1. A price-fixing combination of competitors in interstate trade
violates the Sherman Act. P.
316 U. S.
274.
2. Acceptance by competitors, without previous agreement, of an
invitation to participate in a plan, the necessary consequence of
which, if carried out, will be restraint of interstate commerce
renders them liable as conspirators under the Sherman Act. P.
316 U. S.
275.
The fixing of prices by one member of a group pursuant to
express delegation, acquiescence, or understanding of the others is
no less illegal than if done by their direct joint action. P.
316 U. S.
276.
Page 316 U. S. 266
4. A combination fixing prices in interstate commerce cannot be
justified by business reasons or by its tendency to increase
distribution of the commodity without increase of price to
consumers, or by its tendency to promote competition between
dealers. P.
316 U. S.
276.
5. A patent affords no immunity for a monopoly not plainly
within the grant, and the grant cannot be extended by contract. P.
316 U. S.
277.
6. When a patented article is disposed of to a purchaser, it
passes beyond the monopoly protected by the patent law. P.
316 U. S.
277.
7. A determination as to whether a particular disposition of a
patented article exhausts the patent monopoly is not governed by
the form of the transaction, but depends upon whether there has
been such a disposition that it may fairly be said the patentee has
received his reward for the use of the article. P.
316 U. S.
278.
8. In making such a determination, regard must be had for the
dominant concern of the patent system,
viz., promotion of
the progress of science and the useful arts; the reward to the
inventor is secondary, and merely a means to an end. P.
316 U. S.
278.
9. The scope of the patentee's statutory right to "vend" cannot
be determined by the private law of sales alone. Such rights must
be strictly construed, since patents are privileges restrictive of
a free economy. P.
316 U. S.
280.
10. Numerous corporations which were in active competition with
each other as dealers in building materials entered into a
combination whereby one of them, which manufactured and sold
material called "hardboard" for which it held a patent, undertook
to constitute the others its
del credere agents for the
sale of that product through their respective sales organizations
at prices fixed by the patent owner.
Held, that this
arrangement went beyond the patent privilege and violated the
Sherman Act.
United States v. General Electric Co.,
272 U. S. 476,
distinguished. Pp.
316 U. S. 280,
316 U. S.
282.
40 F. Supp. 852 reversed.
Appeal from a decree of the District Court which dismissed a
bill brought by the United States under the Sherman Act.
Page 316 U. S. 267
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS delivered the opinion of the Court.
The question presented by this case is whether appellees have
combined to restrain trade or commerce in violation of §§ 1 and 2
of the Sherman Act. 15 U.S.C. §§ 1, 2, 26 Stat. 209. The bill to
enjoin the alleged violations of the Act was dismissed by the
District Court (40 F.Supp. 852) on the authority of
United
States v. General Electric Co., 272 U.
S. 476. The case is here on appeal. 15 U.S.C. § 29, 32
Stat. 823, 36 Stat. 1167; 28 U.S.C. § 345, Judicial Code, §
238.
The appellees are Masonite Corporation, Celotex Corporation,
Certain-Teed Products Corporation, Johns-Manville Sales
Corporation, Insulite Company, Flintkote Company, National Gypsum
Company, Wood Conversion Company, Armstrong Cork Company, and Dant
& Russell, Inc. Each is engaged either in manufacturing and
selling building materials, or in selling building materials
manufactured by others. All maintain selling organizations and to a
large extent compete in the same markets. As we shall see, some
have competing patents, though others do not. Masonite is a
manufacturer and distributor of hardboard. Hardboard -- a
homogeneous, hard, dense, grainless, synthetic board -- is made
from wood chips. It has a high tensile strength, low water
absorption, and a density that ranges from 30 to 60 lbs. per
Page 316 U. S. 268
cubic foot. It is used in the building industry as wallboard,
paneling, flooring, ceilings, and forms into which concrete is
poured. It also has numerous industrial uses. Masonite began its
production of hardboard in 1926. and distributed it through its own
selling organization. Between March 30, 1926, and March 20, 1928,
four patents were issued to it, the claims of which covered both
hardboard and the processes for making it. Celotex, for some period
prior to 1928, had been manufacturing and selling insulation board
-- a fibre board which has a density of less than 30 lbs. per cubic
foot and which is softer and lighter, has a lower tensile strength,
and is less resistant to water than hardboard. In 1928, Celotex
announced that it intended to begin the manufacture of hardboard
from bagasse, a waste product from the grinding of sugar cane. It
began production in 1929. Several patents were issued to it. Late
in 1928, Masonite notified Celotex that its hardboard infringed
Masonite's patents. Various discussions were had with a view of
avoiding patent litigation by entering into a cross-licensing
agreement. Masonite refused. Celotex continued to manufacture and
sell hardboard. Its production increased from about 800,000 square
feet in 1929 to about 12,000,000 square feet in 1933. It sold its
product in competition with Masonite's hardboard and marketed it at
prices lower than Masonite sold its hardboard. In 1931, Masonite
instituted suit against Celotex for infringement of one of its
patents. The District Court held Masonite's patent valid, but not
infringed.
Masonite Corp. v. Celotex Co., 1 F. Supp. 494.
Masonite appealed. The Circuit Court of Appeals held that
Masonite's patent was both valid and infringed. 66 F.2d 451. A
petition for a writ of certiorari was filed in this Court in
September, 1933. About that time, Masonite renewed negotiations
with Celotex. Those negotiations resulted in a settlement of the
patent litigation and in the execution of the so-called
Page 316 U. S. 269
"agency" agreement of October 10, 1933 [
Footnote 1] -- one of the agreements which is here
attacked and which we discuss later.
Shortly after the decision of the Circuit Court of Appeals in
the patent litigation between Celotex and Masonite, the latter
company sent the same proposed "agency" agreement which it had
worked out with Celotex to various of the appellees. Johns-Manville
Sales Corporation, National Gypsum Company, Armstrong Newport
Company (predecessor of Armstrong Cork Company), Hawaiian Cane
Products Ltd. (assignor of Certain-Teed Products Corporation), and
Wood Conversion Company each executed identical agreements with
Masonite on various dates between October 31, 1933, and June 25,
1934. As each agreement was made, Masonite informed the other party
of the existence and terms of each of the agreements which Masonite
had previously made with the others. And as each contract was
executed, Masonite sent copies to the companies which had
previously executed similar contracts.
Insulite, a manufacturer of insulation board, began producing
hardboard in 1930. Its production rose from about 4,500,000 square
feet in 1932 to about 9,000,000 square feet in 1933, and amounted
to over 7,000,000 square feet annually in 1934 and 1935. There was
some evidence that it was selling hardboard at prices lower than
those of Masonite. It was advised by Masonite in July, 1933, of
possible legal action if it continued to manufacture and sell
hardboard. It received from Masonite a copy of the proposed
"agency" agreement. It formally advised Masonite
Page 316 U. S. 270
of its refusal to enter into any such agreement in December,
1933. In March, 1934, Masonite filed suit against a dealer who
handled Insulite's hardboard charging infringement of one of
Masonite's patents. Insulite undertook the defense, but before
issue was joined, negotiations between Insulite and Masonite
resulted in the execution in February, 1935, of a so-called
"agency" agreement substantially identical with the agreement
between Masonite and Celotex. [
Footnote 2] At that time, Insulite knew that Masonite and
the other companies had previously executed the other
agreements.
Disputes arose between Masonite and the so-called "agents"
concerning the operation and construction of the "agency"
agreements. As a result, the agreements were modified in 1936. Each
agreement, when executed in 1936, was placed in escrow. The escrow
agreement was signed by each of the companies and included the name
of each of the other "agents." Each "agent" knew at that time that
Masonite proposed to make substantially identical agreements with
the others. The escrow agreement provided that it should become
effective only when all the "agents" had agreed to it. The new
agreements became effective October 29, 1936. In 1937, Flintkote
Company and Dant & Russell, Inc., entered into identical
agreements with Masonite. Though their agreements differed somewhat
from the 1936 agreements, they were substantially similar for
present purposes. Both companies knew when they signed the
contracts that similar "agency" agreements existed between Masonite
and the other appellees.
By each of the 1933, agreements Masonite designated the other
party as an "agent" and appointed it as a "
del
Page 316 U. S. 271
credere factor" to sell Masonite's hardboard products.
The "agent" expressly acknowledged the validity of Masonite's
hardboard patents so long as the agreement remained in force. The
"agent" agreed to promote the sale of Masonite hardboards. Masonite
agreed to manufacture designated hardboard products in specified
sizes, and to ship on orders and specifications from the "agent" to
any place within the continental United States or Hawaii. Masonite
agreed to designate from time to time the minimum selling price and
the maximum terms and conditions of sale at which the "agent" might
sell Masonite's products. The list prices and terms of sale were to
be the minimum prices and maximum terms of sale at which Masonite
was either offering or making sales to its customers. The right to
change the list prices and terms of sale was vested solely in
Masonite, and might be exercised on 10 days' notice. It was agreed
that Masonite was bound to adhere to the prices, and terms and
conditions of sale which it fixed for its "agents." In case the
"agent" sold for less than the minimum price, it was obligated to
pay liquidated damages at a specified rate. On direct shipments to
the "agent," the hardboards "shall be received and held on
consignment," and "title thereto shall remain" in Masonite until
sold by the "agent." The minimum prices were f.o.b. Masonite's
factory, the "agent" paying freight and transportation costs and
sales and other taxes. The "agent" also agreed at its expense to
carry insurance on all products consigned to it. The "agent's"
compensation was fixed by way of specified commissions on each
sale. The "agent" was prohibited from making sales (except for
off-sized boards) to any person other than specified classes. Those
provisions permitted the "agent" to sell only to the construction
industry, the industrial market being reserved for Masonite. The
"agent" agreed to compensate Masonite by advancing one-half of the
difference between the list price and the agent's discount within
20
Page 316 U. S. 272
days after the close of the month in which the order was shipped
and the balance within 20 days after the close of the month in
which the products were sold by the "agent" to its customers. In
case of direct shipments by Masonite to the customers of the
"agent," the latter agreed to pay the entire amount due Masonite
within 20 days after the close of the month in which the shipment
was made. The "agent" agreed not to use the tradename or the
trademarks of Masonite. But the latter agreed to mark, without
extra cost, all hardboard with the "agent's" or its customer's name
or trademark if the "agent" or customers so desired. And Masonite
reserved the right to mark all products sold by the "agent" with
Masonite's patent notice. Masonite warranted that the products were
to be "good, workmanlike products of a character and quality equal
to that currently manufactured by it and sold to its customers."
Its liability was to be limited to replacing without cost to the
"agent" any "defective material when the defect is one of
manufacture." The "agent" agreed to make monthly reports on
inventory consigned and on hand. For any default of the "agent,"
Masonite could terminate the arrangement on 30 days' notice.
Masonite could also terminate in case of the bankruptcy,
receivership, or insolvency of the "agent" or in case the "agent"
failed to order from Masonite at least 1,500,000 square feet of
hardboard products for any six months' period. The "agent" could
terminate the agreement on six months' written notice. On
termination of the agreement, the "agent" agreed to "purchase and
pay for all products consigned to it and unsold," or, at the option
of Masonite, the latter might have the products returned to it and
refund to the "agent" all advances made by the "agent" to or for
Masonite's account. Masonite agreed to issue to the "agent" at its
request "a license to manufacture and sell hard boards" under its
patents on specified terms and conditions and on payment of
designated sums -- $200,000 if
Page 316 U. S. 273
the license was issued before December 31, 1934, and decreasing
amounts if the license was issued at subsequent dates. Masonite
reserved the right to inspect and examine, through certified public
accountants, the physical inventory and the books and records of
the "agent" relating to the transactions covered by the agreement.
Masonite agreed to save harmless and protect the "agent" and its
customers against any claim that the hardboards infringed any
patent owned by others than the parties to the agreement.
Provisions for arbitration and for assignment of the agreement were
included. And it was provided that the agreement should continue
"during the life of that one" of specified patents of Masonite
"having the longest term to run, including any reissues, extensions
or improvements thereof," unless the agreement was sooner
terminated by either party. Each agreement had attached a form of
"license" to manufacture and sell to be used in case the option
license was exercised. [
Footnote
3]
Page 316 U. S. 274
We need not stop to analyze the 1936 agreements. They contained
numerous changes and elaborations. But they are not important for
the purposes of this case, since the pattern of the relationship
between appellees was fixed in 1933 and its fundamental
characteristics were maintained, not basically altered, in 1936.
Nor need we stop to explore all of the contentions made by the
United States. They include arguments that there has been an
illegal division of markets (
Addyston Pipe & Steel Co. v.
United States, 175 U. S. 211);
that the "agency" agreements have been used to control unlawfully
other materials sold in combination with hardboard, the subject
matter of Masonite's patents (
Carbice Corp. v. American Patents
Dev. Corp., 283 U. S. 27);
that, in some instances, the combination unlawfully controlled the
price of hardboard "owned" by the "agents" (
Ethyl Gasoline
Corp. v. United States, 309 U. S. 436),
and that the arrangement included agreements to suppress the use of
patents contrary to the rule of
Standard Sanitary Mfg. Co. v.
United States, 226 U. S. 20, and
Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 283 U.
S. 163,
283 U. S. 174.
But we can put these contentions to one side without expressing an
opinion on them. For there is one phase of the case which is
decisive. That is the agreement for price-fixing.
But for Masonite's patents and the
del credere agency
agreements there can be no doubt that this is a price-fixing
combination which is illegal
per se under the Sherman Act.
United States v. Trenton Potteries Co., 273 U.
S. 392;
Ethyl Gasoline Corp. v. United States,
309 U. S. 436;
United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.
S. 150. That is true though the District Court found
that,
Page 316 U. S. 275
in negotiating and entering into the first agreements, each
appellee, other than Masonite, acted independently of the others,
negotiated only with Masonite, desired the agreement regardless of
the action that might be taken by any of the others, did not
require as a condition of its acceptance that Masonite make such an
agreement with any of the others, and had no discussions with any
of the others. It is not clear at what precise point of time each
appellee became aware of the fact that its contract was not an
isolated transaction but part of a larger arrangement. But it is
clear that, as the arrangement continued, each became familiar with
its purpose and scope. Here, as in
Interstate Circuit, Inc. v.
United States, 306 U. S. 208,
306 U. S.
226,
"It was enough that, knowing that concerted action was
contemplated and invited, the distributors gave their adherence to
the scheme and participated in it."
The circumstances surrounding the making of the 1936 agreements
and the joinder in 1937 of the two other companies leave no room
for doubt that all had an awareness of the general scope and
purpose of the undertaking. As this Court stated in the
Interstate Circuit case (p.
306 U. S.
227):
"It is elementary that an unlawful conspiracy may be and often
is formed without simultaneous action or agreement on the part of
the conspirators. . . . Acceptance by competitors, without previous
agreement, of an invitation to participate in a plan, the necessary
consequence of which, if carried out, is restraint of interstate
commerce, is sufficient to establish an unlawful conspiracy under
the Sherman Act."
And, as respects statements of various appellees that they did
not intend to join a combination or to fix prices, we need only say
that they "must be held to have intended the necessary and direct
consequences of their acts, and cannot be heard to say the
contrary."
United States v. Patten, 226 U.
S. 525,
226 U. S. 543.
Nor can the fact that Masonite alone fixed the prices and that the
other appellees never consulted with Masonite
Page 316 U. S. 276
concerning them make the combination any the less illegal.
Prices are fixed when they are agreed upon.
United States v.
Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., supra, p.
310 U. S. 222.
The fixing of prices by one member of a group pursuant to express
delegation, acquiescence, or understanding is just as illegal as
the fixing of prices by direct, joint action.
Id. Since
there was price-fixing, the fact that there were business reasons
which made the arrangements desirable to the appellees, the fact
that the effect of the combination may have been to increase the
distribution of hardboard without increase of price to the
consumer, or even to promote competition between dealers, or the
fact that, from other points of view, the arrangements might be
deemed to have desirable consequences would be no more a legal
justification for price-fixing than were the "competitive evils" in
the
Socony-Vacuum case.
But it is urged that the arrangement is saved from the Sherman
Act by the
General Electric case. The District Court so
held, as we have noted. In that connection, the District Court
found that Masonite's patents on hardboard were "fundamental and
basic," that there was no monopoly or restraint other than the
monopoly or restraint granted by the patents, that the parties had
an honest and sincere intent to recognize and exercise the rights
belonging to Masonite under its patents, and that the agreements
constituted a "true agency" to carry out that purpose. We assume
arguendo that the patents in question, owned by Masonite,
are valid. But we do not agree that the "agency" device saved the
arrangement from the Sherman Act.
Del credere agency has an ancient lineage, and has been
put to numerous business and mercantile uses. Chorley,
Del
Credere, 45 Law Quarterly Rev. 221; Mechem, Agency,2d Ed. ch.
IV. But, however useful it may be in allocating risks between the
parties and determining their rights
inter se, its terms
do not necessarily control
Page 316 U. S. 277
when the rights of others intervene, whether they be creditors
or the sovereign.
See Klaus, Sale, Agency and Price
Maintenance, 28 Col.L.Rev. 441, 443-450. We assume in this case
that the agreements constituted the appellees as
del
credere agents of Masonite. But that circumstance does not
prevent the arrangement from running afoul of the Sherman Act. The
owner of a patent cannot extend his statutory grant by contract or
agreement. A patent affords no immunity for a monopoly not fairly
or plainly within the grant. We have recently stated in
Morton
Salt Co. v. Suppiger Co., 314 U. S. 488,
that
"the public policy which includes inventions within the granted
monopoly excludes from it all that is not embraced in the
invention. It equally forbids the use of the patent to secure an
exclusive right or limited monopoly not granted by the Patent
Office and which it is contrary to public policy to grant."
Beyond the limited monopoly which is granted, the arrangements
by which the patent is utilized are subject to the general law.
Standard Sanitary Mfg. Co. v. United States, supra; Boston
Store v. American Graphophone Co., 246 U. S.
8,
246 U. S. 25;
Ethyl Gasoline Corp. v. United States, supra.
We do not have here any question as to the validity of a license
to manufacture and sell, since none of the "agents" exercised its
option to acquire such a license from Masonite. Hence, we need not
reach the problems presented by
Bement & Sons v. National
Harrow Co., 186 U. S. 70, and
that part of the
General Electric case which dealt with
the license to Westinghouse Company. Rather, we are concerned here
only with a license to vend. But it will not do to say that, since
the patentee has the power to refuse a license, he has the lesser
power to license on his own conditions. There are strict
limitations on the power of the patentee to attach conditions to
the use of the patented article. As Chief Justice Taney said in
Bloomer v.
McQuewan, 14 How. 539,
55 U. S. 549,
when the patented product
Page 316 U. S. 278
"passes to the hands of the purchaser, it is no longer within
the limits of the monopoly. It passes outside of it, and is no
longer under the protection of the act of Congress."
And see 84 U. S.
Burke, 17 Wall. 453;
Hobbie v. Jennison, 149 U.
S. 355. In applying that rule, this Court has quite
consistently refused to allow the form into which the parties chose
to cast the transaction to govern. The test has been whether or not
there has been such a disposition of the article that it may fairly
be said that the patentee has received his reward for the use of
the article.
Straus v. Victor Talking Machine Co.,
243 U. S. 490;
Boston Store v. American Graphophone Co., supra. And
see United States v. Univis Lens Co., Inc., ante, p.
316 U. S. 241. In
determining whether or not a particular transaction comes within
the rule of the
Bloomer case, regard must be had for the
dominant concern of the patent system. As stated by Mr. Justice
Story in
Pennock v.
Dialogue, 2 Pet. 1,
27 U. S. 19, the
promotion of the progress of science and the useful arts is the
"main object;" reward of inventors is secondary, and merely a means
to that end. Or, in the words of Mr. Justice Daniel in
Kendall v.
Winsor, 21 How. 322,
62 U. S.
329,
"Whilst the remuneration of genius and useful ingenuity is a
duty incumbent upon the public, the rights and welfare of the
community must be fairly dealt with and effectually guarded.
Considerations of individual emolument can never be permitted to
operate to the injury of these."
And see Blount Mfg. Co. v. Yale & Towne Mfg. Co.,
166 F. 555.
That must be the point of departure for decision on the facts of
cases such as the present one lest the limited patent privilege be
enlarged by private agreements so as to bypass the Sherman Act.
Ethyl Gasoline Corp. v. United States, supra, pp.
309 U. S.
456-459. Certainly, if the
del credere agency
device were given broad approval, whole industries could be knit
together so as to regulate prices and suppress competition. That
would allow the patent
Page 316 U. S. 279
owner, under the guise of his patent monopoly, not merely to
secure a reward for his invention but to secure protection from
competition which the patent law, unaided by restrictive
agreements, does not afford. Doubtless there is a proper area for
utilization by a patentee of a
del credere agent in the
sale or disposition of the patented article. A patentee who employs
such an agent to distribute his product certainly is not enlarging
the scope of his patent privilege if it may fairly be said that
that distribution is part of the patentee's own business and
operates only to secure to him the reward for his invention which
Congress has provided. But where he utilizes the sales organization
of another business -- a business with which he has no intimate
relationship -- quite different problems are posed, since such a
regimentation of a marketing system is peculiarly susceptible to
the restraints of trade which the Sherman Act condemns. And when it
is clear, as it is in this case, that the marketing systems
utilized by means of the
del credere agency agreements are
those of competitors of the patentee, and that the purpose is to
fix prices at which the competitors may market the product, the
device is, without more, an enlargement of the limited patent
privilege and a violation of the Sherman Act. In such a case, the
patentee exhausts his limited privilege when he disposes of the
product to the
del credere agent. He then has, so far as
the Sherman Act is concerned, no greater rights to price
maintenance [
Footnote 4] than
the owner of an unpatented commodity would have.
Dr.
Page 316 U. S. 280
Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Parks & Sons Co.,
220 U. S. 373. Our
reasons for that conclusion are as follows:
Congress has provided that a patentee shall have the "exclusive
right to make, use, and vend the invention or discovery" for a
limited period. 46 Stat. 376, 35 U.S.C. § 40. But the scope of the
right to "vend" cannot be determined by reference to the private
law of sales alone. Since patents are privileges restrictive of a
free economy, the rights which Congress has attached to them must
be strictly construed so as not to derogate from the general law
beyond the necessary requirements of the patent statute.
United
States v. Univis Lens Co., Inc., supra. So far as the Sherman
Act is concerned, the result must turn not on the skill with which
counsel has manipulated the concepts of "sale" and "agency," but on
the significance of the business practices in terms of restraint of
trade.
In this case, some of the appellees had patents on hardboard,
some did not. But each was tied to Masonite by an agreement which
expressly recognized the validity of Masonite's patents during the
life of the agreement and which required the distribution of the
patented product at fixed prices. In the
General Electric
case, the Court thought that the purpose and effect of the
marketing plan was to secure to the patentee only a reward for his
invention. We cannot agree that that is true here. In this case,
the price regulation was based on mutual agreement among
distributors of competing products, some of whom had competing
patents, as we have noted. None of these patents, except possibly
some held by Celotex, had been held to conflict with or infringe
the Masonite patents. Nor are we warranted in assuming, in absence
of a a definite adjudication, that one grant by the Patent Office
is more valid than another. It is true that the District Court
found that, both before and after the agreements in question, the
various appellees had been active in attempting to find a
substitute for the patented hardboard
Page 316 U. S. 281
which would not infringe Masonite's so-called "basic" patents;
that they were not successful in that search; that the agreements
did not discourage or dissuade them from their efforts to discover
or develop noninfringing products; that they were willing and
intended to terminate their respective agency agreements whenever
it should become commercially possible to offer a competitive
noninfringing product, and that many of the appellees have, in fact
distributed products which were in many respects competitive with
hardboard. But those circumstances are not controlling.
The power of Masonite to fix the price of the product which it
manufactures, and which the entire group sells and with respect to
which all have been and are now actual or potential competitors, is
a powerful inducement to abandon competition. The extent to which
that inducement in a given case will have or has had the desired
effect is difficult, if not impossible, of measurement. The forces
which that influence puts to work are subtle and incalculable.
Active and vigorous competition then tend to be impaired not from
any preference of the public for the patented product, but from the
preference of the competitors for a mutual arrangement for
price-fixing which promises more profit if the parties abandon,
rather than maintain, competition. The presence of competing
patents serves merely to accentuate that tendency and to underline
the potency of the forces at work. Control over prices thus becomes
an actual or potential brake on competition. This kind of marketing
device thus actually or potentially throttles or suppresses
competing and noninfringing products, and tends to place a premium
on the abandonment of competition. It is outside our competence to
inquire whether the result was or was not beneficent, or whether
the evil was or was not realized. As in case of an appraisal of the
reasonableness of prices which
Page 316 U. S. 282
are fixed, such a determination could satisfactorily be made
"only after a complete survey of our economic organization and a
choice between rival philosophies" (
United States v. Trenton
Potteries Co., supra, 273 U.S. at p.
273 U. S. 398)
and only after weighing a host of intangibles.
United States v.
Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., supra. The power of this type of
combination to inflict the kind of public injury which the Sherman
Act condemns renders it illegal
per se. If it were
sanctioned in this situation, it would permit the patentee to add
to his domain at public expense by obtaining command over a
competitor. He would then not only secure a reward for his
invention; he would enhance the value of his own trade position by
eliminating or impairing competition. That would be no more
permissible than a contract between a copyright owner and one who
has no copyright, or a contract between two copyright owners or
patentees, to restrain the competitive distribution of the
copyrighted or patented articles in the open market.
Interstate
Circuit, Inc. v. United States, supra, p.
306 U. S. 230.
As stated in
Standard Sanitary Mfg. Co. v. United States,
supra, 226 U.S. at p.
226 U. S. 49, rights conferred by patents
"do not give any more than other rights a universal license
against positive prohibitions. The Sherman law is a limitation of
rights, rights which may be pushed to evil consequences, and
therefore restrained."
Since the transactions here challenged were in interstate
commerce, no question as to the violation of the Sherman Act
remains.
But it is urged that the agreements made by the appellees in
1941, after the present suit was instituted, mark an abandonment of
the former combination, and that, since the new arrangement is
unobjectionable, there is nothing to enjoin. The difficulty with
that contention is that the 1941 agreements, though improved models
of an agency arrangement, removed none of the features which we
have found to be fatal. They still are unmistakable
Page 316 U. S. 283
price-fixing agreements with competitors. And if there were any
lingering doubt as to whether the appellees were parties to a
conspiracy, it is dispelled at this point. A committee of the
appellees was appointed to draft the new agreement. The agreement
was completed after meetings at which representatives of all of the
appellees attended. The 1941 agreements were the product of joint
and concerted action.
Reversed.
MR. JUSTICE ROBERTS and MR. JUSTICE JACKSON did not participate
in the consideration or decision of this case.
[
Footnote 1]
In 1932, receivers for Celotex were appointed by the United
States District Court for the District of Delaware and an ancillary
receiver was appointed by the United States District Court for the
Northern District of Illinois. The agreement with Masonite was
authorized by those courts.
[
Footnote 2]
At the time Insulite entered into this agreement with Masonite,
its parent company was in receivership in the United States
District Court for the District of Minnesota. The receivership
court authorized Insulite to execute the agreement with
Masonite.
[
Footnote 3]
There were in some cases supplemental agreements. Thus, Celotex
agreed to withdraw its petition for a writ of certiorari in this
Court, Masonite waived an accounting in connection with that
infringement suit, and each of the parties agreed to pay its own
costs and expenses incurred in that litigation. In the case of
Insulite, Masonite agreed to dismiss the patent suit which it had
instituted against one of Insulite's dealers without prejudice to
the patent claims of either party. Masonite also agreed to purchase
a press from Insulite and to lease that press to Insulite on
condition that any hardboard made with it should be of the type
theretofore manufactured by Insulite and should not be marketed
except "by sale for export only." Masonite could terminate
Insulite's right to manufacture for export by offering to sell
Insulite hardboard for that purpose. This agreement was without
prejudice to Masonite's rights or the rights of its foreign
licensees under Masonite's foreign patents.
In 1937, both Insulite and Masonite had applications for patents
relating to hardboard pending in the Patent Office. Certain claims
of these applications were involved in interference proceedings.
Masonite was contending that Insulite was infringing its patents in
Finland. By contract, the interference proceedings were settled in
1938 by Masonite's conceding priority to certain patent claims of
Insulite and by Insulite's giving Masonite as exclusive
royalty-free license under all of Insulite's patents and patent
applications relating to hardboard. The license excluded Insulite
from using the patents. The alleged infringement of the Finnish
patents was settled by Masonite's assigning its Finnish patents to
Insulite.
[
Footnote 4]
It should be noted in this connection that the Miller-Tydings
Act, 50 Stat. 693, which amended § 1 of the Sherman Act so as to
legalize certain types of resale price agreements expressly
excluded
"any contract or agreement, providing for the establishment or
maintenance of minimum resale prices on any commodity herein
involved, between manufacturers, or between producers, or between
wholesalers, or between brokers, or between factors, or between
retailers, or between persons, firms, or corporations in
competition with each other."