1. As an incident to a temporary and experimental scheme for
assisting the milk industry by fixing prices to producer and
consumer (
Nebbia v. New York, 291 U.
S. 502), the New York Milk Control Act, as amended,
discriminated between dealers who had, and dealers who had not,
well advertised tradenames, by permitting the latter to sell
bottled milk in the City of New York at a price one cent less per
quart than the price prescribed for the former.
Held, that
there was a reasonable basis for the discrimination, and that a
dealer of the former class who failed to show that, in practice,
the differential had resulted in any gain of trade at its expense
by the latter class of dealers, or had caused it substantial loss,
did not
Page 297 U. S. 252
prove a violation of the equal protection clause of the
Fourteenth Amendment. Pp.
297 U. S. 261,
297 U. S.
263.
2. The findings in this case establish that, before the fixing
of prices under the Act, dealers without well advertised brands
were able to compete for the trade in question, but only by
slightly underselling their advertised competitors. The
differential is sustained as an attempt, competent to the
legislature during the limited term of the experiment, to preserve
this trade practice, already existing, which balanced the advantage
of a lower price for the one group against the advantage of
advertisement enjoyed by the other. P.
297 U. S.
261.
11 F.
Supp. 599 affirmed.
Appeal from a decree which dismissed, upon the final hearing, a
suit to enjoin the enforcement of a provision of the New York
Agriculture & Markets Law. For an earlier phase,
see
s.c.,
293 U. S. 194.
Cf. p.
297 U. S. 266,
post.
Page 297 U. S. 256
MR. JUSTICE ROBERTS delivered the opinion of the Court.
This cause is here a second time. The prior appeal was from a
decree denying a preliminary injunction and dismissing the bill.{1}
We reversed, holding that evidence should be taken, findings and
conclusions made, and a decree thereupon entered. After remand, the
appellant amended its bill, the court sent the case to a master,
who made findings of fact, stated his conclusions of law, and
Page 297 U. S. 257
recommended that an injunction be entered. The District Court
accepted the master's findings and found certain additional facts,
but dismissed the bill upon the merits.{2} From this judgment, the
present appeal was taken.
As will appear by reference to our former opinion, the
appellant's complaint is that the fixing of a differential of not
to exceed one cent per quart on sales to stores, in favor of milk
dealers not having a "well advertised tradename," by the Milk
Control Law of April 10, 1933, Laws N.Y.1933, c. 158 (reenacted by
the Laws N.Y.1934, c. 126), was an invasion of rights guaranteed by
the Fourteenth Amendment. The bill, as framed when the case was
here before, recited that the administrative authority which fixed
the minimum price on sales to stores found the appellant and three
other milk dealers in the metropolitan market had well advertised
tradenames, and the statute permitted dealers not having such
tradenames to sell bottled milk to stores at one cent per quart
less than the minimum which dealers with well advertised tradenames
were required to charge, and also permitted stores to resell to
their customers the unadvertised brands of milk at a price one cent
per quart less than that at which the appellant's milk could be
sold under the minimum fixed by the order. Resulting loss of
business and irreparable damage were alleged.
In this Court, the appellees sought to justify the differential
by the assertion that the statute was temporary in character,
intended to relieve a temporary economic situation, and meanwhile
to prevent monopoly of the business by dealers having well
advertised names. In support of this position, it was said that,
prior to the adoption of the Milk Control Act of 1933, independent
dealers, so-called, had purchased from producers at prices lower
than
Page 297 U. S. 258
those paid by appellant and other purveyors of well advertised
brands, and, in turn, charged less to stores than the appellant and
others in its class. By the Milk Control Act, the independent
dealers were compelled to purchase from the farmers on the same
basis as the well known dealers, and to deprive them of this
advantage and, in turn, to compel them to charge the same price for
their milk as the well advertised brands commanded would be to
transfer all their customers to the owners of well known brands,
and put them out of business. The appellant replied that, prior to
the adoption of the Milk Control Law, there had been a threat to
forbid the sale of milk in bulk to stores; this compelled the
independents who had formerly sold mostly bulk milk to change to
the bottled trade, and keen competition ensued between them and the
owners of well advertised brands, with destructive price-cutting
throughout the greater part of New York City, so that there was no
fixed price for bottled milk sold to stores either by the
independents or the well advertised dealers. In support of these
contentions, we were referred to statements found in the
legislative report leading to the adoption of the Milk Control Law,
and the injunction affidavits.
We held we could not take judicial notice of local trade
conditions prevailing in the City of New York; as the case had been
disposed of below on the allegations of the bill, we were not
called upon to examine the affidavits submitted in support of the
motion for injunction and to find the facts, and the
constitutionality of the challenged provision should be determined
in the light of evidence upon the matters as to which the parties
were in disagreement.
By amendment, the appellant added to its bill paragraphs to the
following effect: prior to 1932, less than one-third of the fluid
milk sold in New York was bottled, the balance being sold in bulk
and under no tradename.
Page 297 U. S. 259
Toward the end of 1931, a commission recommended that the sale
of loose milk to stores be prohibited. The Board of Health made an
order, effective January 1, 1933, the effective date of which was
subsequently postponed to June 1, 1933, prohibiting the practice.
By reason of the impending ban upon the sale of loose milk, dealers
engaged in the sale of that commodity were forced to make a drastic
change in their methods. The transition from the sale of loose milk
to bottled, which began about April 1, 1933, and continued until
June 1, 1933, engendered widespread price-cutting and a steadily
declining price level, and brought about unsettled market
conditions and great variations in price. At no time prior to the
effective date of the Milk Control Act was there any trade custom,
practice, or usage whereby the bottled milk of dealers thereafter
classified as not having well advertised tradenames was sold to
stores at a price different from that of the bottled milk of the
appellant and others classified as having well advertised
tradenames. Before April 10, 1933, and thereafter, the appellant
was in active competition with more than 150 dealers in the sale of
bottled milk to stores in the city. The appellant and others
classified as having well advertised tradenames sell approximately
21 percent of the bottled milk sold to stores. The prices paid by
dealers to producers under the Milk Control Law have been the same
for all dealers, no matter how classified. All bottled milk must
have printed on the cap the name of the dealer distributing it. The
services rendered by the appellant and by so-called independent
dealers differ in no respect.
The assertions of shrinkage of appellant's sales to stores
consequent upon the establishment of the differential were repeated
and amplified in the amended bill. An answer was filed denying the
allegations of the bill. Much evidence was received.
Page 297 U. S. 260
The findings of the master establish that the dealers having a
well advertised tradename, of which appellant is one, are in keen
competition with each other and with the independent dealers, and
have no monopoly, nor anything approaching a monopoly, of the sale
of bottled milk to stores. The findings further demonstrate that
the good will incident to appellant's well known tradename
"Borden's" has been built up largely by advertising, and there is
no finding that the appellant's methods in that respect, or its
trade practices, have been illegal. Grade B milk, with which we are
alone concerned, must conform to standards of quality, purity, and
cleanliness prescribed by law, whether sold by appellant or by an
independent dealer. The service rendered and the conditions of sale
are the same for both. It is plain from these facts that the
allowance of the differential cannot be justified as a preventive
of monopoly or as a deterrent of illegal combination or illegal
trade practices, or as a recognition of differences in the service
rendered.
We are brought to the remaining issue of fact to resolve which
the case was remanded. Was there a differential during a
substantial period prior to adoption of the act between the price
charged to stores by dealers having well advertised tradenames and
that charged by those lacking this advantage?
The master's findings upon the point, though the appellant
excepted to them, were adopted by the court below. They are to the
effect that, from November, 1931, to April, 1933, and for several
years prior thereto, the independent dealers sold their bottled
milk to stores in New York City for resale to consumers at one or
more cents per quart below the price at which the advertised
dealers were selling their bottled milk to stores in that city,
and, during the same years, the stores were selling the
independents' bottled milk to consumers from one cent to two cents
per quart below the price at which they were
Page 297 U. S. 261
vending the bottled milk of the advertised dealers. The District
Court made additional findings, supplementing those of the master,
that independent dealers, on occasions before November 1, 1931, and
until April 1, 1933, tried to sell bottled milk to stores at the
same price as that charged by the appellant and another advertised
dealer, and, in each case, were compelled by loss of business to
resume their earlier and lower price, and, during the same period,
customers, when offered the several brands at the same price, would
usually take a bottle of the well advertised dealer's milk in
preference to that of an independent dealer. These findings of the
master and the court disclose the circumstances in the light of
which the appellant's claim that it was denied the equal protection
of the laws must be considered. The appellant assigns them as
error, but they are supported by substantial evidence, and we will
not disturb them.
We hold that the fixing of the differential in favor of the
sellers of milk not having a well advertised tradename, in the
situation exhibited by the findings, does not deny the appellant
equal protection.
The argument is that the classification is arbitrary, since the
statute puts the appellant and other dealers who have well
advertised tradenames in a single class solely by reason of the
fact that their legitimate advertising has brought them goodwill.
So, it is said, they are penalized for their business skill and
acumen. The answer seems sufficiently obvious. In enforcing its
policy of price-fixing -- a temporary expedient to redress an
injurious economic condition -- the Legislature believed that a
fixed minimum price by dealers to stores would not preserve the
existing economic method of attaining equality of opportunity. That
method was for the well advertised dealers to rely on their
advertising to obtain a given price, and for the independents to
retain their share of the market, not by counter-advertising, but
by slight
Page 297 U. S. 262
reduction of price. The one expedient, the law did not purport
to touch; the other, by fixing the same minimum for all dealers, it
would effectually destroy. In these circumstances, it was competent
to the lawmakers to attempt, during the limited term of the
legislative experiment, to preserve the existing relationship of
advantage established by the past trade practices of the two
groups. So to do, we must assume, was within the legislative power
under the State Constitution. No prohibition of the expedient is
found in the Federal Constitution unless in the Fourteenth
Amendment. We have held that article does not prevent the fixing of
maximum and minimum prices for milk in the circumstances existing
in the state of New York in 1933.{3} We now hold that to provide
that a differential of one cent maintained by the independent
dealers shall continue does not deny their advertised competitors
equal protection. There was a plain reason for the classification.
It was not merely that appellant had established a goodwill; it was
that there had resulted a balance between that advantage and the
resulting disadvantage to the unadvertised dealer -- a balance
maintained by a price differential. To attempt the maintenance of
that balance was to strive for equality of treatment, equality of
burden, not to create inequality. To adapt the law to the existing
trade practice was neither unreasonable nor arbitrary. The present
case affords an excellent example of the difficulties and
complexities which confront the legislator who essays to interfere
in sweeping terms with the natural laws of trade or industry. The
danger in such efforts always is that unintended dislocations will
bring hardship to groups whose situation the broad rules fail to
fit. Where, as here, there is recognition of an existing status and
an attempt to equate the incidence of the statute in accordance
with it, we find a
Page 297 U. S. 263
compliance with, rather than a disregard of, the constitutional
guarantee of equal protection. The appellant cannot complain if, in
fact, the discrimination embodied in the law is but a perpetuation
of a classification created and existing by the action of the
dealers. In the light of the facts found, the Legislature might
reasonably have thought trade conditions existed justifying the
fixing of a differential. Judicial inquiry does not concern itself
with the accuracy of the legislative finding, but only with the
question whether it so lacks any reasonable basis as to be
arbitrary.
Standard Oil Co. v. Marysville, 279 U.
S. 582,
279 U. S.
586-587.
A second argument is that, instead of maintaining equality
between the two groups, the act has destroyed it by unduly favoring
the independents. The differential is said to inflict grievous
injury and irreparable and continuing damage upon the appellant. We
must look to the record to determine whether it supports the
appellant's claim. The master made numerous findings touching the
relative sales of bulk and bottled milk to stores by the two groups
of dealers at various times before and after the adoption of the
act, and in respect of appellant's share of that trade in
comparison with total sales and those of its independent
competitors. He also found:
"Since the enactment of the 1933 Law, the advertised dealers
have had a smaller proportion relative to the independent dealers
of the total sales of bottled milk to stores in New York City than
before the enactment of the law."
But neither in his findings nor in his general discussion does
he say that the smaller volume of appellant is due to the
differential provision. He does state: "The voluminous proofs fail
to furnish facts on which to base a finding as to the effect of
minimum prices without a differential." There is no factfinding of
loss and damage to plaintiff from the differential. A conclusion of
law is: "By reason of the differential provision, the
Page 297 U. S. 264
plaintiff is now suffering, and will continue to suffer,
irreparable damage." After a full discussion of the master's
findings, the District Court said: "From all this, it seems to us
very doubtful whether the differential has really damaged the
plaintiff at all." We have examined the findings and the evidence,
and concur in the conclusion. Though appellant, at the time of the
trial, had acquired a large experience of the operation of the
differential, its proofs and the findings based upon them, leave
serious doubt as to the effect on the appellant's store trade of
other factors, such as seasonal variation, the decrease in the
consumption of milk in 1934, the change from loose to bottled milk
in store distribution, and the sale of great quantities of
so-called relief milk under arrangement with the public
authorities. It has failed to show that, as a result of the
statute, the independent dealers have gained trade at its expense,
or that it has suffered substantial loss.
We have no occasion to determine whether the differential would
become unlawful, and the appellant would be entitled to relief if
there were proof that, in practice, it produces such gross
inequality, and so unnecessarily damages the appellant, as to shock
the conscience.
Decree affirmed.
Borden's Farm Products Co. v. Baldwin, 293 U.
S. 194; 7 F. Supp. 352.
11 F.
Supp. 599.
Nebbia v. New York, 291 U. S. 502.
MR. JUSTICE McREYNOLDS, dissenting.
MR. JUSTICE VAN DEVANTER, MR. JUSTICE SUTHERLAND, MR. JUSTICE
BUTLER, and I think the challenged judgment should be reversed.
In
Nebbia v. New York, 291 U.
S. 502,
291 U. S. 539,
we stated reasons in support of the conclusion that the New York
Milk Control Act of 1933 infringed the due process clause. We
adhere to what we there said.
The present cause raises a distinct, although subordinate,
question. Assuming that the general price-fixing provisions of the
Control Act are valid, do the provisions
Page 297 U. S. 265
which permit other dealers to sell below the minimum price
prescribed for appellant deprive it of the equal protection of the
laws? The answer should be in the affirmative.
Rational classification, based on substantial differences, is
within legislative power. An act which permits dealer A to sell at
less than the price fixed for dealer B obviously denies equality,
and, in the absence of some adequate reason for different
treatment, the enactment is invalid.
Here, appellant differs from favored dealers only in that it
possesses a well advertised brand, while they do not. And, solely
because of that fact, the Legislature undertook to handicap it, and
thus enable others profitably to share the trade. There is no
question of unfair trade practices or monopoly.
By fair advertisement and commendable service, appellant
acquired the public's goodwill. The purpose is to deprive it of the
right to benefit by this, and thereby aid competitors to secure the
business. This is grossly arbitrary and oppressive.
To support the legislation, it is said the Legislature believed
that a fixed minimum price to stores would not preserve the
existing economic method of attaining equality of opportunity.
Apparently this means that a dealer who, through merit, has
acquired a good reputation can be deprived of the consequent
benefit in order that another may trade successfully. Thus, the
statute destroys equality of opportunity -- puts appellant at a
disadvantage because of merit.
Merely because, on a given date, there were differences in
prices under open competition offers no rational reason for
legislation abolishing competition and perpetuating such
differences. The status existing under competitive conditions
certainly is not preserved by destroying competition. Formerly,
appellant had the right to adjust prices to meet trade exigencies,
and thus protect itself
Page 297 U. S. 266
from loss of business. Now it must stand helpless while
adversaries take possession of the field. It may suffer utter ruin
solely because of good reputation, honestly acquired.