A trustee of an estate created by the will of a decedent
domiciled in Indiana at the time of his death instructed his
Indiana broker to arrange for the sale of certain securities at
stated prices. They were offered for sale on the New York Stock
Exchange through the Indiana broker's New York correspondents. When
a purchaser was found, the trustee delivered the securities in
Indiana to his Indiana broker, who mailed them to New York. The New
York brokers made delivery, received the purchase price, and
remitted the proceeds (less expense and commission) to the Indiana
broker, who delivered the proceeds (less commission) to the trustee
in Indiana.
Held:
1. The Indiana Gross Income Tax Act of 1933 cannot
constitutionally be applied to the gross receipts from these sales,
since it would constitute a direct burden on interstate commerce in
violation of the Commerce Clause. Pp.
329 U. S.
252-259.
2.
McGoldrick v. Berwind-White Co., 309 U. S.
33;
American Mfg. Co. v. St. Louis,
250 U. S. 459;
Harvester Co. v. Department of Treasury, 322 U.
S. 340, differentiated. Pp.
329 U. S.
257-258.
3. The Commerce Clause protects interstate sales of intangibles,
as well as interstate sales of tangibles. P.
329 U. S.
258.
221 Ind. 675, 51 N.E.2d 6, reversed.
Appeal from a decision of the Supreme Court of Indiana
sustaining application of the Indiana Gross Income Tax Act of 1933
to gross receipts from interstate sales of securities. 221 Ind.
675, 51 N.E.2d 6.
Reversed, p. 259.
Page 329 U. S. 250
MR. JUSTICE FRANKFURTER delivered the opinion of the Court.
This case presents another phase of the Indiana Gross Income Tax
Act of 1933, which has been before this Court in a series of cases
beginning with
Adams Mfg. Co. v. Storen, 304 U.
S. 307. The Act imposes a tax upon "the receipt of the
entire gross income" of residents and domiciliaries of Indiana, but
excepts from its scope
"[s]uch gross income as is derived from business conducted in
commerce between this state and other states of the United States .
. . to the extent to which the State of Indiana is prohibited from
taxing such gross income by the Constitution of the United
States."
Indiana Laws 1933, pp. 388, 392, as amended, Laws 1937, p. 615,
Burns' Ind.Stat.Anno. § 64-2601
et seq.
Appellant's predecessor, domiciled in Indiana, was trustee of an
estate created by the will of a decedent domiciled in Indiana at
the time of his death. During 1940, the trustee instructed his
Indiana broker to arrange for the sale at stated prices of
securities forming part of the trust estate. Through the broker's
New York correspondents, the securities were offered for sale on
the New York Stock Exchange. When a purchaser was found, the New
York brokers
Page 329 U. S. 251
notified the Indiana broker, who, in turn, informed the trustee,
and the latter brought the securities to his broker for mailing to
New York. Upon their delivery to the purchasers, the New York
brokers received the purchase price, which, after deducting
expenses and commission, they transmitted to the Indiana broker.
The latter delivered the proceeds, less his commission, to the
trustee. On the gross receipts of these sales, amounting to
$65,214.20, Indiana, under the Act of 1933, imposed a tax of 1%.
Having paid the tax under protest, the trustee brought this suit
for its recovery. The Supreme Court of Indiana, reversing a court
of first instance, sustained the tax on the ground that the situs
of the securities was in Indiana. 221 Ind. 675, 51 N.E.2d 6. The
case is here on appeal under § 237(a) of the Judicial Code, 28
U.S.C. 344(a), and has had the consideration which two arguments
afford.
The power of the States to tax and the limitations upon that
power imposed by the Commerce Clause have necessitated a long,
continuous process of judicial adjustment. The need for such
adjustment is inherent in a federal government like ours, where the
same transaction has aspects that may concern the interests and
involve the authority of both the central government and of the
constituent States.
*
Page 329 U. S. 252
The history of this problem is spread over hundreds of volumes
of our Reports. To attempt to harmonize all that has been said in
the past would neither clarify what has gone before not guide the
future. Suffice it to say that, especially in this field, opinions
must be read in the setting of the particular cases, and as the
product of preoccupation with their special facts.
Our starting point is clear. In two recent cases, we applied the
principle that the Commerce Clause was not merely an authorization
to Congress to enact laws for the protection and encouragement of
commerce among the States, but, by its own force, created an area
of trade free from interference by the States. In short, the
Commerce Clause, even without implementing legislation by Congress,
is a limitation upon the power of the States.
Southern Pacific
Co. v. Arizona, 325 U. S. 761;
Morgan v. Virginia, 328 U. S. 373. In
so deciding, we reaffirmed, upon fullest consideration, the course
of adjudication unbroken through the Nation's history. This
limitation on State power, as the
Morgan case so well
illustrates, does not merely forbid a State to single out
interstate commerce for hostile action. A State is also precluded
from taking any action which may fairly be deemed to have the
effect of impeding the free flow of trade between States. It is
immaterial that local commerce is subjected to a similar
encumbrance. It may commend itself to a State to encourage a
pastoral, instead of an industrial, society. That is its concern,
and its privilege. But to compare a State's treatment of its local
trade with the exertion of its authority against commerce in the
national domain is to compare incomparables.
These principles of limitation on State power apply to all State
policy, no matter what State interest gives rise to its
legislation. A burden on interstate commerce is none the lighter,
and no less objectionable, because it
Page 329 U. S. 253
is imposed by a State under the taxing power, rather than under
manifestations of police power in the conventional sense. But, in
the necessary accommodation between local needs and the overriding
requirement of freedom for the national commerce, the incidence of
a particular type of State action may throw the balance in support
of the local need because interference with the national interest
is remote or unsubstantial. A police regulation of local aspects of
interstate commerce is a power often essential to a State in
safeguarding vital local interests. At least until Congress chooses
to enact a nationwide rule, the power will not be denied to the
State.
The Minnesota Rate Cases, 230 U.
S. 352,
230 U. S. 402
et seq.; S.C. Hwy. Dept. v. Barnwell Bros.,
303 U. S. 177, ;
Union Brokerage Co. v. Jensen, 322 U.
S. 202,
322 U. S.
209-212. State taxation falling on interstate commerce,
on the other hand, can only be justified as designed to make such
commerce bear a fair share of the cost of the local government
whose protection it enjoys. But revenue serves as well no matter
what its source. To deny to a State a particular source of income
because it taxes the very process of interstate commerce does not
impose a crippling limitation on a State's ability to carry on its
local function. Moreover, the burden on interstate commerce
involved in a direct tax upon it is inherently greater, certainly
less uncertain in its consequences, than results from the usual
police regulations. The power to tax is a dominant power over
commerce. Because the greater or more threatening burden of a
direct tax on commerce is coupled with the lesser need to a State
of a particular source of revenue, attempts at such taxation have
always been more carefully scrutinized and more consistently
resisted than police power regulations of aspects of such commerce.
The task of scrutinizing is a task of drawing lines. This is the
historic duty of the
Page 329 U. S. 254
Court so long as Congress does not undertake to make specific
arrangements between the national government and the States in
regard to revenues from interstate commerce.
See Act of
July 3, 1944, 58 Stat. 723; H.Doc. 141, 79th Cong., 1st Sess.,
"Multiple Taxation of Air Commerce;"
and compare 54 Stat.
1059, 4 U.S.C. § 13
et seq. (permission to State to extend
taxing power to Federal areas). Considerations of proximity and
degree are here, as so often in the law, decisive.
It has been suggested that such a tax is valid when a similar
tax is placed on local trade, and a specious appearance of fairness
is sought to be imparted by the argument that interstate commerce
should not be favored at the expense of local trade. So to argue is
to disregard the life of the Commerce Clause. Of course, a State is
not required to give active advantage to interstate trade. But it
cannot aim to control that trade, even though it desires to control
its own. It cannot justify what amounts to a levy upon the very
process of commerce across State lines by pointing to a similar
hobble on its local trade. It is true that the existence of a tax
on its local commerce detracts from the deterrent effect of a tax
on interstate commerce to the extent that it removes the temptation
to sell the goods locally. But the fact of such a tax, in any
event, puts impediments upon the currents of commerce across the
State line, while the aim of the Commerce Clause was precisely to
prevent States from exacting toll from those engaged in national
commerce. The Commerce Clause does not involve an exercise in the
logic of empty categories. It operates within the framework of our
federal scheme, and with due regard to the national experience
reflected by the decisions of this Court, even though the terms in
which these decisions have been cast may have varied. Language
alters, and there is a fashion in judicial writing, as in other
things.
Page 329 U. S. 255
This case, like
Adams Mfg. Co. v. Storen, supra,
involves a tax imposed by the the seller on the proceeds of
interstate sales. To extract a fair tithe from interstate commerce
for the local protection afforded to it, a seller State need not
impose the kind of tax which Indiana here levied. As a practical
matter, it can make such commerce pay its way, as the phrase runs,
apart from taxing the very sale. Thus, it can tax local manufacture
even if the products are destined for other States. For some
purposes, manufacture and the shipment of its products beyond a
State may be looked upon as an integral transaction. But, when
accommodation must be made between state and national interests,
manufacture within a State, though destined for shipment outside,
is not a seamless web, so as to prevent a State from giving the
manufacturing part detached relevance for purposes of local
taxation.
American Mfg. Co. v. City of St. Louis,
250 U. S. 459;
Utah Power & L. Co. v. Pfost, 286 U.
S. 165. It can impose license taxes on domestic and
foreign corporations who would do business in the State,
Cheney
Brothers Co. v. Massachusetts, 246 U.
S. 147;
St. Louis Southwestern Ry. v. Arkansas,
235 U. S. 350,
235 U. S. 364,
though it cannot, even under the guise of such excises, "hamper"
interstate commerce.
Western Union Tel. Co. v. Kansas,
216 U. S. 1;
Pullman Co. v. Kansas, 216 U. S. 56
(particularly White, J. concurring at p. 63); Henderson, The
Position of Foreign Corporations in American Constitutional Law
(1918) 118-23, 128-31. It can tax the privilege of residence in the
State and measure the privilege by net income, including that
derived from interstate commerce.
United States Glue Co. v. Oak
Creek, 247 U. S. 321;
cf. Atlantic Coast Line v. Doughton, 262 U.
S. 413. And where, as in this case, the commodities
subsequently sold interstate are securities, they can be reached by
a property tax by the domicil of the owner.
Virginia
v. Imperial
Page 329 U. S. 256
Sales Co., 293 U. S. 15,
293 U. S. 19,
and see Citizens National Bank of Cincinnati v. Durr,
257 U. S. 99.
These illustrative instances show that a seller State has
various means of obtaining legitimate contribution to the costs of
its government, without imposing a direct tax on interstate sales.
While these permitted taxes may, in an ultimate sense, come out of
interstate commerce, they are not, as would be a tax on gross
receipts, a direct imposition on that very freedom of commercial
flow which for more than a hundred and fifty years has been the
ward of the Commerce Clause.
It is suggested, however, that the validity of a gross sales tax
should depend on whether another State has also sought to impose
its burden on the transactions. If another State has taxed the same
interstate transaction, the burdensome consequences to interstate
trade are undeniable. But that, for the time being, only one State
has taxed is irrelevant to the kind of freedom of trade which the
Commerce Clause generated. The immunities implicit in the Commerce
Clause and the potential taxing power of a State can hardly be made
to depend, in the world of practical affairs, on the shifting
incidence of the varying tax laws of the various States at a
particular moment. Courts are not possessed of instruments of
determination so delicate as to enable them to weigh the various
factors in a complicated economic setting which, as to an isolated
application of a State tax, might mitigate the obvious burden
generally created by a direct tax on commerce. Nor is there any
warrant in the constitutional principles heretofore applied by this
Court to support the notion that a State may be allowed one single
tax worth of direct interference with the free flow of commerce. An
exaction by a State from interstate commerce falls not because of a
proven increase in the cost of the product. What makes the tax
invalid is the
Page 329 U. S. 257
fact that there is interference by a State with the freedom of
interstate commerce. Such a tax by the seller State alone must be
judged burdensome in the context of the circumstances in which the
tax takes effect. Trade being a sensitive plant, a direct tax upon
it to some extent, at least, deters trade, even if its effect is
not precisely calculable. Many States, for instance, impose taxes
on the consumption of goods and such taxes have been sustained
regardless of the extra-State origin of the goods, or whether a tax
on their sale had been imposed by the seller State. Such potential
taxation by consumer States is but one factor pointing to the
deterrent effect on commerce by a superimposed gross receipts
tax.
It has been urged that the force of the decision in the
Adams case has been sapped by
McGoldrick v.
Berwind-White Coal Mining Co., 309 U. S.
33. The decision in
McGoldrick v. Berwind-White
was found not to impinge upon "the rationale of the
Adams
Manufacturing Co. case," and the tax was sustained because it
was "conditioned upon a local activity delivery of goods within the
state upon their purchase for consumption." 309 U.S. at
309 U. S. 58.
Compare McLeod v. J. E. Dilworth Co., 322 U.
S. 327. Taxes which have the same effect as consumption
taxes are properly differentiated from a direct imposition on
interstate commerce, such as was before the Court in the
Adams case, and is now before us. The tax on the sale
itself cannot be differentiated from a direct unapportioned tax on
gross receipts which has been definitely held beyond the State
taxing power ever since
Fargo v. Michigan, 121 U.
S. 230, and
Philadelphia & S. M. Steamship Co.
v. Pennsylvania, 122 U. S. 326.
See also, e.g., Galveston, Harrisburg & S.A. R. Co. v.
Texas, 210 U. S. 217;
Kansas City, Ft. S. & M. Ry. v. Botkin, 240 U.
S. 227,
240 U. S. 231;
Puget Sound Stevedoring Co. v. Tax Commission,
302 U. S. 90,
302 U. S. 94,
and compare Wallace v. Hines, 253 U. S.
66. For not even an "internal regulation" by a
Page 329 U. S. 258
State will be allowed if it directly affects interstate
commerce.
Robbins v. Shelby Taxing Dist., 120 U.
S. 489,
120 U. S.
494.
Nor is
American Mfg. Co. v. City of St. Louis,
250 U. S. 459, or
International Harvester Co. v. Dept. of Treasury,
322 U. S. 340, any
justification for the present tax. The
American Mfg. Co.
case involved an imposition by St. Louis of a license fee upon the
conduct of manufacturing within that city. It has long been settled
that a State can levy such an occupation tax graduated according to
the volume of manufacture. In that case, to lighten the
manufacturer's burden, the imposition of the occupation tax was
made contingent upon the actual sale of the goods locally
manufactured. Sales in St. Louis of goods made elsewhere were not
taken into account in measuring the license fee. That tax, then,
unlike this, was not, in fact, a tax on gross receipts.
Cf.
Cornell v. Coyne, 192 U. S. 418.
And, if words are to correspond to things, the tax now here is not
"a tax on the transfer of property" within the State, which was the
basis for sustaining the tax in
International Harvester Co. v.
Dept of Treasury, supra, at
322 U. S.
348.
There remains only the claim that an interstate sale of
intangibles differs from an interstate sale of tangibles in
respects material to the issue in this case. It was by this
distinction that the Supreme Court of Indiana sought to escape the
authority of
Adams Mfg. Co. v. Storen, supra. Latin tags
like
mobilia sequuntur personam often do service for legal
analysis, but they ought not to confound constitutional issues.
What Mr. Justice Holmes said about that phrase is relevant
here.
"It is a fiction, the historical origin of which is familiar to
scholars, and it is this fiction that gives whatever meaning it has
to the saying
mobilia sequuntur personam. But, being a
fiction, it is not allowed to obscure the facts, when the facts
become important."
Blackstone v. Miller, 188 U. S. 189,
188 U. S.
204.
Page 329 U. S. 259
Of course, this is an interstate sale. And, constitutionally, it
is commerce no less and no different because the subject was pieces
of paper worth $65,214.20, rather than machines.
Reversed.
MR. JUSTICE BLACK dissents.
*
Compare Report of the (Australian) Royal Commission
on the Constitution (1929) pp. 260, 322-24,
and Report of
the (Canadian) Royal Commission on Dominion-Provincial Relations
(1940), bk. II, pp 62-67, 111-21, 150-62, 216-19.
See
Australia, Act No. 1, 1946, repealing Act No. 20, 1942, and Act No.
43, 1942;
South Australia v. Commonwealth, 65 C.L.R. 373;
also Proposals of the Government of Canada, Dominion-Provincial
Conference on Reconstruction pp. 47-49; Proceedings of the
Dominion-Provincial Conference (1945)
passim, particularly
the statement of Prime Minister Mackenzie King, p. 388, and the
discussion following.
And see Maxwell, The Fiscal Impact
of Federalism in the United States (1946) cc. II, XIII, XIV.
MR. JUSTICE RUTLEDGE, concurring.
This is a case in which the grounding of the decision is more
important than the decision itself. Whether the Court now intends
simply to qualify or to repudiate entirely, except in result,
Adams Mfg. Co. v. Storen, 304 U.
S. 307, I am unable to determine from its opinion. But
that one or the other consequence is intended seems obvious from
its refusal to rest the present decision squarely on that case,
together with the wholly different foundation on which it now
relies. In either event, the matter is important, and calls for
discussion.
I
The
Adams case held the Indiana tax now in issue to be
invalid when applied, without apportionment, to gross receipts
derived from interstate sales of goods made by Indiana
manufacturers who sold and shipped them to purchasers in other
states. "The vice of the statute" as thus applied, it was held,
was
"that the tax includes in its measure,
without
apportionment, receipts derived from activities in interstate
commerce, and that the exaction is of such a character that, if
lawful, it may in substance be laid
to the fullest extent
by states in which the goods are sold as well as those in which
they are manufactured. Interstate commerce would thus be subjected
to
the risk of a double tax burden to which intrastate
commerce is
Page 329 U. S. 260
not exposed, and which the commerce clause forbids."
(Emphasis added.)
304 U. S. 307,
304 U. S. 311.
[
Footnote 1]
Today's opinion refuses to rest squarely on the
Adams
case, although that case would be completely controlling if no
change in the law were intended. No basis for distinguishing the
cases on the facts or the ultimate questions is found or stated.
The Court takes them as identical. [
Footnote 2] Yet it places no emphasis upon apportionment,
the absence of which the
Adams opinion held crucial. The
Court also puts to one side as irrelevant the factor there most
stressed, namely, the danger of multiple taxation, that is, of
similar taxation by other states, if the Indiana tax should be
upheld in the attempted application.
Those matters were the very essence of the
Adams
decision. They were, in its words, "the vice" of the statute as
applied. The
Adams opinion gives no reason for believing
that the application of the tax would not have been sustained if
either of the two elements vitiating it had been absent. On the
contrary, the fair -- indeed the necessary -- inference from the
language and reasons given is that the tax would not have been
voided if there had been no danger of multiple state taxation or if
the tax had been apportioned so as to eliminate that risk.
Moreover, those
Page 329 U. S. 261
groundings were strictly in accord with long lines of previous
decisions rendered here, [
Footnote
3] were intended to conform to them and to preserve them
unimpaired.
Yet now they are put to one side, either as irrelevant or as not
controlling, and therefore presumably as insufficient, [
Footnote 4] in favor of another
rationalization which ignores them completely. Shortly, this is, in
reiterated forms, that the tax as applied is laid "directly on"
interstate commerce, is a levy "on the very sale" or "the very
process" of such commerce, is therefore and solely thereby a
"burden" on it, and consequently is an exaction the commerce clause
forbids. What outlaws it is neither comparative disadvantage with
local trade nor any actual or probable clogging or impeding effect
in fact. [
Footnote 5] It is
simply the "direct" bearing and "incidence" of the tax on
interstate commerce, and this alone. Stripped of any discriminatory
element and of any actual or probable tendency to block or impede
the commerce in fact, this "direct incidence" is itself enough,
without more, to invalidate the tax, although it is one of general
application singling out the commerce neither for separate nor for
distinct or invidious treatment.
If this ever was the law, it has not been such for many years.
In a sense, it is a reversion to ideas once prevalent,
Page 329 U. S. 262
but long since repudiated [
Footnote 6] about the "exclusiveness" of Congress' power
over interstate commerce, which, if now resurrected for general
application, will strike down state taxes in a great variety of
forms sustained consistently of late. Not since
Cooley v.
Board of Wardens, 12 How. 299, has the notion
prevailed that the mere existence of power in Congress to regulate
commerce excludes the states from exacting revenue from it through
exercise of their powers of taxation. [
Footnote 7] Yet if a general tax, applying to all commerce
alike, is to be outlawed, regardless of discriminatory consequences
or actual or probable impeding effect in fact simply because it
bears "directly" on the commerce, and for no other reason, not only
will there be a resurrection of Marshall's "exclusive" idea, never
prevailing after the
Cooley case. The effect will be to
knock down many types of state taxes held valid since that landmark
decision. [
Footnote 8]
That consequence must follow if the presently asserted basis for
decision is to be taken as a principle fit for general application
and intended to be so used. We cannot assume that the Court intends
it to be used otherwise, for that would be to make of it an
arbitrary formula applied to dispose of the present case alone and
having no validity for any other situation. But the ground relied
upon is broad enough to include many other types of situation and
of tax, and cannot be restricted logically or in reason to these
narrow facts. If discrimination and real risk, in
Page 329 U. S. 263
the sense of practical effect to clog or impede trade, are
irrelevant to the validity of this type of tax, they are equally
irrelevant to many others, unless sheer fiction and arbitrary
distinction based on inconsequential factors are to be controlling.
If the grounding which disregards them is adequate for disposing of
this case, it is adequate also for disposing of many others
involving it in which the Court has been at great pains to rest on
other factors, unnecessarily, it now would seem.
It will be appropriate, before turning to further consideration
of the more pertinent decisions, to note the only basis upon which
the Court grounds its ruling that "direct" state taxes on "the very
process" of interstate commerce are void. This is because, in the
words of the opinion, the commerce clause, "by its own force,
created an area of trade free from interference by the States."
Although this is stated as grounding for the long established
conclusion that, even without implementing legislation by Congress,
the clause is a limitation upon state power, it also is quite
obviously the foundation of the further conclusion that "direct"
taxes laid by the states within that area are outlawed, regardless
of any other factor than their direct incidence upon it.
II
I agree that the commerce clause, "of its own force," places
restrictions upon state power to tax, as well as to regulate,
interstate commerce. This has been held through various lines of
decision extending back to
Gibbons v.
Ogden, 9 Wheat. 1, some of them unbroken. [
Footnote 9] I also agree that this
construction is consonant with the great purpose of the commerce
clause to maintain our distinctively
Page 329 U. S. 264
national trade free from state restrictions and barriers against
it which the clause was adopted to prevent. But, at any rate since
Cooley v. Board of Wardens, supra, this has not meant that
the clause was intended to or could secure "by its own force" that
vast area of commercial activity wholly free from "interference" --
that is, from taxation and regulation -- by the states. [
Footnote 10] Nor, for many years,
has it meant that the field of interstate commerce is to be free
from such "interference" simply because it is "direct" or has
immediate incidence upon it. [
Footnote 11] True, language frequently appears in the
cases, especially the earlier ones, to the effect that "direct"
taxation and regulation by the states are forbidden. But, apart
from its inconsistency with both language and results in other
cases, [
Footnote 12] in most
of those where it has appeared there were other invalidating
factors, such as singling out the commerce for special treatment,
other types of discrimination, or failure to
Page 329 U. S. 265
apportion where multiple state taxation could result if the tax
were sustained. [
Footnote
13]
The fact is that "direct incidence" of a state tax or
regulation, apart from the presence of such a factor, has long
Page 329 U. S. 266
since been discarded as being, in itself, sufficient to outlaw
state legislation. "Local" regulations, under the
Cooley
formula, bear directly on the commerce itself. [
Footnote 14] But they are not outlawed for
that reason. Calling them "incidental," where this is done, does
not make them "indirect," except in judicial perspective. Police
regulations bear no more indirectly or remotely upon the interstate
commerce which must observe them than upon the local commerce
falling equally within their incidence.
Again, an apportioned tax on interstate commerce is a "direct"
tax bearing immediately upon it in incidence. But such a tax is
not, for that reason, invalid. Decisions have sustained such taxes
repeatedly, regardless of their direct bearing, provided the
apportionment were fairly made and no other vitiating element were
present, such as those above mentioned. [
Footnote 15] It was this fact, without question, which
the Court had in mind in the
Adams case when it carefully
saved from its ban any question concerning such a tax as Indiana's
if properly apportioned in a situation like the ones presented
there and now. [
Footnote
16]
Page 329 U. S. 267
III
The language purporting to outlaw "direct" taxes because they
are direct has appeared more frequently perhaps in relation to
gross receipts taxes than any other including both "direct" taxes,
apportioned and unapportioned, and others considered "indirect"
because purporting to be laid not "on the commerce itself," but
upon some "local incident." We have recently held that a tax having
effects forbidden by the commerce clause will not be saved merely
because it is cast in terms of bearing upon some "local incident."
[
Footnote 17] As we then
said, all interstate commerce takes place within the states, and
the consequences forbidden by the commerce clause cannot be
achieved legally simply by the device of hooking the tax or other
forbidden regulation to some selected "local incident." That such a
factor may be chosen for bearing the "direct"
Page 329 U. S. 268
incidence of the tax may be a consideration to be taken into
account in determining its validity. But it cannot validate a tax
or regulation which produces the forbidden consequences any more
than a "direct tax" which does not produce them can be outlawed
because it is direct. Not "directness" or "immediacy" of incidence,
per se, whether "upon the commerce itself" or upon a
"local incident," is the outlawing factor, but whether the tax,
regardless of the special point of incidence, has the consequences
for interstate trade intended to be outlawed by the commerce
clause.
The difficulty of any other rule or approach is disclosed most
clearly perhaps by contrasting the decision in
American Mfg.
Co. v. St. Louis, 250 U. S. 459,
with the
Adams decision and this one, in both of which
efforts are made, unsuccessfully in my opinion, to distinguish the
American case. There, the tax was laid upon the
manufacture, locally done, of goods sold locally and out of state.
But the tax was "measured by" the gross receipts from sales of the
goods manufactured, including those sold interstate. [
Footnote 18]
Page 329 U. S. 269
A tax upon a local privilege measured by the volume of gross
receipts from both local and interstate trade [
Footnote 19] would seem to have, in practical
effect, the same consequences for blocking or impeding the commerce
as one laid "directly" upon it in any situation where no multiple
levy is made, likewise in any where more than one state might find
such a local privilege for pegging the tax. [
Footnote 20] And a tax upon gross receipts "in
lieu of" property or other taxes [
Footnote 21] cannot be said either to be less "direct" in
its incidence upon the commerce than the application of the Indiana
tax now in issue or to afford protection against multiple levies
the risk of which was held in
Adams Mfg. Co. v. Storen to
make the Indiana tax inherently vicious in that application.
[
Footnote 22]
Unless we are to return to the formalism of another day, neither
the "directness" of the incidence of a tax "upon the commerce
itself" nor the fact that its incidence is manipulated to rest upon
some "local incident" of the interstate transaction can be used as
a criterion or, many times, as a consideration of first importance
in determining the validity of a state tax bearing upon or
affecting interstate commerce. Not the words "direct" and
"indirect" or "local incident" can fulfill the function of judgment
in deciding
Page 329 U. S. 270
whether the tax brings the forbidden results.
See the
dissenting opinion of Mr. Justice Stone in
Di Santo v.
Pennsylvania, 273 U. S. 34,
273 U. S. 44,
quoted in
note 11 That can
be done only by taking account of the specific effects of state
legislation the clause was intended to outlaw, and of the
consequences actual or probable of the legislation called in
question to create them.
IV
Judgments of this character and magnitude cannot be made by
labels or formulae. They require much more than pointing to a word.
It is for this reason that, increasingly with the years, emphasis
has been placed upon practical consequences and effects, either
actual or threatened, of questioned legislation to block or impede
interstate commerce or place it at practical disadvantage with the
local trade. [
Footnote 23]
Formulae and adjectives have been retained at times in intermixture
with the effective practical considerations. But, proportionately,
the stress upon them has been greatly reduced, until the present
decision, and the trend of recent decisions to sustain state taxes
formerly regarded as invalid has been due in large part to this
fact.
The commerce clause was not designed or intended to outlaw all
state taxes bearing "directly" on interstate commerce. Its design
was only to exclude those having the effects to block or impede it
which called it and the Constitution itself into being. Not all
state taxes, nor indeed all direct state taxes, can be said to
produce those effects. On the other hand, many "indirect" forms of
state taxation -- that is, "indirect" as related to "incidence" --
do in fact produce such consequences, and for that reason are
invalid.
Page 329 U. S. 271
It is for this reason that selection of a "local incident" for
hanging the tax will not save it, if also the exaction does not in
fact avoid the outlawed interferences with the free flow of
commerce. Selection of a local incident for pegging the tax has two
functions relevant to determination of its validity. One is to make
plain that the state has sufficient factual connections with the
transaction to comply with due process requirements. [
Footnote 24] The other is to act as
a safeguard, to some extent, against repetition of the same or a
similar tax by another state. [
Footnote 25] These matters are often interrelated,
cf. Western Union Telegraph Co. v. Kansas, 216 U. S.
1, though, in other situations, they may be entirely
separate. The important difference is between situations where it
is essential to show minimal factual connections of the transaction
with the taxing state in order to sustain the levy as against due
process objections for "want of jurisdiction to tax;" [
Footnote 26] and other situations
where, although such connections clearly are present, the necessity
is for showing that the tax, if sustained, will create a multiple
tax load or other consequences having the forbidden effects.
This case is not one of the former sort. The transactions were
as closely connected in fact with Indiana as with any other state.
[
Footnote 27] But the case
is one of the latter
Page 329 U. S. 272
type -- that is, where, despite those connections, there were
equally close and important ones in another state, New York, and
therefore, as the
Adams case declared, the risk of
multiple state taxation would be incurred unless one or the other
or both states were forbidden to tax the transaction as such, or
were required to apportion the tax. Not the "directness" of the tax
in its bearing upon the commerce, but this danger, is the crucial
issue in this case, as it was in the
Adams case. In other
words, but for the possibility that more states than one would levy
the same or a similar tax, such an application as was made of
Indiana's tax in the
Adams case and here would be no more
burdensome or objectionable than other applications of the same tax
this Court has sustained or of other taxes likewise held valid.
[
Footnote 28]
This Court, in recent years, has gone far in sustaining state
taxes laid upon local incidents of interstate transactions by both
the state of origin and the state of the market. [
Footnote 29]
Page 329 U. S. 273
Perhaps it may be said, in view of such decisions, that it has
more clearly sustained such taxes at the marketing end than by the
state of origin, [
Footnote
30] although this may be matter for debate. In any event, the
factual connections of the taxing state with the interstate
transaction in the cases where the tax has been sustained hardly
can be regarded as greater or more important than those of Indiana
with the transactions involved in the
Adams case and here.
Nor could it be shown in fact that, in some of them, at any rate,
the danger of multiple state taxation was appreciably less, if it
be assumed that the forwarding state has the same power to tax the
transaction, by pegging the tax upon a local incident, as has been
recognized for the state of market.
Such taxes, whether in one state or the other, may in fact block
or impede interstate commerce as much as, or more than, one placed
directly upon the commerce itself. They have been sustained,
nevertheless, not simply because of their bearing upon a local
incident, but because, in the circumstances of their application,
they were considered to have neither discriminatory effects upon
interstate trade as compared with local commerce nor to impose upon
it the blocking or impeding effects which the commerce clause was
taken to forbid. [
Footnote
31]
Page 329 U. S. 274
This, in my judgment, is the appropriate criterion to be
applied, rather than any mere question of "direct" or "indirect"
incidence upon a "local incident." The absence of any such
connection with the taxing state is highly material. [
Footnote 32] Its presence cannot be
the controlling consideration for validating the tax.
Nippert
v. Richmond, 327 U. S. 416. In
this view, it would seem clear that the validity of such a tax as
Indiana's, applied to situations like those presented in the
Adams case and now, should be determined by reference not
merely to the "direct incidence" of the tax, but by whether those
forbidden consequences would be produced, either through the actual
incidence of multiple taxes laid by different states or by the
threat of them, with resulting uncertainties producing the same
impeding consequences. [
Footnote
33]
Thus, it is highly doubtful that the levy in this case, or in
the
Adams case, actually had any impeding effect whatever
upon the transactions or the free flow interstate of such commerce.
[
Footnote 34] But the
Adams case found the impediment in the assumption that, if
one state could tax, so also could the other, and, in that event, a
double burden would result for interstate commerce not borne by
local
Page 329 U. S. 275
trade. This danger, it was said, was inherent in the type of the
tax, since it was not apportioned, and, in consequence, the tax as
applied must fall.
The basic assumption was not true as a universally or even a
generally resulting consequence, for two reasons. One is that it
would not follow necessarily as a matter of fact that both states
would tax or, if they did so, that the combined effects of the
taxes would be either to clog or to impede the commerce. [
Footnote 35] The other, it no more
follows, as a matter of law, that, because one state may tax, the
other may do likewise.
The
Adams decision did not take account of any
difference, as regards the risk of multiple state taxation, between
situations where the multiple burden would actually or probably be
incurred in fact and others in which no such risk would be
involved. It rather disregarded such differences, so that "the risk
of double tax burden" on which the Court relied to invalidate the
levy was not one actually, probably, or even doubtfully imposed in
fact by another state. [
Footnote
36] It rather was one which resulted only from an assumed, and
an unexercised, power in that state to impose a similar tax.
The Court was not concerned with whether the forbidden
consequences had been incurred in the particular situation or might
not be incurred in others covered by its ruling. The motivating
fear was more general. The
Page 329 U. S. 276
ultimate risk which the Court sought to avoid was the danger
that gross income or gross receipts tax legislation, without
apportionment, might be widely adopted if the door were once
opened, and, if adopted and applied to interstate sales by all or
many of the states, would result generally in bringing such sales
within the incidence of multiple state taxation of that nature.
Rather than incur this risk, with the anticipated consequent
widespread creation of multiple levies, the Court in effect
forestalled them at the source. Its action was prophylactic, and
the prophylaxis was made absolute.
By thus relieving interstate commerce from liability to pay
taxes in either state, without any showing that both had laid them,
the effect was not simply to relieve that commerce from multiple
burden, but to give it exemption from taxes all other trade must
bear. [
Footnote 37] Local
trade was thus placed at disadvantage with interstate trade, by the
amount of the tax, and the commerce clause thereby became a refuge
for tax exemption, not simply a means of protection against unequal
or undue taxation. Certainly its object was not to create for
interstate trade such a specially privileged position.
But the alternatives to such a ruling were not themselves free
from difficulty. They may be stated shortly. But preliminarily, I
accept the view frequently declared [
Footnote 38] that a state runs afoul the commerce clause
when it singles out interstate commerce for special taxation not
applied to other trade, or otherwise discriminates against it or
treats it invidiously. Moreover, all other things being equal,
Page 329 U. S. 277
multiple state taxation of gross receipts, although by
nondiscriminatory taxes of general applicability, does compel the
latter to bear a heavier tax burden than local trade in either
state. The cumulative tax burden is in effect discriminatory,
involving in any practical view the exact effects of a single
discriminatory tax. Although the difference in total tax load may
not be sufficient actually to block or impede the free flow of
interstate trade, [
Footnote
39] discrimination alone, without regard to showing or further
consequences, has been held consistently to be sufficient for
outlawing the tax.
This too I accept. For discrimination not only is ordinarily
itself invidious treatment, but has an obvious tendency toward
blocking or impeding the commerce, if not always the actual effect
of doing so. Nor is the discriminatory tendency or effect lessened
because it results from cumulation of tax burdens, rather than from
a single tax producing the same consequence. To allow both states
to tax "to the fullest extent" would produce the invidious sort of
barrier or impediment the commerce clause was designed to stop. But
the bare power of another state to tax unexercised does not produce
such results. It only opens the way for them to be produced. This
danger is not fanciful, but real -- more especially in a time when
new sources of revenue constantly are being sought. Accordingly, I
agree that this door should not be opened.
But it is not necessary to go as far as the
Adams case
went, or as the decision not rendered goes, in order to prevent the
anticipated deluge. There is no need to give interstate commerce a
haven of refuge from taxation, albeit of gross receipts or from
"direct" incidence, in order
Page 329 U. S. 278
to safeguard it from evils against which the commerce clause is
designedly protective. Less broad and absolute alternatives are
available, and are adequate for the purpose of protection without
creating the evils of total exemption.
The alternative methods available for avoiding the multiple
state tax burden may now be stated. They are: (1) to apply the
Adams ruling, stopping such taxes at the source, unless
the tax is apportioned, thus eliminating the cumulative burdens;
[
Footnote 40] (2) to rule
that either the state of origin or the state of market, but not
both, can levy the exaction; (3) to determine factually in each
case whether application of the tax can be made by one state
without incurring actual danger of its being made in another or the
risk of real uncertainty whether, in fact it will be so made.
The
Adams solution is not unobjectionable, for reasons
already set forth. To deprive either state, whether of origin or of
market, of the power to lay the tax, permitting the other to do so,
has the vice of allowing one state to tax, but denying this power
to the other when neither may be as much affected by the
deprivation as would be the one allowed to tax, and, in any event,
both may have equal or substantial due process connections with the
transaction. The solution by factual determination in particular
cases of the actual or probable incidence of both taxes is open to
two objections. One is that, to some extent, it would make the
taxing power of one or both states depend upon whether the other
had exercised, or probably would
Page 329 U. S. 279
exercise, the same power. The other would lie in the volume of
litigation such a rule would incite and the difficulties, in some
cases at least, of making the factual determination.
VI
The problem of multiple state taxation, absent other factors
making for prohibition, is therefore one of choosing among evils.
There is no ideal solution. To leave the matter to Congress,
allowing both states to tax "to the fullest extent" until it
intervenes, would run counter to the long established rules not
only requiring apportionment where incidence of multiple taxes
would be likely, but also in substance and effect to those
forbidding discrimination, without the consent of Congress,
cf.
Prudential Life Ins. Co. v. Benjamin, 328 U.
S. 408, as well as the long settled rule that the clause
is "of its own force" a prohibition upon the states. To require
factual determination of forbidden effects in each case would be to
invite costly litigation, make decision turn in some cases, perhaps
many, on doubtful facts or conclusions, and encourage the enactment
of legislation involving those consequences. The
Adams
ruling, as I have said, creates for many situations a tax refuge
for interstate commerce, and does this in both states.
As among the various possibilities, I think the solution most
nearly in accord with the commerce clause at once most consistent
with its purpose and least objectionable for producing either evils
it had no design to bring or practical difficulties in
administration, would be to vest the power to tax in the state of
the market, subject to power in the forwarding state also to tax by
allowing credit to the full amount of any tax paid or due at the
destination. This too is more nearly consonant with what the more
recent decisions have allowed, if full account is taken of their
effects.
Page 329 U. S. 280
In
McLeod v. J. E. Dilworth, 322 U.
S. 327,
322 U.S.
361, I have set forth the reasons leading to this
conclusion. [
Footnote 41] It
may be added that such a result would avoid altogether the
undesirable features of factual determination in each case; would
prevent the multiple and, in effect, discriminatory burden which
would follow from allowing both states to tax until Congress should
intervene, and would reduce by half, at least, the tax refuge
created by the
Adams ruling, without incurring other
outlawed effects.
It is true this view logically would deny the state of original
power to tax, notwithstanding its adequate due process connections,
except by giving credit for taxes due at the destination. [
Footnote 42] But the forwarding
state has no greater power under the
Adams ruling, and
none at all under the present one if it is to be applied
consistently and, as I think, this can be taken to outlaw both
unapportioned and apportioned taxes.
I have no doubt that, under the law prevailing until now, this
tax would have been sustained, if apportioned, under the
Adams decision and others. [
Footnote 43] Nor have I any question that such a tax laid
by New York would be upheld under
Page 329 U. S. 281
those decisions. Indeed, in my opinion, the necessary effect of
McGoldrick v. Berwind-White Co., 309 U. S.
33, as appellee asserts, is to sustain power in the
state of the market to tax "to the fullest extent" without
apportionment by nondiscriminatory taxes of general applicability,
transactions essentially no different from the ones involved in
this case and in the
Adams case.
It is true the
Berwind-White case purported to
distinguish the
Adams case. But it did so by pointing out
that the New York tax was "conditioned upon a local activity
delivery of goods within the state upon their purchase for
consumption," and that
"The effect of the tax, even though measured by the sales price,
as has been shown, neither discriminates against nor obstructs
interstate commerce more than numerous other state taxes which have
repeatedly been sustained as involving no prohibited regulation of
interstate commerce."
309 U. S. 309 U.S.
33,
309 U. S.
58.
This comes down to sustaining the tax, as was done in
American Mfg. Co. v. St. Louis, supra, relied upon to
distinguish the
Adams case, simply because the tax was
pegged upon the "local incident" of delivery. Apart from the
reasons I have set forth above for regarding this as not being
controlling, that basis was flatly repudiated in
Nippert v.
Richmond, 327 U. S. 416, as
adequate for sustaining a tax having otherwise the forbidden
effects and features. So here, in my opinion, it is hardly adequate
to distinguish the
Adams case, leaving it unimpaired, or
to differentiate consistently the broader ruling made in this
case.
I therefore agree with the appellee that the effect of the
Berwind-White ruling was in substance, though not in
words, to qualify the
Adams decision, and that the
combined effect of the two cases, taken together, was to permit the
state of the market to tax the interstate transaction,
Page 329 U. S. 282
but to deny this power to the forwarding state unless, by credit
or otherwise, it should make provision for apportionment.
See Powell, New Light on Gross Receipts Taxes (1940) 53
Harv.L.Rev. 909, 939. Whether or not such a provision would save
the Indiana tax as now applied, in view of what I think was the
effect of
Berwind-White on any basis other than sheer
formalism, need not now be considered. [
Footnote 44]
Whether or not acknowledgment of this effect of the
Berwind-White decision would require reconsideration of
the validity of apportioned taxes otherwise than by full credit,
laid by the forwarding state, [
Footnote 45] neither that fact nor the effect of
Berwind-White in qualifying the
Adams ruling
justifies the broader ruling now made to reach the same result as
the
Adams case reached. The trend of recent decisions has
been toward sustaining state taxes formerly regarded as outlawed by
the commerce clause. The present decision, by its reversion to the
formal and discarded grounding in the "direct incidence" of the tax
is a reversal of that trend. It is one, moreover, unnecessary for
sustaining the result the Court has reached. Its consequence, if
followed in logical application to apportioned taxes, will be to
outlaw them, for they bear as "directly" on "the commerce itself"
as does the tax now stricken down in its
Page 329 U. S. 283
present application. So also does the type of tax sustained in
the
Berwind-White case, in everything but verbalism.
I think the result now reached is justified as necessary to
prevent the cumulative, and therefore discriminatory, tax burden
which would rest on or seriously threaten interstate commerce if
more than one state is allowed to impose the tax, as does Indiana,
upon the gross receipts from the sale without apportionment or
credit for taxes validly imposed elsewhere. This result would
follow in view of the
Berwind-White decision and others
like it, [
Footnote 46] if
not only the state of the market, but also the forwarding state,
could tax the sale "to the fullest extent" upon the gross receipts.
For this reason, I concur in the result.
But, in doing so, I dissent from grounding the decision upon a
foundation which not only will outlaw properly apportioned taxes,
thus going beyond the
Adams decision, unless the Court is
merely to reiterate the rule forbidding "direct" taxation of
interstate sales only to recall it when a case involving a property
apportioned tax shall arise, but also will require outlawing many
other types of tax heretofore sustained, unless a similar retreat
is made.
[
Footnote 1]
The Court added:
"We have repeatedly held that such a tax is a regulation of and
a burden upon, interstate commerce prohibited by article 1, section
8, of the Constitution. The opinion of the State Supreme Court
stresses the generality and nondiscriminatory character of the
exaction, but it is settled that this will not save the tax if it
directly burdens interstate commerce."
304 U. S. 304 U.S.
307,
304 U. S.
311-312.
Cf. notes
5 and |
5 and S.
249fn16|>16.
[
Footnote 2]
The only factual difference is that here, the sales were of
securities, there of goods. It was this upon which Indiana has
relied to distinguish the
Adams case, asserting originally
that it gave domiciliary foundation for sustaining the tax. This
claim disappeared, in effect, at the second oral argument, and the
Court does not rest on it. I agree that, for present purposes,
sales of intangibles should be treated identically with sales of
goods.
[
Footnote 3]
See, e.g., Pullman's Palace Car Co. v. Pennsylvania,
141 U. S. 18;
Cudahy Packing Co. v. Minnesota, 246 U.
S. 450;
United States Express Co. v. Minnesota,
223 U. S. 335.
And see especially discussion in
Western Live Stock v.
Bureau of Revenue, 303 U. S. 250,
303 U. S.
255-257.
[
Footnote 4]
Compare the opinion of MR. JUSTICE FRANKFURTER in
Northwest Airlines v. Minnesota, 322 U.
S. 292.
[
Footnote 5]
As the Court says,
"An exaction by a State from interstate commerce falls not
because of a proven increase in the cost of the product. What makes
the tax invalid is the fact that there is interference by a State
with the freedom of interstate commerce."
The only "interference" held to be important is the direct
incidence of the tax on the commerce, not the double burden or risk
of it.
Cf. notes
1 and
|
1 and S. 249fn16|>16.
[
Footnote 6]
See e.g., Ribble, State and National Power Over
Commerce (1937) 204; Dowling, Interstate Commerce and State Power
(1940) 27 Va.L.Rev. 1, 3-10.
See also Frankfurter, The
Commerce Clause (1937) 53:
"Had Marshall's theory of the 'dormant' commerce power
prevailed, the taxable resources of the states would have been
greatly confined. The full implications of his theory, if logically
pursued, might well have profoundly altered the relations between
the state and the central government."
[
Footnote 7]
[
Footnote 8]
Cf. text
infra at notes
14 to |
14
to S. 249fn16|>16, also
14 to S. 249fn21|>21, and authorities cited.
[
Footnote 9]
See, e.g., Robbins v. Taxing District of Shelby County,
120 U. S. 489;
Real Silk Hosiery Mills v. City of Portland, 268 U.
S. 325;
Nippert v. City of Richmond,
327 U. S. 416, and
authorities cited.
[
Footnote 10]
See Ribble,
supra at 72 ff.; Frankfurter,
supra at 24, 56; Wechsler, Stone and the Constitution
(1946) 46 Col.L.Rev. 764, 785:
"It will summarize his basic conception to say that as the
issues were framed in the long debate the position taken by the
Court in
Cooley v. Board of Wardens comes closest to
according with his thought."
[
Footnote 11]
"Experience has taught that the opposing demands that the
commerce shall bear its share of local taxation, and that it shall
not, on the other hand, be subjected to multiple tax burdens merely
because it is interstate commerce, are not capable of
reconciliation by resort to the syllogism. Practical, rather than
logical, distinctions must be sought."
Western Live Stock v. Bureau of Revenue, 303 U.
S. 250,
303 U. S. 259.
See also the dissenting opinion of Mr. Justice Stone in
Di Santo v. Pennsylvania, 273 U. S.
34,
273 U. S. 44
(overruled by
California v. Thompson, 313 U.
S. 109),
"In thus making use of the expressions, 'direct' and 'indirect
interference' with commerce, we are doing little more than using
labels to describe a result, rather than any trustworthy formula by
which it is reached."
[
Footnote 12]
See, e.g., McGoldrick v. Berwind-White Coal Mining Co.,
309 U. S. 33;
Gwin, White & Prince v. Henneford, 305 U.
S. 434;
Nippert v. Richmond, 327 U.
S. 416.
[
Footnote 13]
Gross receipts taxes which have been sustained fall into the
following groups: (a) Those which were fairly apportioned.
See,
e.g., Illinois Cent. R. v. Minnesota, 309 U.
S. 157;
Pullman's Palace Car Co. v.
Pennsylvania, 141 U. S. 18;
Wisconsin & Michigan Ry. v. Powers, 191 U.
S. 379;
United States Express Co. v. Minnesota,
223 U. S. 335;
Ficklen v. Taxing District, 145 U. S.
1. (b) Those which have been justified on a "local
incidence" theory.
See, e.g., Western Live Stock v. Bureau of
Revenue, 303 U. S. 250,
with which compare Fisher's Blend Station v. Tax Comm'n,
297 U. S. 650;
McGoldrick v. Berwind-White Coal Mining Co., 309 U. S.
33;
American Mfg. Co. v. St. Louis,
250 U. S. 459.
See also cases cited in
note 21 In many cases, apportioned gross receipts taxes
have been sustained not on the ground that they were apportioned,
but that they were local in nature.
See, e.g., Maine v. Grand
Trunk Ry., 142 U. S. 217;
New York, L. E. & W. R. Co. v. Pennsylvania,
158 U. S. 431;
Wisconsin & Michigan Ry. v. Powers, supra; United States
Express Co. v. Minnesota, supra.
Gross receipts taxes which have not been sustained fall into the
following groups: (a) Those which were not fairly apportioned.
See, e.g., Meyer v. Wells Fargo Co., 223 U.
S. 298. (b) Those which were not apportioned, and
subjected interstate commerce to the risk of multiple taxation.
Philadelphia & So. S.S. Co. v. Pennsylvania,
122 U. S. 326;
Ratterman v. Western Union Telegraph Co., 127 U.
S. 411;
Western Union Telegraph Co. v. Alabama,
132 U. S. 472;
Adams Mfg. Co. v. Storen, 304 U.
S. 307;
Gwin, White & Prince v. Henneford,
305 U. S. 434,
305 U. S. 439.
Cf. Fargo v. Michigan, 121 U. S. 230, as
explained in
Western Live Stock v. Bureau of Revenue,
303 U. S. 250,
303 U. S. 256.
(c) Those in which there was a discriminatory element in that they
were directed exclusively "at transportation or communication,"
Lockhart, Gross Receipts Taxes on Transportation (1943) 57
Harv.L.Rev. 40, 65-66.
Galveston, H. & S.A. Ry. v.
Texas, 210 U. S. 217,
and cf. New Jersey Bell Tel. Co. v. State Tax Board,
280 U. S. 338.
But see Nashville, C. & St.L. Ry. v. Browning,
310 U. S. 362. In
both the
Galveston and
New Jersey Telephone
Company cases, although the taxable events all occurred within
the taxing state, the possibility of multiple taxation was
nevertheless present. (d) Those in which there was no
discrimination, but a possible multiple burden.
Fisher's Blend
Station v. Tax Comm'n, supra, as explained in
Western Live
Stock v. Bureau of Revenue, 303 U.S. at
303 U. S.
260-261. (e) Those in which there was no discrimination,
no apportionment, and no possibility of multiple burden.
Puget
Sound Stevedoring Co. v. Tax Commission, 302 U. S.
90. This decision, it may be noted, might have been
rested upon the clause of the Constitution forbidding the states to
tax exports.
Cf. Richfield Oil Corp. v. State Board of
Equalization, 329 U. S. 69.
[
Footnote 14]
Cf. California v. Thompson, 313 U.
S. 109;
Union Brokerage Co. v. Jensen,
322 U. S. 202;
Robertson v. California, 328 U. S. 440.
Indeed, sometimes police regulations bear more heavily on
interstate commerce.
Cf. Robertson v. California, supra,
and cases cited at note 28 therein.
[
Footnote 15]
See cases cited in
note 13 supra.
[
Footnote 16]
The Court said, in answer to the Indiana Supreme Court's
emphasis upon the "generality and nondiscriminatory character" of
the levy, "but it is settled that this will not save the tax if it
directly burdens interstate commerce." 304 U.S. at
304 U. S. 312;
cf. note 1
supra. The same statement is now made in this case not to
support the conclusion that these features cannot save a tax where
the risk of multiple state taxation would outlaw it, as in the
Adams case, but to support the vastly broader grounding
that the tax is invalid simply because it is "direct" in its
incidence. The quoted
Adams statement had no such
significance, as appears not only from its immediate context, but
also from the further statement, made apropos
American Mfg. Co.
v. St. Louis, 250 U. S. 459, in
an effort to distinguish it:
"It is because the tax, forbidden as to interstate commerce,
reaches,
indiscriminately and without apportionment, the
gross compensation for both interstate commerce and intrastate
activities that it must fail in its entirety so far as applied to
receipts from sales interstate."
(Emphasis added.) 304 U.S. at
304 U. S. 314.
Not "direct" taxation simply, but taxing the entire proceeds
without apportionment in the face of threatened or possible
multiple state taxation, was the "direct burden" found and outlawed
in the
Adams case.
[
Footnote 17]
"If the only thing necessary to sustain a state tax bearing upon
interstate commerce were to discover some local incident which
might be regarded as separate and distinct from 'the transportation
or intercourse which is' the commerce itself, and then to lay the
tax on that incident, all interstate commerce could be subjected to
state taxation, and without regard to the substantial economic
effects of the tax upon the commerce."
Nippert v. Richmond, 327 U. S. 416,
327 U. S.
423.
[
Footnote 18]
To say that this was not in substance a tax on gross receipts,
because sales in St. Louis of goods made elsewhere were not taken
into account in measuring the tax is simply to ignore the fact that
the tax did include all interstate sales of goods manufactured and
all returns from them. That the local sales of goods brought in
from other states were excepted does not mean either that those
sales were interstate transactions (which it was not necessary to
decide in view of their exemption) or that the sales out of state
included in the measure were not interstate transactions; or that
they were not, in substantial effect, taxed upon their gross
returns by the measure, notwithstanding the tax was made legally to
fall upon the privilege of manufacturing.
The
Adams decision purported to distinguish
American Mfg. Co. v. St. Louis simply on the ground that
the tax was not one laid on the taxpayer's sales or the income
derived from them, but was a license fee for engaging in the
manufacture which could be measured "by the sales price of the
goods produced, rather than by their value at the date of
manufacture."
[
Footnote 19]
In addition to
American Mfg. Co. v. St. Louis,
250 U. S. 459,
see Oliver Iron Mining Co. v. Lord, 262 U.
S. 172;
Hope Natural Gas Co. v. Hall,
274 U. S. 284;
Utah Power & Light Co. v. Pfost, 286 U.
S. 165.
[
Footnote 20]
Cf. Galveston, H. & S.A. R. Co. v. Texas,
210 U. S. 217,
210 U. S. 227;
Morrison, State Taxation of Interstate Commerce (1942) 36
Ill.L.Rev. 727, 738.
[
Footnote 21]
See Postal Telegraph-Cable Co. v. Adams, 155 U.
S. 688;
United States Express Co. v. Minnesota,
223 U. S. 335;
Pullman Co. v. Richardson, 261 U.
S. 330.
See also discussion in
Galveston,
H. & S.A. R. Co. v. Texas, 210 U.
S. 217,
210 U. S.
226-227.
[
Footnote 22]
This is true though concededly such a tax might work to prevent
cumulative or higher tax burdens imposed by a single taxing state.
Cf. Lockhart, Gross Receipts Taxes on Interstate
Transportation and Communication (1943) 57 Harv.L.Rev. 40.
[
Footnote 23]
See Nippert v. Richmond, 327 U.
S. 416;
Best & Co. v. Maxwell, 311 U.
S. 454.
Cf. Prudential Ins. Co. v. Benjamin,
328 U. S. 408.
See also Wechsler, Stone and the Constitution (1946) 46
Col.L.Rev. 764, 785-787.
[
Footnote 24]
See dissenting opinion in
McLeod v. J. E.
Dilworth, 322 U. S. 327, at
322 U.S. 356-357.
See
also Wisconsin v. J. C. Penney Co., 311 U.
S. 435,
311 U. S.
444-445.
[
Footnote 25]
See McNamara, Jurisdictional and Interstate Commerce
Problems in the Imposition of Excises on Sales (1941) 8 Law &
Contemp.Prob. 482, 491.
Compare the discussion of a
proposed federal statute to give the buyer's state the right to
impose nondiscriminatory sales taxes. Proc. 27th Ann.Conf.Nat.Tax
Assn. (1934) 136-160.
See also Perkins, The Sales Tax and
Transactions in Interstate Commerce (1934) 12 N.C.L.Rev. 99.
[
Footnote 26]
Cf. note 25
[
Footnote 27]
Indiana was the state by whose law the trust was created. It was
the situs of the trust's administration. It was the place where the
securities were kept prior to mailing for delivery in accordance
with the terms of their sale.
Cf. Curry v. McCanless,
307 U. S. 357. The
directions for sale were given there. The proceeds were forwarded
to Indiana, and there received into the corpus of the trust. The
state's connections with the trust, and with the property which was
the subject of the sale, more than satisfy and due process
requirement for exercise of the power to tax either the property or
transactions relating to its disposition taking place as largely
within Indiana's borders as did the sales in this case.
[
Footnote 28]
The cases, aside from
Adams Mfg. Co. v. Storen,
304 U. S. 307,
which involve the Indiana gross receipts tax are:
Department of
Treasury v. Wood Preserving Corp., 313 U. S.
62;
Department of Treasury v. Ingram-Richardson Mfg.
Co., 313 U. S. 252;
International Harvester Co. v. Dept. of Treasury,
322 U. S. 340;
Ford Motor Co. v. Dept. of Treasury, 323 U.
S. 459.
See also General Trading Co. v. State Tax
Commission, 322 U. S. 335;
cf. Northwestern Airlines v. Minnesota, 322 U.
S. 292.
[
Footnote 29]
See, e.g., McGoldrick v. Berwind-White Co.,
309 U. S. 33;
Nelson v. Sears, Roebuck & Co., 312 U.
S. 359;
General Trading Co. v. State Tax
Commission, 322 U. S. 335;
Western Live Stock v. Bureau of Revenue, 303 U.
S. 250;
Coverdale v. Arkansas-Louisiana Pile Line
Co., 303 U. S. 604;
Department of Treasury v. Ingram-Richardson Mfg. Co.,
313 U. S. 252.
[
Footnote 30]
Compare McGoldrick v. Berwind-White Co., 309 U. S.
33,
with McLeod v. J. E. Dilworth, 322 U.
S. 327.
See Powell, New Light on Gross Receipts
Taxes (1940) 53 Harv.L.Rev. 909.
[
Footnote 31]
See McGoldrick v. Berwind-White Co., 309 U. S.
33,
309 U. S. 58,
quoted
infra 329 U. S.
[
Footnote 32]
As a matter of minimal due process requirements.
Cf.
text
infra at notes
24
to 27
[
Footnote 33]
The danger of an impending burden or barrier from multiple state
taxation could be real and substantial in a particular case if the
threat of such taxation were actual or probable or if its
threatened incidence were involved in such actual uncertainty that
this uncertainty itself would constitute, in practical effect, a
substantial clog.
[
Footnote 34]
The Indiana tax was only one percent of the proceeds of the
sales. The record indicates, too, that the New York Stock Transfer
tax was collected from the proceeds of the sale in New York. The
amount of the tax was three cents per share sold for less than
twenty dollars, and four cents per share sold for more than twenty
dollars. Tax Law §§ 270, 270a;
O'Kane v. New York, 283
N.Y. 439, 28 N.E.2d 905. The tax did not apply to the transfer of
bonds.
Cf. Op.Atty.Gen.N.Y.1939, p. 208.
[
Footnote 35]
Cf. note 31
Whether such a tax would in fact produce the forbidden results or
not would depend upon the incidence or likelihood of the incidence
of a like tax in the other, or another, jurisdiction having similar
power. Frequently this likelihood will be, in fact either nil or
small.
[
Footnote 36]
The opinion discloses no consideration of any question or
suggestion whether a like or other tax had been or was likely to be
imposed by the state of destination, or even that such a tax by
that state was doubtfully incident. Such an inquiry would have been
inconsistent with the Court's thesis.
[
Footnote 37]
It is assumed, of course, that a nondiscriminatory tax of
general applicability laid by the taxing state would be
involved.
[
Footnote 38]
See Best & Co. v. Maxwell, 311 U.
S. 454;
Hale v. Bimco Trading Co., 306 U.
S. 375;
Buy v. Baltimore, 100 U.
S. 434;
Webber v. Virginia, 103 U.
S. 344;
Welton v. Missouri, 91 U. S.
275;
Voight v. Wright, 141 U. S.
62;
Brimmer v. Rebman, 138 U. S.
78.
[
Footnote 39]
For a variety of reasons, among which might be the larger
capacity of such trade to absorb the difference, by reason of
greater volume, without sustaining loss of profit, in the
particular sort of commerce or type of transaction.
See
also note 34
[
Footnote 40]
The
Adams decision, of course, made no direct ruling
upon an actual tax laid by the state of destination. But the basic
premise of its rationalization would be altogether without
substance if it were taken to mean that such a tax would be levied
there with ut meeting the same barrier, and for the same reason, as
the tax levied by Indiana, the state of origin, encountered.
[
Footnote 41]
"If, in this case, it were necessary to choose between the state
of origin and that of market for the exercise of exclusive power to
tax, or for requiring allowance of credit in order to avoid the
cumulative burden, in my opinion the choice should lie in favor of
the state of market, rather than the state of origin. The former is
the state where the goods must come in competition with those sold
locally. It is the one where the burden of the tax necessarily will
fall equally on both classes of trade. To choose the tax of the
state of origin presents at least some possibilities that the
burden it imposes on its local trade, with which the interstate
traffic does not compete at any rate directly, will be heavier than
that placed by the consuming state on its local business of the
same character."
[
Footnote 42]
Credit allowed for taxes paid elsewhere,
see Henneford v.
Silas Mason Co., 300 U. S. 577;
General Trading Co. v. State Tax Commission, 322 U.
S. 335, is a form of apportionment, though not the only
one.
[
Footnote 43]
See also Gwin, White & Prince v. Henneford,
305 U. S. 434.
[
Footnote 44]
It is obvious that an apportioned tax laid by the forwarding
state, taken in conjunction with an unapportioned one levied by the
state of the market, would produce the effect of multiple state
levies to the extent of the apportioned tax unless the
apportionment were made by giving full credit for the other tax. In
the latter event, of course, there would be no effect of multiple
burden in the sense forbidden by the rule requiring apportionment
and sustaining properly apportioned taxes. In the absence of a
credit to the full amount of the marketing state's tax, the
apportioned tax of the forwarding state, although making a
cumulative burden, would impose only a reduced one as compared with
an unapportioned tax by that state.
[
Footnote 45]
Cf. note 44
[
Footnote 46]
See the "use tax" cases:
General Trading Co. v.
State Tax Commission, 322 U. S. 335;
Felt & Tarrant Mfg. Co. v. Gallagher, 306 U. S.
62;
Nelson v. Sears, Roebuck & Co.,
312 U. S. 359;
Nelson v. Montgomery Ward & Co., 312 U.
S. 373.
See also Jagels v. Taylor, 309 U.S.
619, discussed in McNamara,
supra, note 25 at 487.
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS, with whom MR. JUSTICE MURPHY concurs,
dissenting.
I think the Court confuses a gross receipts tax on the Indiana
broker with a gross receipts tax on his Indiana customer.
Gwin,
White & Prince, Inc. v. Henneford, 305 U.
S. 434, would hold invalid a gross receipts tax,
unapportioned,
Page 329 U. S. 284
on the broker. In that case, the taxpayer was a marketing agent
for fruit growers in the Washington. The agent made sales and
deliveries of the fruit in other States and in foreign countries,
collected the sales prices, and remitted the proceeds, less
charges, to the customers. The Court held that the gross receipts
tax, being unapportioned, was invalid. There are two reasons why
that result followed. In the first place, as the Court stated 305
U.S. at
305 U. S. 437,
"[t]he entire service for which the compensation is paid is in aid
of the shipment and sale of merchandise" in interstate or foreign
commerce. "Such services are within the protection of the commerce
clause." In the second place, as the Court stated, 305 U.S. at
305 U. S.
439,
"If Washington is free to exact such a tax, other states to
which the commerce extends may, with equal right, lay a tax
similarly measured for the privilege of conducting within their
respective territorial limits the activities there which contribute
to the service. The present tax, though nominally local, thus in
its practical operation discriminates against interstate commerce,
since it imposes upon it, merely because interstate commerce is
being done, the risk of a multiple burden to which local commerce
is not exposed."
Under that view, a tax on the commissions of the Indiana broker
would be invalid. But I see no more reason for giving the customer
immunity than I would for giving immunity to the fruit growers who
sold their fruit through the broker in
Gwin, White & Prince
Inc. v. Henneford, supra.
Concededly almost any local activity could, if integrated with
earlier or subsequent transactions, be treated as parts of an
interstate whole. In that view,
American Mfg. Co. v. St.
Louis, 250 U. S. 459,
would find survival difficult. For, in that case, a state tax on a
manufacturer was upheld though the tax was measured by the value of
the goods
Page 329 U. S. 285
manufactured within the State and thereafter sold in interstate
commerce. In
Western Live Stock v. Bureau of Revenue,
303 U. S. 250, a
tax laid on the gross receipts of a trade journal published in New
Mexico was sustained although out-of-state advertisements were
included in the journal and there was interstate distribution of
it. The Court treated the local business as separate and distinct
from the transportation and intercourse which are interstate
commerce and which were employed to conduct the business.
I think the least that can be said is that the local
transactions or activities of this taxpayer can be as easily
untangled from the interstate activities of his broker.
Any receipt of income in Indiana from out-of-state sources
involves, of course, the use of interstate agencies of
communication. That alone, however, is no barrier to its taxation
by Indiana.
Western Live Stock v. Bureau of Revenue,
supra. Cf. New York ex rel. Cohn v. Graves,
300 U. S. 308. The
receipt of income in Indiana, like the delivery of property there,
International Harvester Co. v. Dept. of Treasury,
322 U. S. 340, is
a local transaction which constitutionally can be made a taxable
event. For a local activity which is separate and distinct from
interstate commerce may be taxed though interstate activity is
induced or occasioned by it.
Western Live Stock v. Bureau of
Revenue supra, p.
303 U. S. 253.
The management of an investment portfolio with income from
out-of-state sources is as much a local activity as the manufacture
of goods destined for interstate commerce,
American Mfg. Co. v.
Louis, supra, the publication of a trade journal with
interstate revenues,
Western Live Stock v. Bureau of Revenue,
supra, or the growing of fruit for interstate markets,
Gwin, White & Prince Inc. v. Henneford, supra. All
such taxes affect in some measure interstate commerce or increase
the cost, of doing it. But, as we pointed out in
McGoldrick
v. Berwind-White
Page 329 U. S. 286
Coal Mining Co., 309 U. S. 33,
309 U. S. 48,
that is no constitutional obstacle.
Adams Mfg. Co. v. Storen, 304 U.
S. 307, is different. In that case, the taxpayer had its
factory and place of business in Indiana, and sold its products in
other States on orders taken subject to approval at the home
office. The Court thought the risk of multiple taxation was real,
because of the interstate reach of the taxpayer's business
activities. The fact is that the incidence of that tax was
comparable to the incidence of an unapportioned tax on interstate
freight revenues.
The present tax is not aimed at interstate commerce, and does
not discriminate against it. It is not imposed as a levy for the
privilege of doing it. It is not a tax on interstate transportation
or communication. It is not an exaction on property in its
interstate journey. It is not a tax on interstate selling. The tax
is on the proceeds of the sales less the brokerage commissions, and
therefore does not reach the revenues from the only interstate
activities involved in these transactions. It is therefore
essentially no different, so far as the Commerce Clause is
concerned, from a tax by Indiana on the proceeds of the sale of a
farm or other property in New York where the mails are used to
authorize it, to transmit the deed, and to receive the
proceeds.
I would adhere to the philosophy of our recent cases,* and
affirm the judgment below.
* Of which
Gwin, White & Prince, Inc. v. Henneford,
supra, Western Live Stock v. Bureau of Revenue, supra, and
McGoldrick v. Berwind-White Coal Mining Co., supra, are
illustrative.