As the controversy in this case involved the question on what
basis dividends in insolvency should have been declared, and
therein the enforcement of the trust in accordance with law, this
Court has jurisdiction of it in equity.
Less than two years having elapsed from the payment of the first
dividend to the filing of this bill, and the other creditors of the
bank not having been harmed by the delay, no presumption of laches
is raised, nor can an estoppel properly be held to have arisen.
A secured creditor of an insolvent national bank may prove and
receive dividends upon the face of his claim as it stood at the
time of the declaration of insolvency without crediting either his
collaterals, or collections made therefrom after such declaration,
subject always to the proviso that dividends must cease when, from
them and from collaterals realized, the claim has been paid in
full.
On the 17th day of July, A.D. 1891, the First National Bank of
Palatka, Florida, a banking association incorporated under the laws
of the United States, having its place of business at Palatka,
Florida, failed and closed its doors. Subsequently, T. B. Merrill
was duly appointed receiver of the bank by the Comptroller of the
Currency, and entered upon the discharge of his duties. At the time
of the failure of the bank, it was indebted to the National Bank of
Jacksonville in the sum of $6,010.47 on sundry drafts, which
indebtedness was unsecured, and also in the sum of $10,093.34,
being $10,000, and interest, for money borrowed June 5, 1891,
evidenced by a certificate of deposit, which was secured by sundry
notes belonging to the First National Bank of Palatka, attached to
the certificate as collateral. These notes aggregated $10,896.22,
the largest being a note of A. L. Hart for $5,350.22. The
Page 173 U. S. 132
National Bank of Jacksonville proved its claim upon the
unsecured drafts for $6,010.47, and as to this there was no
controversy. It also offered to prove its claim for $10,093.34, but
the receiver would not permit it to do this, and, under the ruling
of the Comptroller of the Currency, it was ordered first to exhaust
the collaterals given to secure the certificate of deposit, and
then to prove for the balance due, after applying the proceeds of
the collaterals in part payment.
The Jacksonville Bank collected all the notes, excepting that of
A. L. Hart, obtained a judgment on the latter, which it assigned
and transferred to the receiver, applied the proceeds of the
collaterals which it had collected to its claim on the certificate,
and proved for the balance due thereon, being the sum of $4,496.44.
On December 1, 1892, a dividend of $1,573.75 was paid on the claim
as thus proven, and on May 17, 1893, a second dividend of $449.64
was paid.
On the 11th of September, 1894, the Jacksonville Bank filed its
bill of complaint in the Circuit Court of the United States for the
Southern District of Florida against Merrill, as receiver, which
set forth the foregoing facts, complained of the action of the
receiver in not permitting proof for the full amount of the
certificate of deposit, and alleged that it
"gave due notice that it would demand a
pro rata
dividend upon the whole amount due your orator, without deducting
the amount collected on collateral security, to-wit, that it would
demand a
pro rata dividend upon $16,103.81, and interest
thereon from the 17th day of July, A.D. 1891."
The prayer of the bill was, among other things, for a
pro
rata distribution on the entire amount of the
indebtedness.
The defendant demurred to the bill and, the demurrer having been
overruled, answered, denying
"that the complainant gave due notice that it would demand a
pro rata dividend upon the whole amount due to it without
deducting the amount collected on collateral security,"
and averring, to the contrary, that
"the complainant accepted the said ruling of the said
Comptroller without demur, and accepted from the said Comptroller,
through this defendant, without protesting notice of any kind, the
checks of the
Page 173 U. S. 133
said Comptroller in payment of the dividends mentioned in the
bill, and that it was not until the 15th of March, 1894, that the
complainant gave notice of any kind that it dissented from the said
ruling of the Comptroller, and would demand payment upon a
different basis."
Sundry exceptions were taken to the answer, which were
overruled, and the cause was set down for final hearing on bill and
answer.
The circuit court entered its decree January 29, 1896, that
complainant was entitled to receive dividends on the whole face of
the indebtedness due July 17, 1891, less the dividends actually
paid to it; that the receiver declare the dividend on the basis of
the whole claim, and pay it out of any assets which were in his
hands March 15, 1894, and that he render an account.
From this decree the receiver prosecuted an appeal to the
Circuit Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit. That court,
differing from the circuit court as to the form of its decree,
reversed it and remanded the cause with directions to enter a
decree that the Jacksonville Bank was entitled to prove its claims
to the entire amount of the indebtedness, and to the payment
thereon of the same dividends as had been paid on other
indebtedness of the Palatka Bank, with interest on such dividends
from the date of the declaration thereof, less a credit of the sums
which had been paid as dividends on the part of the claim
theretofore allowed, provided the dividends theretofore paid and
thereafter to be paid on the sum of $10,093.34, together with the
amounts theretofore and thereafter received on the collaterals
securing that indebtedness, should not exceed one hundred cents on
the dollar of the principal and interest of said debt, that the
receiver recognize the Jacksonville Bank as creditor of the Palatka
Bank in said sum of $10,093.34 as of July 17, 1891, and pay
dividends as aforesaid thereon, or certify the same to the
Comptroller of the Currency, to be paid in due course of
administration, and that the Jacksonville Bank receive, before
further payment to other creditors, its due proportion of the
dividends as thus declared, with interest. 75 F. 148. From that
decree,
Page 173 U. S. 134
after the mandate of the circuit court of appeals had been sent
down to the circuit court and proceedings had thereunder, an appeal
was taken and perfected to this Court, and is numbered 54 of this
term.
The decree was entered by the circuit court in pursuance of the
mandate of the circuit court of appeals, July 27, 1896, and the
receiver prayed an appeal therefrom to the circuit court of
appeals, which was by that court dismissed, on motion of the
Jacksonville Bank. 78 F. 208. From this decree of dismissal, an
appeal was allowed and perfected to this Court, and is numbered 55
of this term.
These appeals were argued together.
MR. CHIEF JUSTICE FULLER, after stating the facts in the
foregoing language, delivered the opinion of the Court.
The circuit court of appeals reversed the decree of the circuit
court with specific directions. Nothing remained for the circuit
court to do except to enter a decree in accordance with the
mandate; and, for the purposes of an appeal to this Court, the
decree of the circuit court of appeals was final. The mandate went
down, and the circuit court entered its decree in strict conformity
therewith before the appeal in No. 54 was prosecuted to this Court.
This promptness of action did not, however, cut off that appeal,
and any difficulty in our dealing with the cause in the circuit
court was obviated by the second appeal, which brings before us, in
No. 55, the record subsequent to the first decree of the circuit
court of appeals.
It is contended that the bill should have been dismissed because
of adequate remedy at law, and on the ground of
Page 173 U. S. 135
laches and estoppel. As the controversy involved the question on
what basis dividends should have been declared, and therein the
enforcement of the administration of the trust in accordance with
law, we have no doubt of the jurisdiction in equity.
Nor was the lapse of time such as to raise any presumption of
laches, nor could an estoppel properly be held to have arisen. Less
than two years had elapsed from the payment of the first dividend
to the filing of the bill, and the other creditors of the insolvent
bank had not been harmed by the temporary submission of complainant
to the ruling of the Comptroller. The decree affected only assets
on hand, or such as might be subsequently discovered, and if the
other creditors had no rights superior to that of complainant, they
lost nothing by the reduction of their dividends, if any,
afterwards declared to be paid out of such assets.
The inquiry on the merits is, generally speaking, whether a
secured creditor of an insolvent national bank may prove and
receive dividends upon the face of his claim as it stood at the
time of the declaration of insolvency, without crediting either his
collaterals or collections made therefrom after such declaration,
subject always to the proviso that dividends must cease when, from
them and from collaterals realized, the claim has been paid in
full.
Counsel agree that four different rules have been applied in the
distribution of insolvent estates, and state them as follows:
"Rule 1. The creditor desiring to participate in the fund is
required first to exhaust his security, and credit the proceeds on
his claim, or to credit its value upon his claim, and prove for the
balance, it being optional with him to surrender his security and
prove for his full claim."
"Rule 2. The creditor can prove for the full amount, but shall
receive dividends only on the amount due him at the time of
distribution of the fund -- that is, he is required to credit on
his claim, as proved, all sums received from his security, and may
receive dividends only on the balance due him. "
Page 173 U. S. 136
"Rule 3. The creditor shall be allowed to prove for and receive
dividends upon the amount due him at the time of proving or sending
in his claim to the official liquidator, being required to credit
as payments all the sums received from his security prior
thereto."
"Rule 4. The creditor can prove for and receive dividends upon
the full amount of his claim, regardless of any sums received from
his collateral after the transfer of the assets from the debtor in
insolvency, provided that he shall not receive more than the full
amount due him."
The circuit court and the circuit court of appeals held the
fourth rule applicable, and decreed accordingly.
This was in accordance with the decision of the Circuit Court of
Appeals for the Sixth Circuit in
Chemical National Bank v.
Armstrong, 59 F. 372, Mr. Justice Brown and Circuit Judges
Taft and Lurton, composing the court. The opinion was delivered by
Judge Taft, and discusses the question on principle with a full
citation of the authorities. We concur with that court in the
proposition that assets of an insolvent debtor are held under
insolvency proceedings in trust for the benefit of all his
creditors, and that a creditor, on proof of his claim, acquires a
vested interest in the trust fund, and, this being so, that the
second rule before mentioned must be rejected, as it is based on
the denial, in effect, of a vested interest in the trust fund and
concedes to the creditor simply a right to share in the
distributions made from that fund according to the amount which may
then be due him, requiring a readjustment of the basis of
distribution at the time of declaring every dividend and treating,
erroneously as we think, the claim of the creditor to share in the
assets of the debtor, and his debt against the debtor, as if they
were one and the same thing.
The third and fourth rules concur in holding that the creditor's
right to dividends is to be determined by the amount due him at the
time his interest in the assets becomes vested, and is not subject
to subsequent change, but they differ as to the point of time when
this occurs.
In
Kellock's Case, 3 Ch. App. 769, it was held that
Page 173 U. S. 137
the creditor's interest in the general fund to be distributed
vested at the date of presenting or proving his claim, and this
rule has been followed in many jurisdictions where statutory
provisions have been construed to require an affirmative election
to become a beneficiary thereunder. For instance, the cases in
Illinois construing the assignment act of that state, which are
well considered and full to the point, hold that the interest of
each creditor in the assigned estate "only vests in him when he
signifies his assent to the assignment by filing his claim with the
assignee."
Levy v. Bank, 158 Ill. 88;
Furness v.
Bank, 147 Ill. 570.
On the other hand, the Supreme Court of Pennsylvania, in
Miller's Appeal, 35 Pa.St. 481, and many subsequent cases,
has held, necessarily in view of the statutes of Pennsylvania
regulating the matter, that the interest vests at the time of the
transfer of the assets in trust. In that case, the debtor executed
a general assignment for the benefit of creditors. Subsequently the
assignor became entitled to a legacy which was attached by a
creditor, who realized therefrom $2,402.87. It was held that such
creditor was, notwithstanding, entitled to a dividend out of the
assigned estate on the full amount of his claim at the time of the
execution of the assignment. Mr. Justice Strong, then a member of
the state tribunal, said:
"By the deed of assignment, the equitable ownership of all the
assigned property passed to the creditors. They became joint
proprietors, and each creditor owned such a proportional part of
the whole as the debt due to him was of the aggregate of the debts.
The extent of his interest was fixed by the deed of trust. It was
indeed only equitable, but whatever it was, he took it under the
deed, and it was only as a part owner that he had any standing in
court when the distribution came to be made. . . . It amounts to
very little to argue that Miller's recovery of the $2,402.87
operated with precisely the same effect as if a voluntary payment
had been made by the assignor after his assignment -- that is, that
it extinguished the debt to the amount recovered. No doubt it did,
but it is not as a creditor that he is entitled to a distributive
share of
Page 173 U. S. 138
the trust fund. His rights are those of an owner by virtue of
the deed of assignment. The amount of the debt due to him is
important only so far as it determines the extent of his ownership.
The reduction of that debt therefore, after the creation of the
trust and after his ownership had become vested, it would seem,
must be immaterial."
Differences in the language of voluntary assignments and of
statutory provisions naturally lead to particular differences in
decision, but the principle on which the third and fourth rules
rest is the same. In other words, those rules hold, together with
the first rule, that the creditor's right to dividends is based on
the amount of his claims at the time his interest in the assets
vests by the statute, or deed of trust, or rule of law, under which
they are to be administered.
The first rule is commonly known as the "bankruptcy rule,"
because enforced by the bankruptcy courts in the exercise of their
peculiar jurisdiction, under the Bankruptcy Acts, over the property
of the bankrupt, in virtue of which creditors holding mortgages or
liens thereon might be required to realize on their securities, to
permit them to be sold, to take them on valuation, or to surrender
them altogether, as a condition of proving against the general
assets.
The fourth rule is that ordinarily laid down by the chancery
courts, to the effect that, as the trust created by the transfer of
the assets by operation of law or otherwise is a trust for all
creditors, no creditor can equitably be compelled to surrender any
other vested right he has in the assets of his debtor in order to
obtain his vested right under the trust. It is true that, in
equity, a creditor having a lien upon two funds may be required to
exhaust one of them in aid of creditors who can only resort to the
other; but this will not be done when it trenches on the rights or
operates to the prejudice of the party entitled to the double fund.
Story, Eq.Jur. (13th ed.) § 633;
In re Bates, 118 Ill.
524. And it is well established that in marshaling assets, as
respects creditors, no part of his security can be taken from a
secured creditor until he is completely satisfied. 2 White &
Tudor, Vol. II, Part 1, 4th Amer. ed., pp. 258, 322.
Page 173 U. S. 139
In
Greenwood v. Taylor, 1 Russ. & Myl. 185, Sir
John Leach applied the bankruptcy rule in the administration of a
decedent's estate, and remarked that the rule was
"not founded, as has been argued, upon the peculiar jurisdiction
in bankruptcy, but rests upon the general principles of a court of
equity in the administration of assets,"
and referred to the doctrine requiring a creditor having two
funds as security, one of which he shares with others, to resort to
his sole security first. But
Greenwood v. Taylor was, in
effect, overruled by Lord Cottenham in
Mason v. Bogg, 2
Myl. & Cr. 443, 488, and expressly so by the Court of Appeals
in Chancery in
Kellock's Case, and the application of the
bankruptcy rule rejected.
In
Kellock's Case, Lord Justice W. Page Wood (soon
afterwards Lord Chancellor Hatherly) said:
"Now, in the case of proceedings with reference to the
administration of the estates of deceased persons, Lord Cottenham
put the point very clearly, and said:"
"A mortgagee has a double security. He has a right to proceed
against both, and to make the best he can of both. Why he should be
deprived of this right because the debtor dies, and dies insolvent,
it is not very easy to see."
"Mr. De Gex, who argued this case, very ably, says that the
whole case is altered by the insolvency. But where do we find such
a rule established, and on what principle can such a rule be
founded, as that where a mortgagor is insolvent, the contract
between him and his mortgagee is to be treated as altered in a way
prejudicial to the mortgagee, and that the mortgagee is bound to
realize his security before proceeding with his personal
demand?"
"It was strongly pressed upon us, and the argument succeeded
before Sir J. Leach in
Greenwood v. Taylor, that the
practice in bankruptcy furnishes a precedent which ought to be
followed. But the answer to that is that this Court is not to
depart from its own established practice, and vary the nature of
the contract between mortgagor and mortgagee by analogy to a rule
which has been adopted by a court having a peculiar jurisdiction,
established for administering the property
Page 173 U. S. 140
of traders unable to meet their engagements, which property that
court found it proper and right to distribute in a particular
manner, different from the mode in which it would have been dealt
with in the Court of Chancery. . . . We are asked to alter the
contract between the parties by depriving the secured creditor of
one of his remedies, namely, the right of standing upon his
securities until they are redeemed."
And it was the established rule in England prior to the
Judicature Act, 38 & 39 Victoria, c. 77, that in an
administration suit, a mortgagee might prove his whole debt, and
afterwards realize his security for the difference, and so as to
creditors with security, where a company was being wound up under
the Companies Act of 1862. 1 Daniel's Ch.Prac. 384;
In re
Winternsea Brick Works, L.R. 16 Ch.Div. 337.
Certainly the giving of collateral does not operate of itself as
a payment or satisfaction either of the debt or any part of it, and
the debtor, who has given collateral security, remains debtor
notwithstanding, to the full amount of the debt, and so in
Lewis v. United States, 92 U. S. 623,
it was ruled that "it is a settled principle of equity that a
creditor holding collaterals is not bound to apply them before
enforcing his direct remedies against the debtor."
Doubtless the title to collaterals pledged for the security of a
debt vests in the pledgee so far as necessary to accomplish that
purpose, but the obligation to which the collaterals are subsidiary
remains the same. The creditor can sue, recover judgment, and
collect from the debtor's general property, and apply the proceeds
of the collateral to any balance which may remain. Insolvency
proceedings shift the creditor's remedy to the interest in the
assets. As between debtor and creditor, moneys received on
collaterals are applicable by way of payment; but as, under the
equity rule, the creditor's rights in the trust fund are
established when the fund is created, collections subsequently made
from or payments subsequently made on collateral cannot operate to
change the relations between the creditor and his co-creditors in
respect of their rights in the fund.
As Judge Taft points out, it is because of the distinction
Page 173 U. S. 141
between the right
in personam and the right
in
rem that interest is only added up to the date of insolvency,
although, after the claims as allowed are paid in full, interest
accruing may then be paid before distribution to stockholders.
In short, the secured creditor is not to be cut off from his
right in the common fund because he has taken security which his
co-creditors have not. Of course he cannot go beyond payment, and
surplus assets or so much of his dividends as are unnecessary to
pay him must be applied to the benefit of the other creditors, and,
while the unsecured creditors are entitled to be substituted as far
as possible to the rights of secured creditors, the latter are
entitled to retain their securities until the indebtedness due them
is extinguished.
The contractual relations between borrower and lender, pledging
collaterals, remain, as is said by the New York Court of Appeals in
People v. Remington, 121 N.Y. 328,
"unchanged, although insolvency has brought the general estate
of the debtor within the jurisdiction of a court of equity for
administration and settlement."
The creditor looks to the debtor to repay the money borrowed,
and to the collateral to accomplish this in whole or in part, and
he cannot be deprived either of what his debtor's general ability
to pay may yield or of the particular security he has taken.
We cannot concur in the view expressed by Chief Justice Parker
in
Amory v. Francis (1820), 16 Mass. 308, that
"the property pledged is in fact security for no more of the
debt than its value will amount to, and for all the rest the
creditor relies upon the personal credit of his debtor, in the same
manner he would for the whole if no security were taken."
We think the collateral is security for the whole debt and every
part of it, and is as applicable to any balance that remains after
payment from other sources as to the original amount due, and that
the assumption is unreasonable that the creditor does not rely on
the responsibility of his debtor according to his promise.
The ruling in
Amory v. Francis was disapproved,
shortly
Page 173 U. S. 142
after it was made, by the Supreme Court of New Hampshire in
Moses v. Ranlet (1822), 2 N.H. 488, Woodbury, J.,
afterwards Mr. Justice Woodbury, of this Court, delivering the
opinion, and is rejected by the preponderance of decisions in this
country, which sustain the conclusion that a creditor with
collateral is not on that account to be deprived of the right to
prove for his full claim against an insolvent estate. Many of the
cases are referred to in
Bank v. Armstrong, and these and
others given in the Encyclo. of Law and Eq., 2d ed., vol. 3, p.
141.
Does the legislation in respect to the administration of
national banks require the application of the bankruptcy rule? If
not, we are of opinion that the equity rule was properly applied in
this case.
By section 5234 of the Revised Statutes, and section 1 of the
Act of June 30, 1876, 19 Stat. 63, c. 156, the Comptroller of the
Currency is authorized to appoint a receiver to close up the
affairs of a national banking association when it has failed to
redeem its circulation notes, when presented for payment, or has
been dissolved, and its charter forfeited, or has allowed a
judgment to remain against it unpaid for 30 days, or whenever the
Comptroller shall have become satisfied of its insolvency after
examining its affairs. Such receiver is to take possession of its
effects, liquidate its assets, and pay the money derived therefrom
to the Treasurer of the United States.
Section 5235 of the Revised Statutes requires the Comptroller,
after appointing such receiver, to give notice by newspaper
advertisement for three consecutive months, "calling on all persons
who may have claims against such association to present the same,
and to make legal proof thereof."
By section 5242, transfers of its property by a national banking
association after the commission of an act of insolvency, or in
contemplation thereof, to prevent distribution of its assets in the
manner provided by the chapter of which that section forms a part,
or with a view to preferring any creditor except in payment of its
circulating notes, are declared to be null and void.
Page 173 U. S. 143
Section 5236 is as follows:
"From time to time, after full provision has first been made for
refunding to the United States any deficiency in redeeming the
notes of such association, the Comptroller shall make a ratable
dividend of the money so paid over to him by such receiver on all
such claims as may have been proved to his satisfaction, or
adjudicated in a court of competent jurisdiction, and, as the
proceeds of the assets of such association are paid over to him,
shall make further dividends on all claims previously proved or
adjudicated, and the remainder of the proceeds, if any, shall be
paid over to the shareholders of such association or their legal
representatives in proportion to the stock by them respectively
held."
In
Cook County National Bank v. United States,
107 U. S. 445, it
was ruled that the statute furnishes a complete code for the
distribution of the effects of an insolvent national bank, that its
provisions are not to be departed from, and that the bankrupt law
does not govern distribution thereunder. The question now before us
was not treated as involved, and was not decided, but the case is
in harmony with
Bank v. Colby,
21 Wall. 609, and
Scott v. Armstrong, 146 U.
S. 499, which proceed on the view that all rights, legal
or equitable, existing at the time of the commission of the act of
insolvency which led to the appointment of the receiver, other than
those created by preference forbidden by section 5242, are
preserved, and that no additional right can thereafter be created
either by voluntary or involuntary proceedings. The distribution is
to be "ratable" on the claims as proved or adjudicated -- that is,
on one rule of proportion applicable to all alike. In order to be
"ratable," the claims must manifestly be estimated as of the same
point of time, and that date has been adjudged to be the date of
the declaration of insolvency.
White v. Knox, 111 U.
S. 784. In that case, it appeared that the Miners'
National Bank had been put in the hands of a receiver by the
Comptroller of the Currency, December 20, 1875. White presented a
claim for $60,000, which the Comptroller refused to allow. White
then brought suit to have his claim adjudicated, and on June 23,
1883, recovered judgment for $104,523.72, being
Page 173 U. S. 144
the amount of his claim, with interest to the date of the
judgment. Meanwhile, the Comptroller had paid the other creditors
ratable dividends, aggregating sixty-five percent of the amounts
due them, respectively, as of the date when the bank failed. When
White's claim was adjudicated, the Comptroller calculated the
amount due him according to the judgment as of the date of the
failure, and paid him sixty-five percent on that amount. White
admitted that he had received all that was due him on the basis of
distribution assumed by the Comptroller, but claimed that he was
entitled to have his dividends calculated on the face of the
judgment, which would give him several thousand dollars more than
he had received, and he applied for a mandamus to compel the
payment to him of the additional sum. The writ was refused by the
court below, and its judgment was affirmed. Mr. Chief Justice
Waite, speaking for the Court, said:
"Dividends are to be paid to all creditors, ratably -- that is
to say, proportionally. To be proportionate, they must be made by
some uniform rule. They are to be paid on all claims against the
bank previously proved and adjudicated. All creditors are to be
treated alike. The claim against the bank therefore must
necessarily be made the basis of the apportionment. . . . The
business of the bank must stop when insolvency is declared.
Rev.Stat. § 5228. No new debt can be made after that. The only
claims the Comptroller can recognize in the settlement of the
affairs of the bank are those which are shown by proof satisfactory
to him, or by the adjudication of a competent court, to have had
their origin in something done before the insolvency. It is clearly
his duty, therefore, in paying dividends, to take the value of the
claim at that time as the basis of distribution."
In
Scott v. Armstrong, 146 U.
S. 499, it was argued that the ordinary equity rule of
set-off in case of insolvency did not apply to insolvent national
banks, in view of sections 5234, 5236, and 5242 of the Revised
Statutes. It was urged
"that these sections, by implication, forbid this set-off
because they require that, after the redemption of the circulating
notes has been fully provided for, the assets shall be ratably
distributed among the creditors, and that no preferences given or
suffered
Page 173 U. S. 145
in contemplation of or after committing the act of insolvency
shall stand,"
and
"that the assets of the bank existing at the time of the act of
insolvency include all its property, without regard to any existing
liens thereon or set-offs thereto."
But this Court said:
"We do not regard this position as tenable. Undoubtedly any
disposition by a national bank, being insolvent or in contemplation
of insolvency, of its choses in action, securities, or other
assets, made to prevent their application to the payment of its
circulating notes, or to prefer one creditor to another, is
forbidden, but liens, equities, or rights arising by express
agreement, or implied from the nature of the dealings between the
parties, or by operation of law, prior to insolvency and not in
contemplation thereof, are not invalidated. The provisions of the
act are not directed against all liens, securities, pledges, or
equities whereby one creditor may obtain a greater payment than
another, but against those given or arising after or in
contemplation of insolvency. Where a set-off is otherwise valid, it
is not perceived how its allowance can be considered a preference,
and it is clear that it is only the balance, if any, after the
set-off is deducted which can justly be held to form part of the
assets of the insolvent. The requirement as to ratable dividends is
to make them from what belongs to the bank, and that which at the
time of the insolvency belongs of right to the debtor does not
belong to the bank."
The set-off took effect as of the date of the declaration of
insolvency, but outstanding collaterals are not payment, and the
statute does not make their surrender a condition to the receipt by
the creditor of his share in the assets.
The rule in bankruptcy went upon the principle of election --
that is to say, the secured creditor
"was not allowed to prove his whole debt unless he gave up any
security held by him on the estate against which he sought to
prove. He might realize his security himself if he had power to do
so, or he might apply to have it realized by the court of
bankruptcy, or by some other court having competent jurisdiction,
and might prove for any deficiency of the proceeds to satisfy his
demand; but if he neglected to do this and proved for his whole
debt, he
Page 173 U. S. 146
was bound to give up his security."
Robson, Law Bank. 336. But it was only under bankrupt laws that
such election could be compelled.
Tayloe v.
Thompson, 5 Pet. 358,
30 U. S.
369.
And we are unable to accept the suggestion that compulsion under
those laws was the result merely of the provision for ratable
distribution, which only operated to prevent preferences, and to
make all kinds of estates, both real and personal, assets for the
payment of debts, and to put specialty and simple contract
creditors on the same footing, and so gave to all creditors the
right to come upon the common fund. Equality between them was
equity, but that was not inconsistent with the common law rule
awarding to diligence, prior to insolvency, its appropriate reward,
or with conceding the validity of prior contract rights.
We repeat that it appears to us that the secured creditor is a
creditor to the full amount due him when the insolvency is
declared, just as much as the unsecured creditor is, and cannot be
subjected to a different rule. And, as the basis on which all
creditors are to draw dividends is the amount of their claims at
the time of the declaration of insolvency, it necessarily results,
for the purpose of fixing that basis, that it is immaterial what
collateral any particular creditor may have. The secured creditor
cannot be charged with the estimated value of the collateral, or be
compelled to exhaust it before enforcing his direct remedies
against the debtor, or to surrender it as a condition thereto,
though the receiver may redeem or be subrogated as circumstances
may require.
Whatever Congress may be authorized to enact by reason of
possessing the power to pass uniform laws on the subject of
bankruptcies, it is very clear that it did not intend to impinge
upon contracts existing between creditors and debtors, by anything
prescribed in reference to the administration of the assets of
insolvent national banks; yet it is obvious that the bankruptcy
rule converts what on its face gives the secured creditor an equal
right with other creditors into a preference against him, and hence
takes away a right which he already had. This a court of equity
should never do unless required by statute at the time the
indebtedness was created.
Page 173 U. S. 147
The requirement of equality of distribution among creditors by
the National Banking Act involves no invasion of prior contract
rights of any of such creditors, and ought not to be construed as
having, or being intended to have, such a result.
Our conclusion is that the claims of creditors are to be
determined as of the date of the declaration of insolvency,
irrespective of the question whether particular creditors have
security or not. When secured creditors have received payment in
full, their right to dividends and their right to retain their
securities cease, but collections therefrom are not otherwise
material. Insolvency gives unsecured creditors no greater rights
than they had before, though, through redemption or subrogation or
the realization of a surplus, they may be benefited.
The case was rightly decided by the circuit court of appeals.
Its decree in No. 54 is
Affirmed, and the decree of the circuit court, entered July
27, 1896, in pursuance of the mandate of that court, is also
affirmed and the case remanded accordingly.
MR. JUSTICE WHITE, with whom concurred MR. JUSTICE HARLAN and
MR. JUSTICE McKENNA, dissenting.
The Court now decides: 1st. That, on the failure of a national
bank, a creditor thereof, whose debt is secured by pledge, is
entitled to be recognized and classed by the Comptroller of the
Currency to the full amount of his debt, without in any way taking
into account the collaterals by which the debt is secured, and on
the amount so recognized he is entitled to be paid out of the
general assets the sum of any dividends which may be declared. (2)
That this right to be classed for the full amount of the debt,
without regard to the value of the collaterals, is fixed by the
date of the insolvency, and continues to the final distribution,
whatever may be the change in the debt thereafter brought about by
the realization of the securities, provided only that the sums
received by the creditor by way of dividends and from the amount
collected
Page 173 U. S. 148
from the collaterals do not exceed the entire debt, and
therefore extinguish it.
I am constrained to dissent from these propositions because, in
my opinion, their enforcement will produce inequality among
creditors, and operate injustice, and, as a necessary consequence,
are inconsistent with the National Banking Act.
It cannot be doubted that the acts of Congress which regulate
the collection and distribution of the assets of an insolvent
national bank are controlling. It is clear that every creditor who
contracts with such bank does so subject to the provisions
directing the manner of distributing the assets of such bank in
case of its insolvency, and therefore that the terms of the act
enter into and form part of every contract which such bank may
make. Now the act of Congress makes it the duty of the receiver
appointed by the Comptroller to liquidate the affairs of a failed
national bank, to take possession of and realize its assets,
Rev.Stat. § 5234; to call, by advertisement for 90 days, upon
creditors to present and make legal proof of their claims,
Rev.Stat., § 5235, and from the proceeds of the assets the
Comptroller is directed to make a "ratable dividend" on the
recognized claims, Rev.Stat., § 5236. To prevent preferences, the
law, moreover, directs that all contracts from which preferences
may arise, made after the commission of an act of insolvency, or in
contemplation thereof, "shall be utterly null and void." Rev.Stat.,
§ 5242.
I seems to me superfluous to demonstrate that the rules now
upheld by which a creditor holding security is decided to be
entitled to disregard the value of his security, and take a
dividend upon the whole amount of the debt from the general assets,
violates the principle of equality and ratable distribution which
the act of Congress establishes. Is it not evident that, if one
creditor is allowed to reap the whole benefit of his security, and
at the same time take from the general assets a dividend on his
whole claim, as if he had no security, he thereby obtains an
advantage over the other general creditors, and that he gets more
than his ratable share of the general assets? Let me illustrate the
unavoidable
Page 173 U. S. 149
consequence of the doctrine now recognized. A loans a national
bank $5,000, and takes as the evidence of such loan a note of the
bank for the sum named, without security. The lender is thus a
general or unsecured creditor for the sum of $5,000. B loans to the
same bank $5,000, without security. He is applied to for a further
loan, and agrees to loan another $5,000 on receiving collateral
worth $5,000, and requires that a new note be executed for the
amount of both loans, which recites that it is secured by the
collateral in question. While theoretically, therefore, B is a
secured creditor for $10,000, he practically has no security for
$5,000 thereof. Insolvency supervenes. The general assets received
by the Comptroller equal only fifty percent of the claims. Now,
under the rule which the Court establishes, A on his unsecured
claim of $5,000 collects a dividend of but $2,500, thereby losing
$2,500. B, on the other hand, who proves $10,000, taking no account
whatever of his collateral, realizes by way of dividends $5,000,
and by collections on collaterals a similar amount, with the result
that though, as to $5,000, he was, in effect, an unsecured
creditor, he loses nothing. B is thus in precisely as good a
situation as though he had originally demanded and received from
the borrowing bank collateral securities equal in value to the full
amount loaned. It is thus apparent that the application of the rule
would operate to enable B -- who, I repeat, virtually held no
collateral security for $5,000 of the sums loaned -- to be paid his
entire debt, though the assets of the insolvent estate of the
borrower paid but fifty cents on the dollar, while another
creditor, holding an unsecured claim for $5,000, fails to realize
thereon more than $2,500. Is it not plain that this result is
produced by practically a double payment to B -- that is, by
recognizing B as a preferred creditor in the specific property, of
the value of $5,000, pledged to him, withdrawing that property from
the general assets, and allowing B to solely appropriate it, yet
permitting him, when the secured part of his debt is thus virtually
satisfied, to again assert the same secured portion of the debt
against other assets by a claim upon the general fund in the hands
of the receiver for the full amount
Page 173 U. S. 150
loaned. The consequence of the receipt of this extra sum upon
account of the already fully secured portion of the original loan
is that B is enabled to offset it against the deficient dividend on
the unsecured portion of the debt, one equaling the other, thus
closing the transaction without loss to him.
Let us suppose also the case of a creditor of a national bank
who recovers a judgment for $100,000 and levies the same upon real
estate of the bank worth only $50,000. While the legal title and
possession is still in the bank, a receiver is appointed, and takes
possession of the real estate. Certainly it cannot be contended
that this judgment lien holder is not in equally as good a position
as the holder of a mortgage lien or other collateral security. The
doctrine of the Court, however, if applied to the judgment lien
holder, would authorize him to demand that the receiver treat the
real estate as not embraced in the general assets, and that the
creditor be allowed to enforce his whole claim against the other
assets, irrespective of the value of the specific security acquired
by his lien.
That the doctrine maintained by the Court also tends to operate
a discrimination, as between secured creditors, in favor of the one
holding collateral securities not susceptible of prompt realization
is, I think, demonstrable. Thus, a secured creditor who takes
collaterals maturing on the same day with the debt owing to
himself, which collaterals consist of negotiable notes, the makers
of which and endorsers upon which are pecuniarily responsible,
finds the collaterals promptly paid when deposited for collection,
and if his debtor should become insolvent the day after payment,
the creditor could only claim for the residue of the debt still
unpaid. On the other hand, a creditor of the same debtor, the debt
to whom matures at the same time as that owing the other creditor
and is secured by collaterals also due contemporaneously, has the
collaterals protested for nonpayment, and when the debtor fails,
the collaterals have not been realized. While the first debtor, who
had received first-class collateral, can collect dividends against
the estate of his insolvent debtor only for the unpaid portion of
the claim, losing a part of such residue by the inability of
the
Page 173 U. S. 151
estate to pay in full, the debtor who received poor collateral
collects dividends out of the general assets on his whole claim,
and, if he eventually realizes on his securities, may come out of
the transaction without the loss of one cent. These illustrations,
to my mind, adequately portray the inequality and injustice which
must arise from the application of the rules of distribution now
sanctioned by the court.
The fallacies which, it strikes me, are involved in the two
propositions sanctioned by the court are these: first, the
erroneous assumption that although the act of Congress contemplates
that the dividends should be declared out of the general assets
after the secured creditors have withdrawn the amount of their
security, it yet provides that the secured creditor who has
withdrawn his security, and thus been
pro tanto satisfied,
can still assert his whole claim against the general assets just as
if he had no security, and had not been allowed to withdraw the
same; second, he mistaken assumption that the act confers upon the
secured creditor a new and substantial right, enabling him to
obtain, as a consequence of the failure of the bank, an advantage
and preference which would not have existed in his favor had the
failure not supervened. This arises from holding that the
insolvency fixed the amount of the claim which the secured creditor
may assert as of the time of the insolvency, thereby enabling him
to ignore any collections which he may have realized from his
securities after the failure, and permitting him to assert as a
claim not the amount due at the time of the proof, but, by
relation, the amount due at the date of the failure, the result
being to cause the insolvency of the bank to relieve the creditor
holding security from the obligation to impute any collections from
his collateral to his debt, so as to reduce it by the extent of the
collections -- a duty which would have rested on him if insolvency
had not taken place. Third. By presupposing that because. before
failure. a secured creditor had a legal right to ignore the
collaterals held by him, and resort for the whole debt in the first
instance against the general estate of his debtor, it would impair
the obligation of the contract to require the secured creditor in
case of insolvency
Page 173 U. S. 152
to take into account his collaterals, and prevent him from
asserting his whole claim, for the purpose of a dividend, against
the general assets. B ut the preferential right arising from the
contract of pledge is in no wise impaired by compelling the
creditor to first exercise his preference against the security
received from the debtor, and thus confine him to the specific
advantage derived from his contract. Further, however, as the
contract, construed in connection with the law governing it,
restricts the secured as well as the unsecured creditor to a
ratable dividend from the general assets, the secured creditor is
prevented from enhancing the advantage obtained as a result of the
contract for security by proving his claim as if no security
existed, since to allow him to so do would destroy the rule of
ratable division, subject and subordinate to which the contract was
made. A forcible statement of the true doctrine on the foregoing
subject was expressed in the case of
Societe Generale de Paris
v. Geen, 8 App.Cas. 606. The question before the court arose
upon the construction to be given to a clause of the English
Bankrupt Act of 1869, incidental to the requirement of a section,
expressly embodied for the first time in a Bankrupt Act, that the
secured creditor should in some form account for the collateral
held by him in proving his claim against the general estate. In
considering the restriction upon the remedy of a secured creditor
produced by the insolvency, and the consequent right of such
creditor to receive only a ratable dividend on the balance of the
debt after the deduction of the value of the collaterals, Lord
Fitzgerald said (p. 620):
"Under ordinary circumstances, each creditor is at liberty to
pursue at his discretion the remedies which the law gives him; but
when insolvency intervenes, and the debtor is unable to pay his
debts, the position of all parties is altered -- the fund has
become inadequate, and the policy of the law is to lead to
equality. In pursuing that policy, the bankrupt law endeavors to
enforce an equal distribution, whilst it respects the rights of
those who have previously, by grant or otherwise, acquired some
security or some preferable right."
To resort, however, to reasoning for the purpose of
endeavoring
Page 173 U. S. 153
to demonstrate that where a statute does not allow preferences
in case of insolvency and commands a ratable distribution of the
assets, a secured creditor cannot be allowed to disregard the value
of his security and prove for the whole debt, seems to me to be
unnecessary, since that he cannot be permitted to so do, under the
circumstances stated, has been the universal rule applied in
bankruptcy in England and in this country from the beginning.
In the earliest English Bankrupt Act, 34 & 35 Hen. VIII. c.
4, the distribution of the general assets of the bankrupt was
directed to be made
"for true satisfaction and payment of the said creditors -- that
is to say, to every of the said creditors a portion rate and rate
like, according to the quantity of their debts."
In the statute of 13 Eliz. c. 7 (and which was in force in this
particular when the consolidated bankrupt statute of 6 Geo. IV. c.
16, was adopted), the distribution of assets was directed in
language similar to that just quoted from the statute of Henry
VIII. Under these statutes, from the earliest times it was held by
the Lord Chancellors of England, having the supervision of the
execution of the bankrupt statutes, that a secured creditor could
not retain his collateral security, and prove for his whole debt,
but must have his security sold, and prove for the rest of the debt
only. Lord Somers, in
Wiseman v. Carbonell (1695), 1
Eq.Cas.Ab. 312, pl. 9; Lord Hardwicke, in
In re Howell
(1737), 7 Vin.Abr. 101, pl. 13, and in
Ex Parte Grove
(1747), 1 Atk. 105; Lord Thurlow in
Ex Parte Dickson
(1789), 2 Cox Ch. 196, and in
Ex Parte Coming (1790), 2
Cox Ch. 225; Cooke's Bankrupt Laws (1st ed., 1786) 114, and (4th
ed., 1799) 119.
In 1794, 4 Brown's Ch.Rep. star paging 550, the prevailing
practice with respect to a sale of a mortgage security was
regulated by a general order formulated by Lord Chancellor
Loughborough wherein, among other things, it was provided that in
case the proceeds of sale should be insufficient to pay and satisfy
what should be found due upon the mortgage,
"that such mortgagee or mortgagees be admitted a creditor or
creditors under such commission for such deficiency, and to receive
a dividend or dividends thereon out of the bankrupt's estate or
Page 173 U. S. 154
effects, ratably and in proportion with the rest of the
creditors seeking relief under the said commission,"
etc.
Concerning the practice in bankruptcy, Lord Chancellor Eldon, in
1813, in Ex Parte Smith, 2 Rose 63, said:
"The practice has been long established in bankruptcy not to
suffer a creditor holding a security to prove unless he will give
up that security or the value has been ascertained by the sale of
it. The reason is obvious. Till his debt has been reduced by the
proceeds of that sale, it is impossible correctly to say what the
actual amount of it is. . . . It is, however, clearly within the
discretion of the court to relax this rule, and cases may occur in
which it would be for the benefit of the general creditors to relax
it."
The first two bankrupt statutes enacted in this country (Act
April 4, 1800, c. 19, 2 Stat. 19; August 4, 1841, c. 9, 5 Stat.
440) required a ratable distribution of the assets, and it was
conceded in argument that the universal practice enforced under
these acts was to require a creditor holding collateral security to
deduct the amount of his security and prove only for the residue of
the debt. This Court, speaking through Mr. Justice Story in 1845 in
In re
Christy, 3 How. 414, declared that under the act of
1841,
"if creditors have a pledge or mortgage for their debt, they may
apply to the court to have the same sold, and the proceeds thereof
applied towards the payment of their debts
pro tanto, and
to prove for the residue."
As the universal rule and practice in bankruptcy in England and
in this country up to and including the Bankrupt Act of 1841 was
solely the result of the statutory requirement that the assets
should be ratably distributed among the general creditors, my mind
fails to discern why the requirement for ratable distribution of
the assets in the act for the liquidation of failed national banks
should not have the same meaning, and produce the same result, as
the substantially similar provisions had always meant and had
always operated in England for hundreds of years, and in this
country for many years before the adoption by Congress of the act
for the liquidation of national banks. Indeed, the fact that the
requirement of ratable distribution had, by a long course of
practice
Page 173 U. S. 155
and judicial construction in England and in this country,
required the secured creditor to account for his security before
proving against the general assets gives rise to the application of
the elementary canon of construction that where words are used in a
statute, which words at the time had a settled and well understood
meaning, their insertion into the statute carries with them a
legislative adoption of the previous and existing meaning.
The reasoning by which it is maintained that the requirement for
ratable distribution should not be applied in the act providing for
the liquidation of an insolvent national bank may be thus summed
up: true it is that, universally in bankruptcy in England and in
this country, the rule was as above stated, but outside of
bankruptcy, a different practice prevailed in England, known as the
"chancery rule," and, as the winding up of an insolvent national
bank does not present a case of bankruptcy, its liquidation is
governed by such chancery rule, and not by the bankruptcy rule. The
bankruptcy rule, it is said, is commonly so called because enforced
by bankruptcy courts in the exercise of their "peculiar"
jurisdiction, and the courts which refuse to apply the rule
generally declare that it arose from express provisions in bankrupt
statutes requiring a creditor to surrender his collaterals, or
deduct for their value, before proving against the estate.
Pretermitting for a moment an examination of this reasoning, it
is to be remarked in passing that the argument, if sound, rests
upon the hypothesis that all the bankruptcy laws from the beginning
in England and in our own country, and the universal course of
decision thereon and the practice thereunder, have worked out
inequality and injustice by depriving a secured creditor of rights
which it is now asserted belonged to him, and which could have been
exercised by him without producing inequality. This deduction
follows, for it cannot be that, if not to compel the creditor to
deduct produces no inequality or injustice, then to compel him to
do so would have precisely the same result. The two opposing and
conflicting rules cannot both be enforced and yet in each instance
equality result. At best, then, the contention admits that, by
Page 173 U. S. 156
the consensus of mankind not to compel the secured creditor to
deduct the value of his collaterals before proving produces
inequality, for of all statutes, those relating to bankruptcy have
most for their object an equal distribution of the assets of the
insolvent among his creditors.
It is worthy also of notice in passing that the reasoning to
which we have referred rests upon the assumption that the act of
Congress providing for the liquidation of the affairs of a national
bank and a distribution of the assets thereof among the creditors
is not substantially a bankrupt statute. It certainly is a
compulsory method provided by law for winding up the concerns of an
insolvent bank, for preventing preferences, and for securing an
equal and ratable division of the assets of the association among
its creditors. And it assuredly can be safely assumed that
Congress, in adopting the rule of ratable distribution in the
National Banking Act, did not intend that the words embodying the
rule should be so construed as to produce a result contrary to that
which, for hundreds of years, had been recognized as necessarily
implied by the employment of similar language. It may also, I
submit, be likewise considered as certain that it was not intended,
in using the words "ratable distribution" in the statute, to bring
about an unequal, instead of a ratable, distribution of the general
assets.
But, coming to the proposition itself, is there any foundation
for the assertion that the rule or practice in bankruptcy requiring
the secured creditor to account for his security was the result of
something peculiar in the jurisdiction of bankruptcy courts, other
than the requirement contained in bankruptcy statutes that the
assets should be distributed ratably among creditors, and is there
any merit in the contention that the rule was the consequence of an
express provision in such laws imposing the obligation referred to
on the secured creditor?
A careful examination of every bankrupt statute in England from
the first statute of 34 & 35 Hen. VIII, c. 4, down to and
including the consolidated Bankrupt Act of 6 Geo. IV, c. 16, fails
to disclose any provision sustaining the statement that
Page 173 U. S. 157
the rule in bankruptcy depended upon express statutory
requirement, and, on the contrary, shows that it was simply a
necessary outgrowth of the command of the statute that there should
be an equal distribution of the bankrupt's assets.
I submit that not only an examination of the English statutes
makes clear the truth of the foregoing, but that its correctness is
placed beyond question by the statement of Lord Chancellor Eldon,
respecting proof in bankruptcy by a secured creditor, already
adverted to, that, "till his debt has been reduced by the proceeds
of that sale [that is, of the security], it is impossible correctly
to say what the actual amount of it is." And as an authoritative
declaration of the origin of the rule, the opinion of Vice
Chancellor Malins in
Ex Parte Alliance Bank (1868), L.R. 3
Ch., note at 773, is in point. The vice chancellor said:
"This rule [requiring a creditor to realize his security, and
prove for the balance of the debt only] does not depend on any
statutory enactment, but on a rule in bankruptcy, established
irrespective of express statutory enactment and under the statute
of Elizabeth, which provides:"
"Or otherwise to order the same [
i.e. the assets] to be
administered for the due satisfaction and payment of the said
creditors -- that is to say, for every of the said creditors a
portion, rate and rate alike, according to the quantity of his and
their debts."
Indeed not only was the obligation of the secured creditor to
account for his security derived from the provision as to ratable
distribution, but from that provision also originated the equally
well settled rule causing interest to cease upon the issuance of
the commission of bankruptcy. As early as 1743, Lord Hardwicke, in
Bromley v. Goodere, 1 Atkyns 75, in speaking of the
suspension of interest by the effect of bankruptcy, said:
"There is no direction in the act for that purpose, and it has
been used only as the best method of settling the proportion among
the creditors that they may have a rate-like satisfaction, and is
founded upon the equitable power given them by the act."
While generally the claim that the bankruptcy rule was the
creature of an express provision of the bankruptcy acts,
Page 173 U. S. 158
other than the requirement as to a ratable distribution of
assets, rests upon a mere statement to that effect without any
reference to the specific text of the Bankrupt Act, which it was
assumed made such requirement, in one instance, in the brief of
counsel in an early case in this country,
Findlay v.
Hosmer (1817), 2 Conn. 320, the statement is made in a more
specific form. A particular section of an English bankrupt statute
is there referred to as in effect expressly requiring a secured
creditor to account for his collaterals in order to prove against
the general assets. The statute thus referred to was section 9 of
21 Jac. I, c.19. But an examination of the section relied on shows
that it in no wise supports the assertion. The pertinent portion of
the section reads as follows:
". . . all and every creditor and creditors having security for
his or their several debts, by judgment, statute, recognizance,
specialty with penalty or without penalty, or other security, or
having no security, or having made attachments in London, or any
other place, by virtue of any custom there used, of the goods and
chattels of any such bankrupt, whereof there is no execution or
extent served and executed upon any the lands, tenements,
hereditaments, goods, chattels and other estate of such bankrupts,
before such time as he or she shall or do become bankrupt, shall
not be relieved upon any such judgment, statute, recognizance,
specialty, attachments or other security for any more than a
ratable part of their just and due debts, with the other creditors
of the said bankrupt, without respect to any such penalty or
greater sum contained in any such judgment, statute, recognizance,
specialty with penalty, attachment or other security."
The securities other than attachment referred to in this section
were manifestly embraced in the class known at common law as
"personal" security, as distinguished from "real" security, or
security upon property. (Sweet's Law Dict'y English Law,
verbo "Security.") In other words, the effect of the
section was but to forbid preferences in favor of creditors which
at law would have resulted from the particular form in which the
debt was evidenced, and from which form a claim would
Page 173 U. S. 159
be raised to a higher rank than a simple contract debt. That
this is the significance of the word "security" as used in this
section is shown by the following excerpt from Cooke's treatise on
Bankrupt Laws, published in 1786. At page 114, he says:
"The aim of the legislature in all the statutes concerning
bankrupts being that the creditors should have an equal proportion
of the bankrupt's effects, creditors of every degree must come in
equally, nor will the nature of their demands make any difference
unless they have obtained actual execution or taken some pledge or
security before an act of bankruptcy committed. For when a creditor
comes to prove his debt, he is obliged to swear whether he has a
security or not, and if he has, and insists upon proving, he must
deliver it up for the benefit of his creditors unless it be a joint
security from the bankrupt and another person,"
etc.
The fact that the expression "security," contained in the
section referred to, had no reference to security on property is
further demonstrated by the subsequent statute of 6 Geo. IV, c. 9,
§ 103, which reenacted in an altered form the ninth section of the
statute of James, for the reenacted section, although it referred
in broad terms to securities generally, yet especially excepted the
case of a mortgage or pledge. The section is as follows:
"SEC. 103. And be it enacted that no creditor having security
for his debt, or having made any attachment in London, or any other
place by virtue of any custom there used, of the goods and chattels
of the bankrupt, shall receive upon any such security or attachment
more than a ratable part of such debt, except in respect of any
execution or extent served and levied by seizure upon, or any
mortgage of or lien upon any part of the property of such bankrupt
before the bankruptcy."
Is it pretended anywhere that, after the reenactment of section
9 of the statute of James I, found in section 103, c. 9, 6 Geo. IV,
that the obligation of a secured creditor to account for his
collateral before he took a dividend out of the general assets
ceased to exist? Certainly there is no such
Page 173 U. S. 160
contention. If, however, that duty of the general creditor arose
not from the provision as to ratable distribution, but from the
provisions of section 9 of the act of James as claimed, then
necessarily such obligation on the part of the general creditor
would have ceased immediately on the enactment of the statute of 6
Geo. IV, which expressly excepted the mortgage creditor from the
operation of the particular section which it is contended imposed
the duty on the mortgage, creditor to account. The continued
enforcement of the rule which required the mortgage creditor to
deduct the value of his security before proving against general
assets after the reenactment of section 9 of the statute of George
referred to can lead to but one conclusion -- that is, that the
duty of the mortgage creditor before existing arose from the
provision for ratable distribution, and not from the terms of
section 9 of the statute of James, since that duty continued to be
compelled after the reenactment of that section in terms which
renders it impossible to contend that that section created the
duty.
A similar course of reasoning applies to bankrupt statutes of
this country.
Section 31 of our first bankrupt statute, Act April 4, 1800, c.
19, 2 Stat. 30, was in substance and effect similar to the
provision in the act of James. The statute of 1800 is said to have
been a consolidation of the provisions of previous English bankrupt
statutes,
Tucker v. Oxley,
5 Cranch 34,
9 U. S. 42;
Roosevelt v. Mark, 6 Johns.Ch. 266, 285, and in
Tucker
v. Oxley, Chief Justice Marshall declared that for that reason
the decisions of the English judges as to the effect of those acts
might be considered as adopted with the text that they expounded.
Section 31 reads as follows:
"SEC. 31. And be it further enacted that in the distribution of
the bankrupt's effects there shall be paid to every of the
creditors a portion-rate, according to the amount of their
respective debts, so that every creditor having security for his
debt by judgment, statute, recognizance, or specialty, or having an
attachment under any of the laws of the individual states, or of
the United States, on the estate of such bankrupt
Page 173 U. S. 161
(provided there be no execution executed upon any of the real or
personal estate of such bankrupt before the time he or she became
bankrupts). shall not be relieved upon any such judgment, statute,
recognizance, specialty, or attachment for more than a ratable part
of his debt with the other creditors of the bankrupt."
This provision of the act of 1800 was, however, omitted from the
Bankrupt Act of 1841, manifestly because it had become unnecessary.
The later statute contained in the fifth section a general
provision forbidding all preferences except in favor of two classes
of debts, thus rendering it superfluous to enumerate cases in which
there should be no preference. It was, however, under the act of
1841, which was drafted by Mr. Justice Story (2 Story's Life of
Story, 407), that this Court, speaking through that learned
Justice, in
In re Christy, already cited, declared that a
secured creditor must account for his security when proving against
the bankrupt estate. How it can be now argued that the requirement
that such creditor should only so prove his claim was the result of
a provision not found in the act of 1841, and clearly shown by all
the antecedent legislation not to refer to a creditor holding
property security, my mind fails to comprehend.
True it is that both in our own act of 1867 and in the English
Bankrupt Act of 1869 there were inserted express provisions
requiring a secured creditor to account for his collaterals before
proving against the general assets. But this was but the
incorporation into the statutes of the rule which had arisen as a
consequence of the requirement for a ratable distribution, and
which had existed for hundreds of years before the statutes of 1867
and 1869 were adopted. In other words, the express statutory
requirement only embodied in the form of a legislative enactment
what theretofore from the earliest time had been universally
enforced because of the provision for a ratable distribution.
The rule in bankruptcy imposing the duty upon the creditor to
account for his security before proving being, then, the result of
the provision of the bankrupt laws requiring ratable distribution,
I submit that the same requirements upon such
Page 173 U. S. 162
creditor should be held to arise from a like provision contained
in the act of Congress under consideration.
But coming to consider the chancery rule which it is contended
lends support to the doctrines applied in the cases at bar.
The foundation upon which the so-called chancery rule rests is
the case of
Mason v. Bogg, 2 Myl. & Cr. 443, decided
in 1837, where Lord Chancellor Cottenham expressed his approval of
the contention that a mortgage creditor, despite the death and
insolvency of his debtor, possessed the contract right to assert
his whole claim against general assets in the course of
administration in chancery, without regard to his mortgage
security. The question was not directly decided, however, as to
whether the creditor might prove in the administration for the
whole amount of the debt, but was reserved. As stated, however, the
reasoning of the court favored the existence of such right upon the
theory that a Court of Chancery, when administering assets in the
absence of a statute regulating the subject, could not deprive a
secured creditor of legal rights previously existing which he might
have asserted at law, although, by permitting the exercise of such
rights, preferences in the general assets would arise.
The next case in point of time in England -- and, indeed, the
one upon which most reliance is placed by those favoring the
chancery rule -- is
Kellock's Case, reported in L.R. 3 Ch.
769, involving two appeals, and argued before Sir W. Page Wood,
L.J., and Sir C. J. Selwyn, L.J. The cases arose in the winding up
of companies by virtue of the statute of 25 & 26 Victoria, c.
89. The issue presented in each case was whether a creditor having
collateral security was entitled to dividends upon the full amount
of the debt without reference to the value of collaterals, and in
one of the cases the lower court applied the doctrine supported by
the reasoning in
Mason v. Bogg, while in the other, the
lower court decided the bankruptcy rule governed. The appellate
court held that the chancery practice should be followed. The claim
was made that the secured creditor ought not to be allowed to take
a dividend on the full amount of his claim, because, among
Page 173 U. S. 163
other reasons, of section 133 of the act, which provided as
follows:
"133. The following consequences shall ensue upon the voluntary
winding-up of a company:"
"(1) The property of the company shall be applied in
satisfaction of its liabilities
pari passu and, subject
thereto, shall, unless it be otherwise provided by the regulations
of the company, be distributed amongst the members according to
their rights and interests in the company."
This contention, however, was answered by Lord Justice Wood, who
said (page 778):
"There is a clause in the Companies Act of 1862 which says that
in a voluntary winding up, equal distribution is to be made among
creditors; an expression similar to which, in 13 Eliz. c. 7,
appears to have led to the establishment of the rule in
bankruptcy."
He then called attention to the fact that a voluntary winding up
was not limited to cases of insolvent companies, but might be
resorted to on behalf of a solvent one, and he proceeded to comment
upon the fact that in previous winding-up acts, "when the
legislature intended proceedings to be conducted according to the
course in bankruptcy, it said so," concluding with the declaration
that the omission to do so in the case before the court indicated
the purpose of Parliament that the court should be governed by the
chancery rule. Lord Justice Selwyn, in a measure, also adopted this
view, saying (page 782):
"I think, therefore, that the onus is clearly thrown on those
persons who come here and say that when the legislature, with a
knowledge of the existence of the difference between the practice
in bankruptcy and the practice in chancery, entrusted the winding
up of the companies to the Court of Chancery, and said in express
terms that the practice of the Court of Chancery was to prevail,
they intended by some implication or inference to diminish,
prejudice, or affect the rights of creditors. I can find no trace
of any such intention. I think therefore we are bound to follow the
established practice of the Court of Chancery, especially when we
find that
Page 173 U. S. 164
that practice has been followed ever since the passing of the
Winding-up Act, and so long as winding-up orders have been made in
the Court of Chancery."
The whole subject has been set at rest, however, in Great
Britain, by section 25 of the Judicature Act of 1873, c. 66, and by
an amendment thereto, adopted in 1875, c. 77, which expressly
required that in the administration in chancery of an insolvent
estate of one deceased and in proceedings in the winding up of an
insolvent company under the companies act,
"the same rule shall prevail and be observed as to the
respective rights of secured and unsecured creditors and as to
debts and liabilities provable . . . as may be in force for the
time being under the law of bankruptcy with respect to the estates
of persons adjudged bankrupt."
So that now, in Great Britain, in all proceedings involving the
distribution of an insolvent fund, a secured creditor can only
prove for the balance which may remain after deduction of the
proceeds or value of collateral security.
In view, therefore, of the English legislation in 1873 and 1875,
which has rendered it impossible in cases of insolvency to apply
the doctrine of the
Kellock case, we need not particularly
notice decisions rendered in England subsequent to 1868, when the
Kellock case was decided, particularly as the tribunals
which rendered such decisions were subordinate to the Court of
Appeal, and necessarily bound by its rulings.
Now I submit, as the English chancellors, from the date of the
enactment of the earliest English bankrupt law, felt constrained to
compel a secured creditor to account for his security before
proving against the general assets of the bankrupt estate, because
Parliament had directed a ratable distribution of all such assets,
it cannot, in consonance with sound reasoning, be said that this
Court is to apply the chancery rule to the distribution of the
assets of an insolvent national bank, as to which Congress has
directed a ratable distribution, because in England, a different
rule was for a time applied to an act of Parliament providing not
solely for the liquidation of an insolvent estate, but equally to a
solvent and insolvent
Page 173 U. S. 165
one, and which rule was so applied in England because a
particular statute was construed as requiring that the practice
pursued in chancery in administering upon estates should
govern.
It is worthy of note that Lord Justice Wood, after stating in
his opinion in the
Kellock case that the bankruptcy rule
was "adopted by a court having a peculiar jurisdiction, established
for administering the property of traders unable to meet their
engagements," conceded that the provision in the statute of 13
Eliz. c. 7, requiring equal distribution, "led to the establishment
of the rule in bankruptcy." But the Lord Justice took the cases
then under consideration out of the operation of the provision of
the statute of Elizabeth because of provisions found in the
Companies Act, which, in his opinion, gave rise to a contrary view
in cases governed by that act. The distribution of the assets of a
failed national bank under the act of Congress, it is obvious,
presents the "peculiar" features which Lord Justice Wood had in
mind, since the requirement of ratable distribution is the exact
equivalent of the provision contained in the statute of Elizabeth.
But the reasoning now employed to cause the rule announced in the
Kellock case to apply so as to defeat the ratable
distribution provided by the act of Congress is made to rest upon
the assumption that the act of Congress does not contain the
peculiar requirement which was found in the bankruptcy acts, from
which the duty of the secured creditor to account for his security
before taking a dividend from the general assets arose. It comes,
then, to this: that the theory by which the obsolete doctrine of
the
Kellock case is made to apply rests upon an assumption
which repudiates the reasoning of that case -- in other words, that
the result of the
Kellock case is taken and applied to
this case, while the reasoning upon which the decision of the
Kellock case was based is in effect denied.
That to permit a secured creditor to retain his specific
contract security and also to prove against the general assets of
his insolvent debtor for the whole amount of the debt was deemed to
work out inequality is shown not only by the fact
Page 173 U. S. 166
that it was not applied in bankruptcy, but that, in the
administration of equitable, as contradistinguished from legal,
assets, courts of equity, following the maxim
equitas est quasi
equalitas, would not permit claimants against equitable assets
to share in the distribution of such assets until they had
accounted for any advantage gained by the assertion against the
general estate of the debtor of a preference permitted at law.
Morrice v. Bank of England, Cases Temp.Talb. 218;
Sheppard v. Kent, 2 Vern. 435;
Deg v. Deg, 2 P.W.
416;
Chapman v. Esgar, 1 Sm. & G. 575;
Bain v.
Sadler, L.R. 12 Eq. 570;
Purdy v. Doyle, 1 Paige 55;
Bank of Louisville v. Lockridge, 92 Ky. 472; 1 Story,
Eq.Jur. 12th ed. p. 543; Watson, 1 Comp.Ex. 2d Rev. ed. p. 35, c.
11.
It was undoubtedly from a consideration of this fundamental rule
of equity in construing the statutory requirement for ratable
division of general assets that the bankruptcy rule was formulated.
That rule, however, in effect declared that secured creditors might
retain their preferential contract rights in particular portions of
the estate of the insolvent debtor, but that it was the purpose of
Parliament, in commanding ratable distribution, that general assets
-- that is, assets disencumbered of liens -- should be distributed
only among the general or unsecured creditors; the necessary effect
being that a secured creditor could not prove against general
assets without surrendering his security, thus becoming a general
or unsecured creditor
for the whole amount of the debt, or
realizing upon the security, or in some form accounting for its
value, in which latter contingency he would be general or unsecured
creditor only
for the deficiency. That the bankruptcy rule
was deemed to be founded upon equitable principles I think is
demonstrated by the statement of Lord Hardwicke in a case already
mentioned --
Bromley v. Goodere, 1 Atk. 77 -- where, after
referring to the act of 13 Eliz. c. 7, he said:
"It is manifest that this act intended to give the commissioners
an equitable jurisdiction as well as a legal one, for they have
full power and authority to take by their discretions such order
and direction as they shall think fit, and that this has
Page 173 U. S. 167
been the construction ever since, and therefore, when petitions
have come before the Chancellor, he has always proceeded upon the
same rules as he would upon causes coming before him upon the bill
-- 'the rules of equity.'"
The foregoing reasoning renders it unnecessary to review at
length the opinion delivered by the Circuit Court of Appeals for
the Sixth Circuit in
Bank v. Armstrong, 59 F. 372, to
which the Court has referred, as the conclusions announced by the
circuit court of appeals were rested on the assumption that the
bankruptcy rule was the creature of an express statutory
requirement, and that to prevent a secured creditor from proving
for his whole debt, as of the time of the insolvency, without
regard to his collaterals, would deprive him of a contract right,
both of which contentions have been fully considered in what I have
already said. Nor is the case of
Lewis v. United States,
92 U. S. 68, also
referred to in the opinion of the Court in the case at bar,
controlling upon the question here presented. True, it was said in
the
Lewis case, in passing, and upon the admission of
counsel, that
"it is a settled principle of equity that a creditor holding
collaterals is not bound to apply them before enforcing his direct
remedies against the debtor,"
citing the
Kellock and two other English and two
Pennsylvania cases involving the question of the rights of a
creditor having the securities of distinct estates of separate
debtors. But the controversy before the Court in the
Lewis
case was of this latter character, being between the United States,
as creditor of a partnership and holding collaterals belonging to
the partnership, and the trustee in bankruptcy of the separate
estates of individual members of the partnership. The government
was seeking to assert against such separate estates a right of
preference given to it by statute. The Court decided that as the
United States had a paramount lien upon all the assets of every
debtor for the full satisfaction of its claim, it was unaffected by
the bankruptcy statutes, and therefore was not controlled by any
provision found therein for ratable distribution or otherwise. It
is apparent, therefore, that the Court, by the quoted statement,
did not decide that a court of equity
Page 173 U. S. 168
would apply the doctrine there set forth, where the rights of
the secured creditor were limited and controlled by statute. If the
secured creditor, who is allowed in the case now decided to
disregard his security and prove for the whole amount of his claim,
had a paramount lien not only upon his collaterals, but upon each
and every asset of the insolvent bank, the rule in the
Lewis case would be apposite. But that is not the
character of the case now before the Court, since here a secured
creditor has no paramount lien upon anything but his collaterals,
and is governed in his recourse against the general assets by the
requirement that there should be a ratable distribution.
As the case before us is to be controlled by the act of
Congress, it would appear unnecessary to advert to state decisions
construing local statutes, but, inasmuch as those decisions were
referred to and cited as authority, I will briefly notice them.
They are referred to in the margin, and divide themselves into four
classes: (1) those which maintain that where ratable distribution
is required, the creditor must account for his security before
proving; [
Footnote 1] (2) those
cases which, on the contrary, decide that to allow the creditor to
prove for his whole claim without deduction of security is not
incompatible with ratable distribution, and hold that the security
need not be taken into account; [
Footnote 2] (3) those cases which, while seemingly
denying
Page 173 U. S. 169
the obligation of the secured creditor to account for his
security, yet practically work out a contrary result by requiring
deduction upon collaterals as collected, and affording remedies to
compel prompt realization of collaterals; [
Footnote 3] (4) those which originated in purely local
statutes, and which hold that the secured creditor can prove for
the whole amount without reference to either the bankruptcy or the
chancery rule; [
Footnote 4] and
in the margin, I supplement the compilation heretofore made by a
reference to some state statutes and decisions referring to
statutes which expressly provide that the claimants upon an
insolvent estate can only prove for the balance due, after
deduction of any security held. [
Footnote 5]
Of course, for the purposes of this case, only the first two
classes of cases need be considered. The first class is well
represented by two Massachusetts cases:
Amory v. Francis,
16 Mass. 308, and
Farnum v. Boutelle, 13 Metc. 159. In the
first-named case, Chief Justice Parker said (page 310):
"If it were not so, the equality intended to be produced by
the
Page 173 U. S. 170
bankrupt laws would be grossly violated, and the creditor
holding the pledge would in fact have a greater security than that
pledge was intended to give him. For originally it would have been
security only for a portion of the debt equal to its value, whereas
by proving the whole debt and holding the pledge for the balance,
it becomes security for as much more than its value as is the
dividend which may be received upon the whole debt."
In the later case, Chief Justice Shaw announced the rule as
follows (13 Met. 164):
"If the mortgage remained in force at the time of the decease of
the debtor, then it is very clear as well upon principle as upon
authority that the creditors cannot prove their debt without first
waiving their mortgage, or in some mode applying the amount thereof
to the reduction of the debt, and then proving only for the
balance.
Amory v. Francis, 16 Mass. 308."
The second class of cases may be typified by the case of
People v. Remington, 121 N.Y. 328, where the conclusion of
the court was placed upon the ground that the rule in bankruptcy
originated in an express requirement in the bankrupt acts other
than that for a ratable distribution. The court, speaking through
Gray, J., said (p. 332):
"Some confusion of thought seems to be worked by the reference
of the decision of the question to the rules of law governing the
administration of estates in bankruptcy, but there is no warrant
for any such reference. The rules in bankruptcy cases proceeded
from the express provisions of the statute, and they are not at all
controlling upon a court administering, in equity, upon the estates
of insolvent debtors. The Bankruptcy Act requires the creditor to
give up his security, in order to be entitled to prove his whole
debt, or, if he retains it, he can only prove for the balance of
the debt after deducting the value of the security held. The
jurisdiction in bankruptcy is peculiar and special, and a
particular mode of administration is prescribed by the act."
Having thus eliminated the bankruptcy rule, the court reviewed
the decisions in
Mason v. Bogg and
Kellock's
case, and held those cases to be controlling. The
Remington case,
Page 173 U. S. 171
therefore, as well as those of which it is a type, need not be
further reviewed, as the fundamental error upon which they rest has
been fully stated in what I have previously said.
It is necessary, however, to call attention to the fact that in
the cases which decline to apply the rule in bankruptcy and refuse
to enforce the provision for ratable distribution there is an
entire want of harmony as to the time when the rights of creditors
are fixed with respect to the amount of the claim which may be
proved against general assets, some holding that dividends are to
be paid on the amount due at the date of insolvency, others on the
amount due at the time of proof, and others upon the sum due when
dividends are declared. This confusion is the necessary outcome of
the erroneous premise upon which the cases rest. A similar
confusion, moreover, I submit, is manifested by the rule now
announced by the Court; since, while it is avowedly rested upon the
defunct chancery rule exemplified in
Mason v. Bogg and the
Kellock case, yet in effect it fails to follow the very
rule upon which the decision is based. This is clear when it is
borne in mind that the chancery rule was decided in both
Mason
v. Bogg and the
Kellock case to be that the amount of
the claim of the creditor was fixed by the date when proof was
actually made, and yet, under the authority of the chancery rule
and the cases in question, the Court now decides that the rights of
the secured creditor are fixed by insolvency. Thus the chancery
rule is applied and at the same time repudiated in an important
particular, for the grave difference between allowing a secured
creditor to prove only for the amount due when proof was made, and
therefore compelling him to account for all collections realized on
collaterals up to that time and allowing him, long after
insolvency, to prove by relation, as of the date of the insolvency,
and disregard the collections actually made is manifest. In this
connection it may not be amiss to call attention to the fact that
if the bankruptcy rule was applied in the proof of claims, the
amount of the claim would not vary whether the date of insolvency
or the time when proof was made was held to be the date when the
rights of the creditor in the fund were fixed.
Page 173 U. S. 172
Moreover I submit that the propositions now adopted, which
reject the bankruptcy rule, rests on reasoning which, if it be
logically applied, requires the enforcement of the bankruptcy rule
in its integrity. It seems to me it has been shown by the doctrine
announced by Lord Hardwicke in 1743 (
Bromley v. Goodere,
supra) that the stoppage of interest on the claims of all
creditors was but an essential evolution of the principle of
ratable distribution. This stoppage of interest at the period named
is now upheld by the rule sanctioned by this Court. This, then,
takes the provision of the bankruptcy rule which favors the secured
creditor, and which arises alone from ratable division, and gives
him the benefit of it, while at the same time rejecting the
obligation to account, which arises from and depends on the very
principle of ratable distribution which is in part enforced. To
repeat, it strikes my mind that the conclusion now announced is
this: that the obsolete chancery rule both applies and does not
apply, that the bankruptcy rule at the same time does not apply and
does apply; the result of this conflict being to so interpret the
act of Congress as to strike from it the beneficent provision for
equality of distribution among general creditors.
MR. JUSTICE HARLAN and MR. JUSTICE McKENNA concur.
[
Footnote 1]
Amory v. Francis (1820), 16 Mass. 308;
Farnum v.
Boutelle (1847), 13 Metc. 159;
Vanderveer v. Conover
(1838), 16 N.J.L. 491;
Bell v. Fleming's Executors (1858),
12 N.J.Eq. 13, 25;
Whittaker v. Amwell National Bank
(1894), 52 N.J.Eq. 400;
Fields v. Creditors of Wheatley
(1853), 1 Sneed 351;
Winston v. Eldridge (1859), 3 Head
361;
Wurtz v. Hart (1862), 13 Ia. 515;
Searle v.
Brumback (1862), 4 Western Law Monthly (Ohio) 330;
In re
Frasch (1892) 5 Wash. 344;
National Union Bank v. National
Mechanics Bank (1895), 80 Md. 371;
American National Bank
v. Branch (1896), 57 Kan. 327;
Investment Co. v. Richmond
National Bank (1897), 58 Kan. 414.
[
Footnote 2]
Findlay v. Hosmer (1817) 2 Conn. 350;
Moses v.
Ranlet (1822), 2 N.H. 488;
West v. Bank of Rutland
(1847), 19 Vt. 403;
Walker v. Baxter (1854), 26 Vt. 710,
714;
In the Matter of Bates (1886), 118 Ill. 524;
Furness v. Union National Bank (1893), 147 Ill. 570;
Levy v. Chicago National Bank (1895), 158 Ill. 88;
Allen v. Danielson (1887), 15 R.I. 480;
Greene v.
Jackson Bank (1895), 18 R.I. 779;
People v. Remington
(1890), 121 N.Y. 328;
Third National Bank of Detroit v.
Haug (1890), 82 Mich. 607;
Kellogg v. Miller (1892),
22 Or. 406;
Winston v. Biggs (1895), 117 N.C. 206.
[
Footnote 3]
In re Estate of McCune (1882) 76 Mo. 200;
State v.
Nebraska Savings Bank (1894), 40 Neb. 342;
Jamison v.
Alder-Goldman Commission Co. (1894), 59 Ark. 548, 552;
Philadelphia Warehouse Co. v. Anniston Pipe Works (1895),
106 Ala. 357;
Erle v. Lane (1896), 22 Colo. 273.
[
Footnote 4]
Shunk's and Freedley's Appeals (1845), 2 Pa.St. 304;
Morris v. Olwine (1854), 22 Pa.St. 441, 442;
Keim's
Appeal (1856), 27 Pa.St. 42;
Miller's Appeal (1860),
35 Pa.St. 481;
Patten's Appeal (1863), 45 Pa.St. 151.
And see a reference to the cases in Pennsylvania in
Boyer's Appeal (1894), 163 Pa.St. 143.
[
Footnote 5]
Indiana --
Combs v. Trust Co., 146 Ind. 688, 691.
Kentucky -- Statutes, 1894 (Barber & Carroll's ed.) p. 193, c.
7, sec. 74;
Bank of Louisville v. Lockridge, 92 Ky. 472.
Massachusetts -- Act April 23, 1838, c. 163, sec. 3; General
Statutes, 1860, c. 118, sec. 27. Michigan -- 2 How.St. p. 2156,
sec. 8824. Minnesota -- by statute March 8, 1860, the security is
made the primary fund, to which resort must be had before a
personal judgment can be obtained against the debtor for a deficit.
Swift v. Fletcher, 6 Minn. 550. New Hampshire -- Laws
1862, c. 2594. South Carolina --
Piester v. Piester, 22
S.C. 146;
Wheat v. Dingle, 32 S.C. 473. Texas -- Civil
Stats. 1897, art. 83; Acts 1879, c. 53, sec. 13;
Willis v.
Holland (1896), 36 S.W. 329.
MR. JUSTICE GRAY dissenting.
While also unable to concur in the opinion of the majority of
the Court, I prefer to rest my dissent upon the effect of the
legislation of Congress, read in the light of the English statutes
and decisions before the American Revolution and of the judgments
of the courts of the United States, without particularly
considering the cases in England in recent times or the conflicting
decisions made in the courts of the several states under local
statute or usage or upon general theory. As the course of reasoning
in support of this view traverses part of the ground covered by the
other dissenting justices, I shall endeavor to state it as shortly
as possible.
The English Bankrupt Acts in force at the time of the
Declaration of Independence, so far as they touched the
distribution of a bankrupt's estate among his creditors, were
the
Page 173 U. S. 173
statute of 13 Eliz. (1571) c. 7, § 2, which directed the estate
to be applied to the
"true satisfaction and payment of the said creditors -- that is
to say to every of the said creditors a portion, rate and rate
like, according to the quantity of his or their debts,"
and the statute of 21 James I (1623), c.19, § 8 (or § 9), which
made more specific provisions against allowing any creditors,
whether "having security" or not, to prove "for any more than a
ratable part of their just and due debts with the other creditors
of the said bankrupt." As appears on the face of this provision,
the word "security" was evidently there used not as including a
mortgage or other instrument executed by the debtor by way of
pleading part of his property as collateral security for the
payment of a debt, but merely as designating a bond or writing
which was evidence of the debt itself as a direct personal
obligation, and the objects of the provision would appear to have
been to put all debts, whether by specialty or by simple contract,
upon an equal footing in the ratable distribution of a bankrupt's
estate, and to permit the real amount only of any debt, and not any
larger sum named in a bond or other specialty, to be proved in
bankruptcy. 4 Statutes of the Realm 539, 1228; 2 Cooke's Bankruptcy
Laws (4th ed.) [18] [33]; 1
ib. 119; Bac.Abr.
"Obligations," A; 3 Bl.Com. 439.
Neither of those statutes contained any provision whatever for
deducting the value of collateral security and proving the rest of
the debt. Yet from the earliest period of which there are any
reported cases, it was uniformly held -- without vouching in any
provision of the bankrupt acts other than those directing a ratable
distribution among all the creditors -- and had, long before the
American Revolution, become the settled practice in the Court of
Chancery, that a creditor could not retain collateral security
received by him from the bankrupt and prove for his whole debt, but
must have his collateral security sold, and prove for the rest of
the debt only. The authorities upon this point are collected in the
opinion of MR. JUSTICE WHITE,
ante, 173 U. S.
153.
After the American Revolution, the provision of the statute of
James I. was thrice reenacted, with little modification.
Page 173 U. S. 174
Stats. 5 Geo. IV (1824) c. 98, § 103; 6 Geo. IV (1825), c. 16, §
108; 12 & 13 Vict. (1849) c. 106, § 184. But the rule
established by the decisions and practice of the Court of Chancery
as to the proof of secured debts was never expressly recognized in
any of the English bankrupt acts until 1869, when provisions to
that effect were inserted in the statute of 32 & 33 Vict., c.
71, § 40. And there is no trace of a different rule in England in
proceedings in equity for the distribution of the estate of any
insolvent debtor or corporation until more than sixty years after
the Declaration of Independence.
Amory v. Francis (1820),
16 Mass. 308, 311;
Greenwood v. Taylor (1830), 1 Russ.
& Myl. 185;
Mason v. Bogg (1837), 2 Myl. & Cr.
443. In 1868, indeed, the Court of Chancery declined to apply the
bankruptcy rule to proceedings under the Winding-up Acts.
Kellock's case, L.R. 3 Ch. 769. But Parliament, by the
Judicature Acts of 1873 and 1875, applied that rule to such
proceedings. Stats. 36 & 37 Vict., c. 66, § 25(1); 38 & 39
Vict., c. 77, § 10. And Sir George Jessel, M.R., has pointed out
the absurdity of having different rules in the cases of living and
of dead bankrupts.
In re Hopkins (1881), 18 Ch.D. 370,
337.
The first bankrupt act of the United States, enacted in 1800,
was in great part copied from the earlier bankrupt acts of England,
and condensed the provisions above mentioned of the statutes of
Elizabeth and of James I. in this form:
"In the distribution of the bankrupt's effects, there shall be
paid to every of the creditors a portion-rate, according to the
amount of their respective debts, so that every creditor having
security for his debt by judgment, statute, recognizance or
specialty, or having an attachment under any of the laws of the
individual states, or of the United States, on the estate of such
bankrupt (provided there be no execution executed upon any of the
real or personal estate of such bankrupt, before the time he or she
became bankrupts) shall not be relieved upon any such judgment,
statute, recognizance, specialty or attachment, for more than a
ratable part of his debt with the other creditors of the
bankrupt."
Act April 4, 1800, c.19, § 31, 2 Stat. 30. That provision must
have received the
Page 173 U. S. 175
same construction that had been given by the English judges to
the statutes therein reenacted. Tucker v. Oxley (1809) 5 Cranch 34,
42; Scott v. Armstrong (1892)
146 U. S. 499,
146 U. S. 511,
13 Sup.Ct. 148.
The Bankrupt Act of 1841, which is well known to have been
drafted by Mr. Justice Story, omitted that section, and made no
specific provision whatever as to the proof of secured debts, but
simply provided that
"all creditors coming in and proving their debts under such
bankruptcy in the manner hereinafter prescribed, the same being
bona fide debts, shall be entitled to share in the
bankrupt's property and effects,
pro rata, without any
priority or preference whatsoever except only for debts due by such
bankrupt to the United States, and for all debts due by him to
persons who, by the laws of the United States, have a preference in
consequence of having paid moneys as his sureties, which shall be
first paid out of the assets."
Act of August 19, 1841, c. 9, § 5, 5 Stat. 444.
Yet Mr. Justice Story, both in the circuit court and in this
Court, laid it down as an undoubted rule that a secured creditor
could prove only for the rest of the debt after deducting the value
of the security given him by the bankrupt himself of his own
property.
In re Babcock (1844), 3 Story 393, 399-400;
In re Christy
(1845), 3 How. 292,
44 U. S.
315.
The omission by that eminent jurist, when framing the act of
1841, of all specific provisions on the subject as unnecessary, and
his repeated judicial declarations, after he had been habitually
administering that act for three or four years, recognizing that
rule as still in force, compel the inference that a general
enactment for the ratable distribution of the estate of an
insolvent among all the creditors had the effect of preventing any
individual creditor, while retaining collateral security on part of
the estate, from proving for his whole debt.
In 1864, Congress, in the first national bank act, after
providing for the appointment of a receiver with power to convert
the assets of any insolvent national bank into money and pay it to
the Treasurer of the United States, subject to the order of the
Comptroller of the Currency, further provided that:
"From time to time, the Comptroller, after full provision
shall
Page 173 U. S. 176
have been first made for refunding to the United States any such
deficiency in redeeming the notes of such association as is
mentioned in this act, shall make a ratable dividend of the money
so paid over to him by such receiver on all such claims as may have
been proved to his satisfaction or adjudicated in a court of
competent jurisdiction."
Act of June 3, 1864, c. 106, § 50, 13 Stat. 115.
The words of this act requiring "a ratable dividend" to be paid
"on all claims" proved or adjudicated are equivalent to the words
of the last preceding bankrupt act directing that "all creditors
coming in and proving their debts . . . shall be entitled to share"
in the estate "
pro rata, without any priority or
preference whatsoever," and, in view of the judicial construction
which had been given to that act, may reasonably be considered as
having been intended by Congress to have the same effect of
preventing a creditor, secured on part of the estate, from proving
his whole debt without relinquishing or applying the security,
although neither act specifically so provided.
If such was the rule under the National Bank Act of 1864, it
could not be affected, as to national banks, by the express
affirmance of the rule in the Bankrupt Act of 1867, or by the
reenactment of the provisions of each of these two acts in the
Revised Statutes. And the extension of the Bankrupt Act of 1867 to
"moneyed business or commercial corporations and joint-stock
companies" increases the improbability that Congress intended
banking associations to be governed by a different rule from that
governing other private corporations, as well as natural persons,
in regard to the effect which a creditor's holding collateral
security should have upon the sum to be proved by him against an
insolvent estate. Act of March 2, 1867, c. 176, §§ 20, 37, 14 Stat.
526, 535; Rev.Stat. §§ 5075, 5236.
Reliance has been placed upon the remark of Mr. Justice Swayne
in
Lewis v. United States, 92 U. S.
618,
92 U. S. 623,
that
"it is a settled principle in equity that a creditor holding
collaterals is not bound to apply them before enforcing his direct
remedies against the debtor."
But he added, "This
Page 173 U. S. 177
is admitted," so that it is evident that the point was not
controverted by counsel or much considered by the Court. Nor was it
necessary to the decision, which had nothing to do with the right
of an individual creditor holding security upon the separate
property of the debtor, to prove against his estate in bankruptcy,
but simply affirmed the right of the United States, holding a debt
against an English partnership, to prove the whole amount of the
debt against one of the partners, an American, in proceedings in
bankruptcy here under the act of 1867, without surrendering or
accounting for collateral security given to the United States by
the partnership. The United States were not bound by the bankrupt
acts, nor subject to the rule of a ratable distribution, but were
entitled to preference over all other creditors.
United
States v. Fisher, 2 Cranch 358;
Harrison v.
Sterry, 5 Cranch 289;
United
States v. State Bank, 6 Pet. 29;
United
States v. Herron, 20 Wall. 251. And even as to a
private creditor, it has always been held that he is obliged to
account for such securities only as he holds from the debtor
against whose estate he seeks to prove, and that a creditor proving
against the estate of a partnership is not bound to account for
security given to him by one partner, nor a creditor proving
against the estate of one partner to account for security given him
by the partnership.
Ex Parte Peacock (1825), 2 Glyn &
Jameson 27;
In re Plummer (1841), 1 Phil.Ch. 56;
Rolfe
v. Flower (1866), L.R. 1 P.C. 27, 46;
In re Babcock,
3 Story 393, 400. To require a creditor, before proving against the
estate of one partner, to surrender to the assignee of that estate
security held from the partnership would be to add to the separate
estate property which should go to the estate of the
partnership.
The ground and the limits of the rule in bankruptcy were clearly
stated by Lord Chancellor Lyndhurst in
Plummer's case,
above cited, in which a partnership creditor was allowed to prove a
partnership debt against the separate estate of each partner
without surrendering or realizing security held by him from the
partnership. The Lord Chancellor said:
"Now what are the principles applicable to cases of this kind?
If
Page 173 U. S. 178
a creditor of a bankrupt holds a security on part of the
bankrupt's estate, he is not entitled to prove his debt under the
commission without giving up or realizing his security. For the
principle of the bankrupt laws is that all creditors are to be put
on an equal footing, and therefore, if a creditor chooses to prove
under the commission, he must sell or surrender whatever property
he holds belonging to the bankrupt. But if he has a security on the
estate of a third person, that principle does not apply. He is in
that case entitled to prove for the whole amount of his debt, and
also to realize the security, provided he does not altogether
receive more than twenty shillings in the pound. That is the ground
on which the principle is established. It is unnecessary to cite
authorities for it, as it is too clearly settled to be disputed,
but I may mention
Ex Parte Bennet, 2 Atk. 527,
Ex
Parte Parr, 1 Rose 76, and
Ex Parte Goodman, 3
Maddock 373, in which it has been laid down. The next point is
this: in administration under bankruptcy, the joint estate and the
separate estate are considered as distinct estates, and accordingly
it has been held that a joint creditor, having a security upon the
separate estate, is entitled to prove against the joint estate
without giving up his security, on the ground that it is a
different estate. That was the principle upon which
Ex Parte
Peacock proceeded, and that case was decided first by Sir John
Leach and afterwards by Lord Eldon, and has since been followed in
Ex Parte Bowden, 1 Deacon & Chitty 135. Now this case
is merely the converse of that, and the same principle applies to
it."
1 Phil.Ch. 59, 60.
This Court, under the existing national bank act, approving and
following the example of the English courts under the statute of 13
Elizabeth, above cited, has allowed creditors to set off, against
their claims on the estate, debts due from them to the debtor whose
estate is in course of distribution, although the statute in
question in either case contained no provision directing or
permitting a set-off.
Scott v. Armstrong, 146 U.
S. 499,
146 U. S. 511.
In giving effect to a statute which simply directs an equal and
ratable distribution of a debtor's estate among all creditors,
without saying anything about either collateral
Page 173 U. S. 179
security or set-off, there would seem to be quite as much ground
for requiring each creditor to account for his collateral security,
for the benefit of all the creditors, as for allowing him the
benefit of a set-off, to their detriment.
For the reasons thus indicated, I cannot avoid the conclusion
that under every act of Congress directing the ratable distribution
among all creditors of the estate of an insolvent person or
corporation, and making no special provision as to secured
creditors, an individual creditor holding collateral security from
the debtor on part of the estate in course of administration is not
entitled to a dividend upon the whole of his debt without releasing
the security or deducting its value, and that therefore the
judgment of the circuit Court of Appeals should be reversed.