provisions for injunction, the decree properly
provides that jurisdiction is retained for the purpose of
"enforcing, enlarging or modifying" its terms. It is further
provided that the injunction is without prejudice to application by
any party for modification in order to permit the adoption of any
"program" that may be permissible under "the National Industrial
Recovery Act" of June 16, 1933 (48 Stat. 195), or the "Emergency
Farm Relief Act" of May 12, 1933, or "any other present or future
statutes of the United States." This subdivision of the decree
should be modified so as to refer simply to "any applicable Act of
Congress."
The decree is modified in the particulars above stated and, as
thus modified, is affirmed.
It is so ordered.
MR. JUSTICE SUTHERLAND and MR. JUSTICE STONE took no part in the
consideration and decision of this cause.
[
Footnote 1]
The court states:
"The testimony is transcribed in over 10,000 typewritten pages;
more than 900 exhibits covering many thousands of pages were
introduced in evidence."
[
Footnote 2]
The "basis price" is the price quoted at so much per pound per
one hundred pound bag of "fine granulated" or "granulated" sugar.
Contracts are closed with reference to this price, but the
purchaser has the option at stipulated differentials to specify for
delivery an assortment of grades and packages.
[
Footnote 3]
It appears that these five refiners accounted for 25.45 percent
of all sugar produced by defendants; in 1931, for 28.54 percent
[
Footnote 4]
The American Sugar Refining Company, which in 1927 had 25.06
percent of all sugar produced by defendants.