1. A provision in a Government bond for payment of principal and
interest "in United States gold coin of the present standard of
value" must be fairly construed, and its reasonable import is an
assurance by the Government that the bondholder will not suffer
loss through depreciation of the medium of payment. P.
294 U. S.
348.
2. The Joint Resolution of June 5, 1933, insofar as it
undertakes to nullify such gold clauses in obligations of the
United States and provides that such obligations shall be
discharged by payment, dollar for dollar, in any coin or currency
which at the time of payment is legal tender for public and private
debts, is unconstitutional. P.
294 U. S.
349.
3. Congress cannot use its power to regulate the value of money
so as to invalidate the obligations which the Government has
theretofore
Page 294 U. S. 331
issued in the exercise of the power to borrow money on the
credit of the United States. Pp.
294 U. S. 350
et seq.
4. There is a clear distinction between the power of Congress to
control or interdict the contracts of private parties when they
interfere with the exercise of its constitutional authority and a
power in Congress to alter or repudiate the substance of its own
engagements when it has borrowed money under its constitutional
authority. P.
294 U. S.
350.
5. By virtue of the power to borrow money "on the credit of the
United States," Congress is authorized to pledge that credit as
assurance of payment as stipulated -- as the highest assurance the
Government can give -- its plighted faith. To say that Congress may
withdraw or ignore that pledge is to assume that the Constitution
contemplates a vain promise, a pledge having no other sanction than
the pleasure and convenience of the pledgor. P.
294 U. S.
351.
6. When the United States, with constitutional authority, makes
contracts, it has rights and incurs responsibilities similar to
those of individuals who are parties to such instruments. P.
294 U. S.
352.
7. The right to make binding obligations is a power of
sovereignty. P.
294 U. S.
353.
8. The sovereignty of the United States resides in the people,
and Congress cannot invoke the sovereignty of the people to
override their will as declared in the Constitution. P.
294 U. S.
353.
9. The power given Congress to borrow money on the credit of the
United States is unqualified and vital to the Government, and the
binding quality of the promise of the United States is of the
essence of the credit pledged. P.
294 U. S.
353.
10. The fact that the United States may not be sued without its
consent is a matter of procedure which does not affect the legality
and binding character of its contracts. P.
294 U. S.
354.
11. Section 4 of the Fourteenth Amendment, declaring that "The
validity of the public debt of the United States, authorized by
law, . . . shall not be questioned," is confirmatory of a
fundamental principle, applying as well to bonds issued after, as
to those issued before, the adoption of the Amendment, and the
expression "validity of the public debt " embraces whatever
concerns the integrity of the public obligations. P.
294 U. S.
354.
12. The holder of a Liberty Bond, which was issued when gold was
in circulation and when the standard of value was the gold dollar
of 25.8 grains, nine-tenths fine, and which promised payment in
gold of that standard, claimed payment after the Government,
pursuant to legislative authority, had withdrawn all gold coin
Page 294 U. S. 332
from circulation, had prohibited its export or its use in
foreign exchange, except for limited purposes under license, and
had reduced the weight of gold representing the standard dollar to
15-5/21 grains and placed all forms of money on a parity with that
standard. The Joint Resolution of June 5, 1933, had enacted that
such bonds should be discharged by payment, dollar for dollar, in
any coin or currency which, at time of payment, was legal tender
for public and private debts. The bondholder, having been refused
payment in gold coin of the former standard or in an equal weight
of gold, demanded currency in an amount exceeding the face of the
bond in the same ratio as that borne by the number of grains in the
former gold dollar to the number in the existing one -- or $1.69 of
currency for every dollar of the bond. The Treasury declined to pay
him more than the face of the bond in currency, and he sued in the
Court of Claims.
Held:
(a) The fact that the Government's repudiation of the gold
clause of the bond is unconstitutional does not entitle the
plaintiff to recover more than the loss he has actually suffered,
and of which he may rightfully complain. P.
294 U. S.
354.
(b) The Court of Claims has no authority to entertain an action
for nominal damages. P.
294 U. S.
355.
(c) The question of actual loss cannot be determined without
considering the economic condition at the time when the Government
offered to pay the face of the bond in legal tender currency. P.
294 U. S.
355.
(d) Congress, by virtue of its power to deal with gold coin as a
medium of exchange, was authorized to prohibit its export and limit
its use in foreign exchange, and the restraint thus imposed upon
holders of such coin was incident to their ownership of it, and
gave them no cause of action. P.
294 U. S.
356.
(e) The Court cannot say that the exercise of this power was
arbitrary or capricious. P.
294 U. S.
356.
(f) The holder of a bond of the United States, payable in gold
coin of the former standard, so far as concerns the restraint upon
the right to export the gold coin or to engage in transactions of
foreign exchange, is in no better case than the holder of gold coin
itself. P.
294 U. S.
356.
(g) In assessing plaintiff's damages, if any, the equivalent in
currency of the gold coin promised can be no more than the amount
of money which the gold coin would be worth to the plaintiff for
the purposes for which it could legally be used. P.
294 U. S.
357.
(h) Foreign dealing being forbidden, save under license, and the
domestic market being not free, but lawfully restricted by
Congress,
Page 294 U. S. 333
valuation of the gold coin would necessarily have regard to its
use as legal tender and as a medium of exchange under a single
monetary system with an established parity of all currency and
coins, and this would involve a consideration of the purchasing
power of the currency dollars. P.
294 U. S.
357.
(i) Plaintiff has not attempted to show that, in relation to
buying power, he has sustained any loss; on the contrary, in view
of the adjustment of the internal economy to the single measure of
value as established by the legislation of the Congress, and the
universal availability and use throughout the country of the legal
tender currency in meeting all engagements, the payment to the
plaintiff of the amount which he demands would appear to constitute
not a recoupment of loss in any proper sense, but an unjustified
enrichment. P.
294 U. S.
357.
Question answered " No."
Response to questions certified by the Court of Claims in an
action on a Liberty Loan Gold Bond.
Page 294 U. S. 346
MR. CHIEF JUSTICE HUGHES delivered the opinion of the Court.
The certificate from the Court of Claims shows the following
facts:
Plaintiff brought suit as the owner of an obligation of the
United States for $10,000, known as "Fourth Liberty Loan 4 1/4%
Gold Bond of 1933-1938." This bond was issued pursuant to the Act
of September 24, 1917, § 1
et seq. (40 Stat. 288), as
amended, and Treasury Department circular No. 121 dated September
28, 1918. The bond
Page 294 U. S. 347
provided: "The principal and interest hereof are payable in
United States gold coin of the present standard of value."
Plaintiff alleged in his petition that, at the time the bond was
issued and when he acquired it, "a dollar in gold consisted of 25.8
grains of gold .9 fine;" that the bond was called for redemption on
April 15, 1934, and, on May 24, 1934, was presented for payment;
that plaintiff demanded its redemption "by the payment of 10,000
gold dollars each containing 25.8 grains of gold .9 fine;" that
defendant refused to comply with that demand, and that plaintiff
then demanded
"258,000 grains of gold .9 fine, or gold of equivalent value of
any fineness, or 16,931.25 gold dollars each containing 15 5/21
grains of gold .9 fine, or 16,931.25 dollars in legal tender
currency;"
that defendant refused to redeem the bond "except by the payment
of 10,000 dollars in legal tender currency;" that these refusals
were based on the Joint Resolution of the Congress of June 5, 1933,
48 Stat. 113, but that this enactment was unconstitutional, as it
operated to deprive plaintiff of his property without due process
of law, and that, by this action of defendant, he was damaged "in
the sum of $16,931.25, the value of defendant's obligation," for
which, with interest, plaintiff demanded judgment.
Defendant demurred upon the ground that the petition did not
state a cause of action against the United States.
The Court of Claims has certified the following questions:
"1. Is the claimant, being the holder and owner of a Fourth
Liberty Loan 4 1/4% bond of the United States, of the principal
amount of $10,000, issued in 1918, which was payable on and after
April 15, 1934, and which bond contained a clause that the
principal is 'payable in United States gold coin of the present
standard of value,' entitled to receive from the United States an
amount in legal tender currency in excess of the face amount of the
bond? "
Page 294 U. S. 348
"2. Is the United States, as obligor in a Fourth Liberty Loan 4
1/4% gold bond, Series of 1933-1938, as stated in Question One,
liable to respond in damages in a suit in the Court of Claims on
such bond as an express contract by reason of the change in or
impossibility of performance in accordance with the tenor thereof
due to the provisions of Public Resolution No. 10, 73rd Congress,
abrogating the gold clause in all obligations?"
First. The Import of the Obligation. The bond in suit
differs from an obligation of private parties, or of states or
municipalities, whose contracts are necessarily made in subjection
to the dominant power of the Congress.
Norman v. Baltimore
& Ohio R. Co., ante, p.
294 U. S. 240. The
bond now before us is an obligation of the United States. The terms
of the bond are explicit. They were not only expressed in the bond
itself, but they were definitely prescribed by the Congress. The
Act of September 24, 1917, both in its original and amended form,
authorized the moneys to be borrowed, and the bonds to be issued,
"on the credit of the United States" in order to meet expenditures
needed "for the national security and defense and other public
purposes authorized by law." Section 1, 40 Stat. 288, as amended by
Act April 4, 1918, § 1, 40 Stat. 503. The circular of the Treasury
Department of September 28, 1918, to which the bond refers "for a
statement of the further rights of the holders of bonds of said
series" also provided that the principal and interest "are payable
in United States gold coin of the present standard of value."
This obligation must be fairly construed. The "
present
standard of value" stood in contradistinction to a
lower
standard of value. The promise obviously was intended to afford
protection against loss. That protection was sought to be secured
by setting up a standard or measure of the government's obligation.
We think that the reasonable import of the promise is that it was
intended
Page 294 U. S. 349
to assure one who lent his money to the government and took its
bond that he would not suffer loss through depreciation in the
medium of payment.
The government states in its brief that the total unmatured
interest-bearing obligations of the United States outstanding on
May 31, 1933 (which it is understood contained a "gold clause"
substantially the same as that of the bond in suit), amounted to
about twenty-one billions of dollars. From statements at the bar,
it appears that this amount has been reduced to approximately
twelve billions at the present time, and that, during the
intervening period, the public debt of the United States has risen
some seven billions (making a total of approximately twenty-eight
billions five hundred millions) by the issue of some sixteen
billions five hundred millions of dollars "of nongold-clause
obligations."
Second. The Binding Quality of the Obligation. The
question is necessarily presented whether the Joint Resolution of
June 5, 1933, 48 Stat. 113, is a valid enactment so far as it
applies to the obligations of the United States. The resolution
declared that provisions requiring "payment in gold or a particular
kind of coin or currency" were "against public policy," and
provided that "every obligation, heretofore or hereafter incurred,
whether or not any such provision is contained therein," shall be
discharged "upon payment, dollar for dollar, in any coin or
currency which at the time of payment is legal tender for public
and private debts." This enactment was expressly extended to
obligations of the United States, and provisions for payment in
gold, "contained in any law authorizing obligations to be issued by
or under authority of the United States," were repealed. [
Footnote 1]
Page 294 U. S. 350
There is no question as to the power of the Congress to regulate
the value of money -- that is, to establish a monetary system, and
thus to determine the currency of the country. The question is
whether the Congress can use that power so as to invalidate the
terms of the obligations which the government has theretofore
issued in the exercise of the power to borrow money on the credit
of the United States. In attempted justification of the Joint
Resolution in relation to the outstanding bonds of the United
States, the government argues that
"earlier Congresses could not validly restrict the 73rd Congress
from exercising its constitutional powers to regulate the value of
money, borrow money, or regulate foreign and interstate
commerce;"
and, from this premise, the government seems to deduce the
proposition that, when, with adequate authority, the government
borrows money and pledges the credit of the United States, it is
free to ignore that pledge and alter the terms of its obligations
in case a later Congress finds their fulfillment inconvenient. The
government's contention thus raises a question of far greater
importance than the particular claim of the plaintiff. On that
reasoning, if the terms of the government's bond as to the standard
of payment can be repudiated, it inevitably follows that the
obligation as to the amount to be paid may also be repudiated. The
contention necessarily imports that the Congress can disregard the
obligations of the government at its discretion, and that, when the
government borrows money, the credit of the United States is an
illusory pledge.
We do not so read the Constitution. There is a clear distinction
between the power of the Congress to control or interdict the
contracts of private parties when they interfere with the exercise
of its constitutional authority
Page 294 U. S. 351
and the power of the Congress to alter or repudiate the
substance of its own engagements when it has borrowed money under
the authority which the Constitution confers. In authorizing the
Congress to borrow money, the Constitution empowers the Congress to
fix the amount to be borrowed and the terms of payment. By virtue
of the power to borrow money "on the credit of the United States,"
the Congress is authorized to pledge that credit as an assurance of
payment as stipulated, as the highest assurance the government can
give -- its plighted faith. To say that the Congress may withdraw
or ignore that pledge is to assume that the Constitution
contemplates a vain promise, a pledge having no other sanction than
the pleasure and convenience of the pledgor. This Court has given
no sanction to such a conception of the obligations of our
government.
The binding quality of the obligations of the government was
considered in the
Sinking Fund Cases, 99 U. S.
700,
99 U. S.
718-719. The question before the Court in those cases
was whether certain action was warranted by a reservation to the
Congress of the right to amend the charter of a railroad company.
While the particular action was sustained under this right of
amendment, the Court took occasion to state emphatically the
obligatory character of the contracts of the United States. The
Court said:
"The United States are as much bound by their contracts as are
individuals. If they repudiate their obligations, it is as much
repudiation, with all the wrong and reproach that term implies, as
it would be if the repudiator had been a state or a municipality or
a citizen. [
Footnote 2] "
Page 294 U. S. 352
When the United States, with constitutional authority, makes
contracts, it has rights and incurs responsibilities similar to
those of individuals who are parties to such instruments. There is
no difference, said the Court in
United
States v. Bank of the Metropolis, 15 Pet. 377,
40 U. S. 392,
except that the United States cannot be sued without its consent.
See also The Floyd
Acceptances, 7 Wall. 666,
74 U. S. 675;
Cooke v. United States, 91 U. S. 389,
91 U. S. 396.
In
Lynch v. United States, 292 U.
S. 571,
292 U. S. 580,
with respect to an attempted abrogation by the Act of March 20,
1933, § 17, 48 Stat. 8, 11, of certain outstanding war risk
insurance policies, which were contracts of the United States, the
Court quoted with approval the statement in the
Sinking Fund
Cases, supra, and said:
"Punctilious fulfillment of contractual obligations is essential
to the maintenance of the credit of public, as well as private,
debtors. No doubt there was in March, 1933, great need of economy.
In the administration of all government business, economy had
become urgent because of lessened revenues and the heavy
obligations to be issued in the hope of relieving widespread
distress. Congress was free to reduce gratuities deemed excessive.
But Congress was without power to reduce expenditures by abrogating
contractual obligations of the United States. To abrogate contracts
in the attempt to lessen government expenditure would
Page 294 U. S. 353
be not the practice of economy, but an act of repudiation."
The argument in favor of the Joint Resolution, as applied to
government bonds, is in substance that the government cannot, by
contract, restrict the exercise of a sovereign power. But the right
to make binding obligations is a competence attaching to
sovereignty. [
Footnote 3] In
the United States, sovereignty resides in the people, who act
through the organs established by the Constitution.
Chisholm v.
Georgia, 2 Dall. 419,
2 U. S. 471;
Penhallow v. Doane's
Administrators, 3 Dall. 54,
3 U.S. 93;
McCulloch
v. Maryland, 4 Wheat. 316,
17 U. S.
404-405;
Yick Wo v. Hopkins, 118 U.
S. 356,
118 U. S. 370.
The Congress, as the instrumentality of sovereignty, is endowed
with certain powers to be exerted on behalf of the people in the
manner and with the effect the Constitution ordains. The Congress
cannot invoke the sovereign power of the people to override their
will as thus declared. The powers conferred upon the Congress are
harmonious. The Constitution gives to the Congress the power to
borrow money on the credit of the United States, an unqualified
power, a power vital to the government, upon which in an extremity
its very life may depend. The binding quality of the promise of the
United States is of the essence of the credit which is so pledged.
Having this power to authorize the issue of definite obligations
for the payment of money borrowed, the Congress has not been vested
with authority to alter or destroy those obligations.
Page 294 U. S. 354
The fact that the United States may not be sued without its
consent is a matter of procedure which does not affect the legal
and binding character of its contracts. While the Congress is under
no duty to provide remedies through the courts, the contractual
obligation still exists, and, despite infirmities of procedure,
remains binding upon the conscience of the sovereign.
Lynch v.
United States, supra, pp.
292 U. S.
580-582.
The Fourteenth Amendment, in its fourth section, explicitly
declares: "The validity of the public debt of the United States,
authorized by law, . . . shall not be questioned." While this
provision was undoubtedly inspired by the desire to put beyond
question the obligations of the government issued during the Civil
War, its language indicates a broader connotation. We regard it as
confirmatory of a fundamental principle which applies as well to
the government bonds in question, and to others duly authorized by
the Congress, as to those issued before the Amendment was adopted.
Nor can we perceive any reason for not considering the expression
"the
validity of the public debt" as embracing whatever
concerns the integrity of the public obligations.
We conclude that the Joint Resolution of June 5, 1933, insofar
as it attempted to override the obligation created by the bond in
suit, went beyond the congressional power.
Third. The Question of Damages. In this view of the
binding quality of the government's obligations, we come to the
question as to the plaintiff's right to recover damages. That is a
distinct question. Because the government is not at liberty to
alter or repudiate its obligations, it does not follow that the
claim advanced by the plaintiff should be sustained. The action is
for breach of contract. As a remedy for breach, plaintiff can
recover no more than the loss he has suffered, and of which he may
rightfully complain. He is not entitled to be enriched.
Page 294 U. S. 355
Plaintiff seeks judgment for $16,931.25, in present legal tender
currency, on his bond for $10,000. The question is whether he has
shown damage to that extent, or any actual damage, as the Court of
Claims has no authority to entertain an action for nominal damages.
Grant v. United
States, 7 Wall. 331,
74 U. S. 338;
Marion & R.V. Ry. Co. v. United States, 270 U.
S. 280,
270 U. S. 282;
Nortz v. United States, ante, p.
294 U. S. 317.
Plaintiff computes his claim for $16,931.25 by taking the weight
of the gold dollar as fixed by the President's proclamation of
January 31, 1934, under the Act of May 12, 1933 (48 Stat. 52, 53),
as amended by the Act of January 30, 1934 (48 Stat. 342) -- that
is, at 15 5/21 grains nine-tenths fine, as compared with the weight
fixed by the Act of March 14, 1900 (31 Stat. 46) -- or 25.8 grains
nine-tenths fine. But the change in the weight of the gold dollar
did not necessarily cause loss to the plaintiff of the amount
claimed. The question of actual loss cannot fairly be determined
without considering the economic situation at the time the
government offered to pay him the $10,000, the face of his bond, in
legal tender currency. The case is not the same as if gold coin had
remained in circulation. That was the situation at the time of the
decisions under the legal tender acts of 1862 and 1863.
Bronson v.
Rodes, 7 Wall. 229,
74 U. S. 251;
Trebilcock v.
Wilson, 12 Wall. 687,
79 U. S. 695;
Thompson v. Butler, 95 U. S. 694,
95 U. S.
696-697. Before the change in the weight of the gold
dollar in 1934, gold coin had been withdrawn from circulation.
[
Footnote 4] The Congress had
authorized the prohibition of the exportation of gold coin and the
placing of restrictions upon transactions in foreign exchange. Acts
of March 9, 1933,
Page 294 U. S. 356
48 Stat. 1; January 30, 1934, 48 Stat. 337. Such dealings could
be had only for limited purposes and under license. Executive
Orders of April 20, 1933, August 28, 1933, and January 15, 1934.
That action the Congress was entitled to take by virtue of its
authority to deal with gold coin as a medium of exchange. And the
restraint thus imposed upon holders of gold coin was incident to
the limitations which inhered in their ownership of that coin and
gave them no right of action.
Ling Su Fan v. United
States, 218 U. S. 302,
218 U. S.
310-311. The Court said in that case:
"Conceding the title of the owner of such coins, yet there is
attached to such ownership those limitations which public policy
may require by reason of their quality as a legal tender and as a
medium of exchange. These limitations are due to the fact that
public law gives to such coinage a value which does not attach as a
mere consequence of intrinsic value. Their quality as a legal
tender is an attribute of law aside from their bullion value. They
bear therefore the impress of sovereign power which fixes value and
authorizes their use in exchange. . . . However unwise a law may be
aimed at the exportation of such coins, in the face of the axioms
against obstructing the free flow of commerce, there can be no
serious doubt but that the power to coin money includes the power
to prevent its outflow from the country of its origin."
The same reasoning is applicable to the imposition of restraints
upon transactions in foreign exchange. We cannot say, in view of
the conditions that existed, that the Congress having this power
exercised it arbitrarily or capriciously. And the holder of an
obligation, or bond, of the United States, payable in gold coin of
the former standard, so far as the restraint upon the right to
export gold coin or to engage in transactions in foreign exchange
is concerned, was in no better case than the holder of gold coin
itself.
Page 294 U. S. 357
In considering what damages, if any, the plaintiff has sustained
by the alleged breach of his bond, it is hence inadmissible to
assume that he was entitled to obtain gold coin for recourse to
foreign markets or for dealings in foreign exchange or for other
purposes contrary to the control over gold coin which the Congress
had the power to exert, and had exerted, in its monetary
regulation. Plaintiff's damages could not be assessed without
regard to the internal economy of the country at the time the
alleged breach occurred. The discontinuance of gold payments and
the establishment of legal tender currency on a standard unit of
value with which "all forms of money" of the United States were to
be "maintained at a parity" had a controlling influence upon the
domestic economy. It was adjusted to the new basis. A free domestic
market for gold was nonexistent.
Plaintiff demands the "equivalent" in currency of the gold coin
promised. But "equivalent" cannot mean more than the amount of
money which the promised gold coin would be worth to the bondholder
for the purposes for which it could legally be used. That
equivalence or worth could not properly be ascertained save in the
light of the domestic and restricted market which the Congress had
lawfully established. In the domestic transactions to which the
plaintiff was limited, in the absence of special license,
determination of the value of the gold coin would necessarily have
regard to its use as legal tender and as a medium of exchange under
a single monetary system with an established parity of all currency
and coins. And, in view of the control of export and foreign
exchange, and the restricted domestic use, the question of value,
in relation to transactions legally available to the plaintiff,
would require a consideration of the purchasing power of the
dollars which the plaintiff could have received. Plaintiff has not
shown, or attempted to show, that, in relation to buying power, he
has sustained any loss whatever. On
Page 294 U. S. 358
the contrary, in view of the adjustment of the internal economy
to the single measure of value as established by the legislation of
the Congress, and the universal availability and use throughout the
country of the legal tender currency in meeting all engagements,
the payment to the plaintiff of the amount which he demands would
appear to constitute not a recoupment of loss in any proper sense,
but an unjustified enrichment.
Plaintiff seeks to make his case solely upon the theory that, by
reason of the change in the weight of the dollar he is entitled to
$1.69 in the present currency for every dollar promised by the
bond, regardless of any actual loss he has suffered with respect to
any transaction in which his dollars may be used. We think that
position is untenable.
In the view that the facts alleged by the petition fail to show
a cause of action for actual damages, the first question submitted
by the Court of Claims is answered in the negative. It is not
necessary to answer the second question.
Question No. 1 is answered "No."
*
See note, p. 240.
[
Footnote 1]
And subdivision (b) of § 1 of the Joint Resolution of June 5,
1933, provided:
"As used in this resolution, the term 'obligation' means an
obligation (including every obligation of and to the United States,
excepting currency) payable in money of the United States, and the
term 'coin or currency' means coin or currency of the United
States, including Federal Reserve notes and circulating notes of
Federal Reserve banks and national banking associations."
[
Footnote 2]
Mr. Justice Strong, who had written the opinion of the majority
of the Court in the legal tender cases (
Knox v.
Lee, 12 Wall. 457), dissented in the
Sinking
Fund Cases, 99 U.S. p.
99 U. S. 731,
because he thought that the action of the Congress was not
consistent with the government's engagement, and hence was a
transgression of legislative power. And, with respect to the
sanctity of the contracts of the government, he quoted, with
approval, the opinion of Mr. Hamilton in his communication to the
Senate of January 20, 1795 (citing 3 Hamilton's Works, 518, 519),
that
"when a government enters into a contract with an individual, it
deposes, as to the matter of the contract, its constitutional
authority, and exchanges the character of legislator for that of a
moral agent, with the same rights and obligations as an individual.
Its promises may be justly considered as excepted out of its power
to legislate, unless in aid of them. It is in theory impossible to
reconcile the idea of a promise which obliges with a power to make
a law which can vary the effect of it."
[
Footnote 3]
Oppenheim, International Law (4th Ed.) vol. 1, §§ 493, 494. This
is recognized in the field of international engagements. Although
there may be no judicial procedure by which such contracts may be
enforced in the absence of the consent of the sovereign to be sued,
the engagement validly made by a sovereign state is not without
legal force, as readily appears if the jurisdiction to entertain a
controversy with respect to the performance of the engagement is
conferred upon an international tribunal. Hall, International Law
(8th Ed.) § 107; Oppenheim,
loc. cit.; Hyde, International
Law, vol. 2, § 489.
[
Footnote 4]
In its Report of May 27, 1933, it was stated by the Senate
Committee on Banking and Currency: "By the Emergency Banking Act
and the existing Executive Orders, gold is not now paid, or
obtainable for payment, on obligations public or private." Sen.Rep.
No. 99, 73d Cong., 1st Sess.
MR. JUSTICE STONE, concurring.
I agree that the answer to the first question is "No," but I
think our opinion should be confined to answering that question,
and that it should essay an answer to no other.
I do not doubt that the gold clause in the government bonds,
like that in the private contracts just considered, calls for the
payment of value in money, measured by a stated number of gold
dollars of the standard defined in the clause,
Feist v. Societe
Intercommunale Belge d'Electricite [1934] A.C. 161, 170-173;
Serbian and Brazilian Bond Cases, P.C.I.J., series A. Nos. 20, 21,
pp. 32-34, 109-119. In the absence of any further exertion of
governmental power, that obligation plainly could not be
Page 294 U. S. 359
satisfied by payment of the same number of dollars, either
specie or paper, measured by a gold dollar of lesser weight,
regardless of their purchasing power or the state of our internal
economy at the due date.
I do not understand the government to contend that it is any the
less bound by the obligation than a private individual would be, or
that it is free to disregard it except in the exercise of the
constitutional power "to coin money" and "regulate the value
thereof." In any case, there is before us no question of default
apart from the regulation by Congress of the use of gold as
currency.
While the government's refusal to make the stipulated payment is
a measure taken in the exercise of that power, this does not
disguise the fact that its action is to that extent a repudiation
of its undertaking. As much as I deplore this refusal to fulfill
the solemn promise of bonds of the United States, I cannot escape
the conclusion, announced for the Court, that, in the situation now
presented, the government, through the exercise of its sovereign
power to regulate the value of money, has rendered itself immune
from liability for its action. To that extent, it has relieved
itself of the obligation of its domestic bonds, precisely as it has
relieved the obligors of private bonds in
Norman v. Baltimore
& Ohio R. Co., ante, p.
294 U. S. 240.
In this posture of the case, it is unnecessary, and I think
undesirable, for the Court to undertake to say that the obligation
of the gold clause in government bonds is greater than in the bonds
of private individuals, or that, in some situation not described,
and in some manner and in some measure undefined, it has imposed
restrictions upon the future exercise of the power to regulate the
currency. I am not persuaded that we should needlessly intimate any
opinion which implies that the obligation may so operate, for
example, as to interpose a serious obstacle to the adoption of
measures for stabilization of
Page 294 U. S. 360
the dollar, should Congress think it wise to accomplish that
purpose by resumption of gold payments, in dollars of the present
or any other gold content less than that specified in the gold
clause, and by the reestablishment of a free market for gold and
its free exportation.
There is no occasion now to resolve doubts, which I entertain,
with respect to these questions. At present, they are academic.
Concededly they may be transferred wholly to the realm of
speculation by the exercise of the undoubted power of the
government to withdraw the privilege of suit upon its gold clause
obligations. We have just held that the Court of Claims was without
power to entertain the suit in
Nortz v. United States,
ante, p.
294 U. S. 317,
because, regardless of the nature of the obligation of the gold
certificates, there was no damage. Here it is declared that there
is no damage because Congress, by the exercise of its power to
regulate the currency, has made it impossible for the plaintiff to
enjoy the benefits of gold payments promised by the government. It
would seem that this would suffice to dispose of the present case,
without attempting to prejudge the rights of other bondholders and
of the government under other conditions which may never occur. It
will not benefit this plaintiff, to whom we deny any remedy, to be
assured that he has an inviolable right to performance of the gold
clause.
Moreover, if the gold clause be viewed as a gold value contract,
as it is in
Norman v. Baltimore & Ohio R. Co., supra,
it is to be noted that the government has not prohibited the free
use by the bondholder of the paper money equivalent of the gold
clause obligation; it is the prohibition, by the Joint Resolution
of Congress, of payment of the increased number of depreciated
dollars required to make up the full equivalent, which alone bars
recovery.
Page 294 U. S. 361
In that case, it would seem to be implicit in our decision that
the prohibition, at least in the present situation, is itself a
constitutional exercise of the power to regulate the value of
money.
I therefore do not join in so much of the opinion as may be
taken to suggest that the exercise of the sovereign power to borrow
money on credit, which does not override the sovereign immunity
from suit, may nevertheless preclude or impede the exercise of
another sovereign power, to regulate the value of money; or to
suggest that, although there is and can be no present cause of
action upon the repudiated gold clause, its obligation is
nevertheless, in some manner and to some extent not stated,
superior to the power to regulate the currency which we now hold to
be superior to the obligation of the bonds.
MR. JUSTICE McREYNOLDS, MR. JUSTICE VAN DEVANTER, MR. JUSTICE
SUTHERLAND and MR. JUSTICE BUTLER, dissent.
See below.
MR. JUSTICE McREYNOLDS, dissenting.
MR. JUSTICE VAN DEVANTER, MR. JUSTICE SUTHERLAND, MR. JUSTICE
BUTLER, and I conclude that, if given effect, the enactments here
challenged will bring about confiscation of property rights and
repudiation of national obligations. Acquiescence in the decisions
just announced
Page 294 U. S. 362
is impossible; the circumstances demand statement of our
views.
"To let oneself slide down the easy slope offered by the course
of events and to dull one's mind against the extent of the danger,
. . . that is precisely to fail in one's obligation of
responsibility."
Just men regard repudiation and spoliation of citizens by their
sovereign with abhorrence; but we are asked to affirm that the
Constitution has granted power to accomplish both. No definite
delegation of such a power exists, and we cannot believe the
far-seeing framers, who labored with hope of establishing justice
and securing the blessings of liberty, intended that the expected
government should have authority to annihilate its own obligations
and destroy the very rights which they were endeavoring to protect.
Not only is there no permission for such actions, they are
inhibited. And no plenitude of words can conform them to our
charter.
The federal government is one of delegated and limited powers
which derive from the Constitution. "It can exercise only the
powers granted to it." Powers claimed must be denied unless
granted. and, as with other writings, the whole of the Constitution
is for consideration when one seeks to ascertain the meaning of any
part.
-----
By the so-called gold clause -- promise to pay in "United States
gold coin of the present standard of value," or "of or equal to the
present standard of weight and fineness" -- found in very many
private and public obligations, the creditor agrees to accept and
the debtor undertakes to return the thing loaned or its equivalent.
Thereby each secures protection, one against decrease in value of
the currency, the other against an increase.
The clause is not new or obscure or discolored by any sinister
purpose. For more than 100 years, our citizens have employed a like
agreement. During the War between the States, its equivalent
"payable in coin" aided
Page 294 U. S. 363
in surmounting financial difficulties. From the housetop men
proclaimed its merits while bonds for billions were sold to support
the World War. The Treaty of Versailles recognized it as
appropriate and just. It appears in the obligations which have
rendered possible our great undertakings -- public works,
railroads, buildings.
Under the interpretation accepted here for many years, this
clause expresses a definite enforceable contract. Both by statute
and long use, the United States have approved it. Over and over
again they have enjoyed the added value which it gave to their
obligations. So late as May 2, 1933, they issued to the public more
than $550,000,000 of their notes, each of which carried a solemn
promise to pay in standard gold coin. (Before that day, this coin
had in fact been withdrawn from circulation, but statutory measure
of value remained the gold dollar of 25.8 grains.)
The Permanent Court of International Justice interpreted the
clause as this Court had done and upheld it. Cases of Serbian and
Brazilian Loans, Publications P.C.I.J., Series A, Nos. 20, 21
(1929). It was there declared: "The gold clause merely prevents the
borrower from availing itself of a possibility of discharge of the
debt in depreciated currency," and
"The treatment of the gold clause as indicating a mere modality
of payment, without reference to a gold standard of value, would
be, not to construe but to destroy it."
In
Feist v. Societe Intercommunale Belge d'Electricite
(1934), A.C. 161, the House of Lords expressed like views.
Gregory v. Morris, 96 U. S. 619,
96 U. S.
624-625 -- last of similar causes -- construed and
sanctioned this stipulation. In behalf of all, Chief Justice Waite
there said:
"The obligation secured by the mortgage or lien under which
Morris held was for the payment of gold coin, or, as was said in
Bronson
v. Rodes, 7 Wall. 229,"
"An
Page 294 U. S. 364
agreement to deliver a certain weight of standard gold, to be
ascertained by a count of coins, each of which is certified to
contain a definite proportion of that weight,"
"and is not distinguishable 'from a contract to deliver an equal
weight of bullion of equal fineness.' . . . We think it clear that,
under such circumstances, it was within the power of the court, so
far as Gregory was concerned, to treat the contract as one for the
delivery of so much gold bullion, and, if Morris was willing to
accept a judgment which might be discharged in currency, to have
his damages estimated according to the currency value of
bullion."
Earlier cases --
Bronson v.
Rodes, 7 Wall. 229;
Butler v.
Horwitz, 7 Wall. 258;
Dewing v.
Sears, 11 Wall. 379;
Trebilcock
v. Wilson, 12 Wall. 687;
Thompson v.
Butler, 95 U. S. 694 --
while important, need not be dissected.
Gregory v. Morris
is in harmony with them, and the opinion there definitely and
finally stated the doctrine which we should apply.
It is true to say that the gold clauses
"were intended to afford a definite standard or measure of
value, and thus to protect against a depreciation of the currency
and against the discharge of the obligation by payment of less than
that prescribed."
Furthermore, they furnish means for computing the sum payable in
currency if gold should become unobtainable. The borrower agrees to
repay in gold coin containing 25.8 grains to the dollar, and if
this cannot be secured, the promise is to discharge the obligation
by paying for each dollar loaned the currency value of that number
of grains. Thus the purpose of the parties will be carried out.
Irrespective of any change in currency, the thing loaned or an
equivalent will be returned -- nothing more, nothing less. The
present currency consists of promises to pay dollars of 15 5/21
grains; the government procures gold bullion on that
Page 294 U. S. 365
basis. The calculation to determine the damages for failure to
pay in gold would not be difficult.
Gregory v. Morris
points the way.
-----
Under appropriate statutes, the United States for many years
issued gold certificates, in the following form:
"This certifies that there have been deposited in the Treasury
of The United States of America One Thousand Dollars in gold coin
payable to the bearer on demand. This certificate is a legal tender
in the amount thereof in payment of all debts and dues public and
private."
The certificates here involved -- series 1928 -- were issued
under § 6, Act March 14, 1900, 31 Stat. 47, as amended.
See U.S.C., Title 31, § 429. [
Footnote 2/1]
In view of the statutory direction that gold coin for which
certificates are issued shall be held for their payment on demand
"and used for no other purpose," it seems idle to argue (as counsel
for the United States did) that other use is permissible under the
ancient Act of March 3, 1863.
By various orders of the President and the Treasury from April 5
to December 28, 1933, persons holding gold certificates were
required to deliver them, and accept
"an equivalent amount of any form of coin or currency coined
Page 294 U. S. 366
or issued under the laws of the United States designated by the
Secretary of the Treasury."
Heavy penalties were provided for failure to comply.
That the holder of one of these certificates was owner of an
express promise by the United States to deliver gold coin of the
weight and fineness established by statute when the certificate
issued, or if such demand was not honored to pay the holder the
value in the currency then in use, seems clear enough. This was the
obvious design of the contract.
-----
The Act of March 14, 1900, 31 Stat. c. 41, as amended, in effect
until January 31, 1934, provided:
"That the dollar consisting of twenty-five and eight tenths
grains of gold nine-tenths fine shall be the standard unit of
value, and all forms of money issued or coined by the United States
shall be maintained at a parity of value with this standard,"
and also
"The Secretary of the Treasury is authorized and directed to
receive deposits of gold coin with the Treasurer . . . in sums of
not less than $20, and to issue gold certificates therefor in
denominations of not less than $10, and the coin so deposited shall
be retained in the Treasury and held for the payment of such
certificates on demand, and used for no other purpose."
See U.S.C., Title 31, §§ 314, 429.
The Act of February 4, 1910, 36 Stat. c. 25, p. 192, directed
that
"any bonds and certificates of indebtedness of the United States
issued after February 4, 1910, shall be payable, principal and
interest, in United States gold coin of the present standard of
value."
By Executive Orders, Nos. 6102, 6111, April 5, and April 20,
1933, the President undertook to require owners of gold coin, gold
bullion, and gold
Page 294 U. S. 367
certificates, to deliver them on or before May 1st to a Federal
Reserve Bank, and to prohibit the exportation of gold coin, gold
bullion, or gold certificates. As a consequence, the United States
were off the gold standard, and their paper money began a rapid
decline in the markets of the world. Gold coin, gold certificates,
and gold bullion were no longer obtainable. "Gold is not now paid,
nor is it available for payment, upon public or private debts" was
declared in Treasury statement of May 27, 1933, and this is still
true. All gold coins have been melted into bars.
The Agricultural Adjustment Act of May 12, 1933, 48 Stat. c. 25,
pp. 31, 52-53, entitled
"An act to relieve the existing national economic emergency by
increasing agricultural purchasing power, to raise revenue for
extraordinary expenses incurred by reason of such emergency, to
provide emergency relief with respect to agricultural indebtedness,
to provide for the orderly liquidation of joint-stock land banks,
and for other purposes"
by § 43 provides that
"such notes [United States notes] and all other coins and
currencies heretofore or hereafter coined or issued by or under the
authority of the United States shall be legal tender for all debts
public and private."
Also that the President, by proclamation, may
"fix the weight of the gold dollar . . . as he finds necessary
from his investigation to stabilize domestic prices or to protect
the foreign commerce against the adverse effect of depreciated
foreign currencies."
And, further,
"such gold dollar, the weight of which is so fixed, shall be the
standard unit of value, and all forms of money issued or coined by
the United States shall be maintained at a parity with this
standard, and it shall be the duty of the Secretary of the Treasury
to maintain such parity, but in no event shall the weight of the
gold dollar be fixed so as to reduce its present weight by more
than 50 percentum."
The Gold Reserve Act of January 30, 1934, 48 Stat. c. 6, pp.
337, 342 undertook to ratify preceding Presidential orders and
proclamations requiring surrender of gold,
Page 294 U. S. 368
but prohibited him from establishing the weight of the gold
dollar "at more than 60 percentum of its present weight." By
proclamation, January 31, 1934, he directed that thereafter the
standard should contain 15 5/21 grains of gold, nine-tenths fine.
(The weight had been 25.8 grains since 1837.) No such dollar has
been coined at any time.
On June 5, 1933, Congress passed a "Joint Resolution to assure
uniform value to the coins and currencies of the United States." 48
Stat. c. 48, p. 112. This recited that holding and dealing in gold
affect the public interest and are therefore subject to regulation;
that the provisions of obligations which purport to give the
obligee the right to require payment in gold coin or in any amount
of money of the United States measured thereby obstruct the power
of Congress to regulate the value of money, and are inconsistent
with the policy to maintain the equal value of every dollar coined
or issued. It then declared that every provision in any obligation
purporting to give the obligee a right to require payment in gold
is against public policy, and directed that
"every obligation, heretofore or hereafter incurred, whether or
not any such provision is contained therein or made with respect
thereto, shall be discharged upon payment, dollar for dollar, in
any coin or currency which at the time of payment is legal tender
for public and private debts."
-----
Four causes are here for decision. Two of them arise out of
corporate obligations containing gold clauses -- railroad bonds.
One is based on a United States Fourth Liberty Loan bond of 1918,
called for payment April 15, 1934, containing a promise to pay "in
United States gold coin of the present standard of value" with
interest in like gold coin. Another involves gold certificates,
series 1928, amounting to $106,300.
Page 294 U. S. 369
As to the corporate bonds the defense is that the gold clause
was destroyed by the Joint Resolution of June 5, 1933, and this
view is sustained by the majority of the Court.
It is insisted that the agreement, in the Liberty bond, to pay
in gold, also was destroyed by the Act of June 5, 1933. This view
is rejected by the majority; but they seem to conclude that,
because of the action of Congress in declaring the holding of gold
unlawful, no appreciable damage resulted when payment therein or
the equivalent was denied.
Concerning the gold certificates, it is ruled that, if upon
presentation for redemption gold coin had been paid to the holder,
as promised, he would have been required to return this to the
Treasury. He could not have exported it or dealt with it.
Consequently he sustained no actual damage.
There is no challenge here of the power of Congress to adopt
such proper "Monetary Policy" as it may deem necessary in order to
provide for national obligations and furnish an adequate medium of
exchange for public use. The plan under review in the Legal Tender
cases was declared within the limits of the Constitution, but not
without a strong dissent. The conclusions there announced are not
now questioned, and any abstract discussion of congressional power
over money would only tend to befog the real issue.
The fundamental problem now presented is whether recent statutes
passed by Congress in respect of money and credits were designed to
attain a legitimate end. Or whether, under the guise of pursuing a
monetary policy, Congress really has inaugurated a plan primarily
designed to destroy private obligations, repudiate national debts,
and drive into the Treasury all gold within the country is exchange
for inconvertible promises to pay, of much less value.
Page 294 U. S. 370
Considering all the circumstances, we must conclude they show
that the plan disclosed is of the latter description, and its
enforcement would deprive the parties before us of their rights
under the Constitution. Consequently the Court should do what it
can to afford adequate relief.
-----
What has been already said will suffice to indicate the nature
of these causes, and something of our general views concerning the
intricate problems presented. A detailed consideration of them
would require much time and elaboration; would greatly extend this
opinion. Considering also the importance of the result to
legitimate commerce, it seems desirable that the Court's decision
should be announced at this time. Accordingly, we will only
undertake in what follows to outline with brevity our replies to
the conclusions reached by the majority and to suggest some of the
reasons which lend support to our position.
The authority exercised by the President and the Treasury in
demanding all gold coin, bullion, and certificates is not now
challenged; neither is the right of the former to prescribe weight
for the standard dollar. These things we have not considered.
Plainly, however, to coin money and regulate the value thereof
calls for legislative action.
Intelligent discussion respecting dollars requires recognition
of the fact that the word may refer to very different things.
Formerly the standard gold dollar weighed 25.8 grains; the weight
now prescribed is 15 5/21 grains. Evidently promises to pay one or
the other of these differ greatly in value, and this must be kept
in mind.
From 1792 to 1873, both the gold and silver dollar were standard
and legal tender, coinage was free and unlimited. Persistent
efforts were made to keep both in circulation. Because the
prescribed relation between them got out of
Page 294 U. S. 371
harmony with exchange values, the gold coin disappeared, and did
not in fact freely circulate in this country for 30 years prior to
1834. During that time, business transactions were based on silver.
In 1834, desiring to restore parity and bring gold back into
circulation, Congress reduced somewhat (6%) the weight of the gold
coin, and thus equalized the coinage and the exchange values. The
silver dollar was not changed. The purpose was to restore the use
of gold as currency, not to force up prices or destroy obligations.
There was no apparent profit for the books of the Treasury. No
injury was done to creditors; none was intended. The legislation is
without special significance here.
See Hepburn on
Currency.
The moneys under consideration in the
Legal Tender
Cases, decided May 1, 1871,
79 U. S. 12 Wall.
457, and
110 U. S. 110 U.S.
421, were promises to pay dollars, "bills of credit." They were "a
pledge of the national credit," promises "by the government to pay
dollars" "the standard of value is not changed." The expectation,
ultimately realized, was that, in due time, they would be redeemed
in standard coin. The Court was careful to show that they were
issued to meet a great emergency in time of war, when the overthrow
of the government was threatened and specie payments had been
suspended. Both the end in view and the means employed the Court
held were lawful. The thing actually done was the issuance of bills
endowed with the quality of legal tender in order to carry on until
the United States could find it possible to meet their obligations
in standard coin. This they accomplished in 1879. The purpose was
to meet honorable obligations, not to repudiate them.
The opinion there rendered declares:
"The legal tender acts do not attempt to make paper a standard
of value. We do not rest their validity upon the assertion that
their emission is coinage, or any regulation of the value of money;
nor do we assert that Congress may make anything
Page 294 U. S. 372
which has no value money. What we do assert is that Congress has
power to enact that the government's promises to pay money shall
be, for the time being, equivalent in value to the representative
of value determined by the coinage acts, or to multiples
thereof."
What was said in those causes, of course, must be read in the
light of all the circumstances. The opinion gives no support to
what has been attempted here.
This Court has not heretofore ruled that Congress may require
the holder of an obligation to accept payment in subsequently
devalued coins, or promises by the government to pay in such coins.
The legislation before us attempts this very thing. If this is
permissible then a gold dollar containing one grain of gold may
become the standard, all contract rights fall, and huge profits
appear on the Treasury books. Instead of $2,800,000,000 as recently
reported, perhaps $20,000,000,000, maybe enough to cancel the
public debt, maybe more!
The power to issue bills and "regulate values" of coin cannot be
so enlarged as to authorize arbitrary action, whose immediate
purpose and necessary effect is destruction of individual rights.
[
Footnote 2/2] As this Court has
said, a "power to regulate is not a power to destroy."
Reagan
v. Farmers' Loan & Trust Co., 154 U.
S. 362,
154 U. S. 398.
The Fifth Amendment limits all governmental powers. We are dealing
here with a debased standard, adopted with the definite purpose to
destroy obligations. Such arbitrary and oppressive action is not
within any congressional power heretofore recognized.
Page 294 U. S. 373
The authority of Congress to create legal tender obligations in
times of peace is derived from the power to borrow money; this
cannot be extended to embrace the destruction of all credits.
There was no coin -- specie -- in general circulation in the
United States between 1862 and 1879. Both gold and silver were
treated in business as commodities. The Legal Tender cases arose
during that period.
CORPORATE BONDS --
The gold clauses in these bonds were valid, and in entire
harmony with public policy when executed. They are property.
Lynch v. United States, 292 U. S. 571,
292 U. S. 579.
To destroy a validly acquired right is the taking of property.
Osborn v.
Nicholson, 13 Wall. 654,
80 U. S. 662.
They established a measure of value and supply a basis for recovery
if broken. Their policy and purpose were stamped with affirmative
approval by the government when inserted in its bonds.
The clear intent of the parties was that, in case the standard
of 1900 should be withdrawn, and a new and less valuable one set
up, the debtor could be required to pay the value of the contents
of the old standard in terms of the new currency, whether coin or
paper. If gold measured by prevailing currency had declined, the
debtor would have received the benefit. The Agricultural Adjustment
Act of May 12th discloses a fixed purpose to raise the nominal
value of farm products by depleting the standard dollar. It
authorized the President to reduce the gold in the standard, and
further provided that all forms of currency shall be legal tender.
The result expected to follow was increase in nominal values of
commodities and depreciation of contractual obligations. The
purpose of § 43, incorporated by the Senate as an amendment to the
House Bill, was clearly stated by the
Page 294 U. S. 374
Senator who presented it. [
Footnote
2/3] It was the destruction of lawfully acquired rights.
In the circumstances existing just after the Act of May 12th,
depreciation of the standard dollar by the presidential
proclamation would not have decreased the amount required to meet
obligations containing gold clauses. As to them, the depreciation
of the standard would have caused an increase in the number of
dollars of depreciated currency. General reduction of all debts
could only be secured by first destroying the contracts evidenced
by the gold clauses, and this the resolution of June 5th undertook
to accomplish. It was aimed directly at those contracts, and had no
definite relation to the power to issue bills or to coin or
regulate the value of money.
To carry out the plan indicated as above shown in the Senate,
the Gold Reserve Act followed -- January 30, 1934. This inhibited
the President from fixing the weight of the standard gold dollar
above 60% of its then existing weight. (Authority had been given
for 50% reduction by the Act of May 12th.) On January 31st, he
directed that the standard should contain 15 5/21 grains of gold.
If this reduction of 40% of all debts was within the power of
Congress, and if, as a necessary means to accomplish that end,
Congress had power by resolution to destroy the
Page 294 U. S. 375
gold clauses, the holders of these corporate bonds are without
remedy. But we must not forget that, if this power exists, Congress
may readily destroy other obligations which present obstruction to
the desired effect of further depletion. The destruction of all
obligations by reducing the standard gold dollar to one grain of
gold, or brass or nickel or copper or lead, will become an easy
possibility. Thus, we reach the fundamental question which must
control the result of the controversy in respect of corporate
bonds. Apparently, in the opinion of the majority, the gold clause
in the Liberty bond withstood the June 5th Resolution
notwithstanding the definite purpose to destroy them. We think
that, in the circumstances, Congress had no power to destroy the
obligations of the gold clauses in private obligations. The attempt
to do this was plain usurpation, arbitrary, and oppressive.
The oft-repeated rule by which the validity of statutes must be
tested is this:
"Let the end be legitimate, let it be within the scope of the
Constitution, and all means which are appropriate which are plainly
adapted to that end which are not prohibited but consistent with
the letter and spirit of the Constitution are constitutional."
The end or objective of the Joint Resolution was not
"legitimate." The real purpose was not "to assure uniform value to
the coins and currencies of the United States," but to destroy
certain valuable contract rights. The recitals do not harmonize
with circumstances then existing. The Act of 1900 which prescribed
a standard dollar of 25.8 grains remained in force, but its command
that "all forms of money issued or coined by the United States
shall be maintained at a parity of value with this standard" was
not being obeyed. Our currency was passing at a material discount;
all gold had been sequestrated; none was attainable. The resolution
made no provision for restoring parity with the old standard; it
established no new one.
Page 294 U. S. 376
This resolution was not appropriate for carrying into effect any
power entrusted to Congress. The gold clauses in no substantial way
interfered with the power of coining money or regulating its value
or providing an uniform currency. Their existence, as with many
other circumstances, might have circumscribed the effect of the
intended depreciation and disclosed the unwisdom of it. But they
did not prevent the exercise of any granted power. They were not
inconsistent with any policy theretofore declared. To assert the
contrary is not enough. The Court must be able to see the
appropriateness of the thing done before it can be permitted to
destroy lawful agreements. The purpose of a statute is not
determined by mere recitals -- certainly they are not conclusive
evidence of the facts stated.
Again, if effective, the direct, primary, and intended result of
the resolution will be the destruction of valid rights lawfully
acquired. There is no question here of the indirect effect of
lawful exercise of power. And citations of opinions which upheld
such indirect effects are beside the mark. This statute does not
"work harm and loss to individuals indirectly," it destroys
directly. Such interference violates the Fifth Amendment; there is
no provision for compensation. If the destruction is said to be for
the public benefit, proper compensation is essential; if for
private benefit, the due process clause bars the way.
Congress has power to coin money, but this cannot be exercised
without the possession of metal. Can Congress authorize
appropriation without compensation of the necessary gold? Congress
has power to regulate commerce, to establish post roads, etc. Some
approved plan may involve the use or destruction of A's land or a
private way. May Congress authorize the appropriation or
destruction of these things without adequate payment? Of
Page 294 U. S. 377
course not. The limitations prescribed by the Constitution
restrict the exercise of all power.
Ling Su Fan v. United States, 218 U.
S. 302, supports the power of the Legislature to prevent
exportation of coins without compensation. But this is far from
saying that the Legislature might have ordered destruction of the
coins without compensating the owners, or that they could have been
required to deliver them up and accept whatever was offered. In
United States v. Lynah, 188 U. S. 445,
188 U. S. 471,
this Court said:
"If any one proposition can be considered as settled by the
decisions of this Court, it is that, although, in the discharge of
its duties, the government may appropriate property, it cannot do
so without being liable to the obligation cast by the Fifth
Amendment of paying just compensation."
GOVERNMENT BONDS --
Congress may coin money; also it may borrow money. Neither power
may be exercised so as to destroy the other; the two clauses must
be so construed as to give effect to each. Valid contracts to repay
money borrowed cannot be destroyed by exercising power under the
coinage provision. The majority seem to hold that the Resolution of
June 5th did not affect the gold clauses in bonds of the United
States. Nevertheless, we are told that no damage resulted to the
holder now before us through the refusal to pay one of them in gold
coin of the kind designated or its equivalent. This amounts to a
declaration that the government may give with one hand and take
away with the other. Default is thus made both easy and safe.
Congress brought about the conditions in respect of gold which
existed when the obligation matured. Having made payment in this
metal impossible, the government cannot defend by saying that, if
the obligation had been met, the creditor could not have retained
the gold; consequently
Page 294 U. S. 378
he suffered no damage because of the nondelivery. Obligations
cannot be legally avoided by prohibiting the creditor from
receiving the thing promised. The promise was to pay in gold,
standard of 1900, otherwise to discharge the debt by paying the
value of the thing promised in currency. One of these things was
not prohibited. The government may not escape the obligation of
making good the loss incident to repudiation by prohibiting the
holding of gold. Payment by fiat of any kind is beyond its
recognized power. There would be no serious difficulty in
estimating the value of 25.8 grains of gold in the currency now in
circulation.
These bonds are held by men and women in many parts of the
world; they have relied upon our honor. Thousands of our own
citizens of every degree, not doubting the good faith of their
sovereign, have purchased them. It will not be easy for this
multitude to appraise the form of words which establishes that they
have suffered no appreciable damage, but perhaps no more difficult
for them than for us. And their difficulty will not be assuaged
when they reflect that ready calculation of the exact loss suffered
by the Philippine government moved Congress to satisfy it by
appropriating, in June 1934, $23,862,750.78 to be paid out of the
Treasury of the United States. [
Footnote 2/4]
And see Act May 30, 1934, 48
Stat. 817, appropriating
Page 294 U. S. 379
$7,438,000 to meet losses sustained by officers and employees in
foreign countries due to appreciation of foreign currencies in
their relation to the American dollar.
GOLD CERTIFICATES --
These were contracts to return gold left on deposit, otherwise
to pay its value in the currency. Here, the gold was not returned;
there arose the obligation of the government to pay its value. The
Court of Claims has jurisdiction over such contracts. Congress made
it impossible for the holder to receive and retain the gold
promised him; the statute prohibited delivery to him. The contract
being broken, the obligation was to pay in currency the value of
25.8 grains of gold for each dollar called for by the certificate.
For the government to say we have violated our contract, but have
escaped the consequences through our own statute, would be
monstrous. In matters of contractual obligation the government
cannot legislate so as to excuse itself.
These words of Alexander Hamilton ought not to be forgotten:
"When a government enters into a contract with an individual, it
deposes, as to the matter of the contract, its constitutional
authority, and exchanges the character of legislator for that of a
moral agent, with the same rights and obligations as an individual.
Its promises may be
Page 294 U. S. 380
justly considered as excepted out of its power to legislate,
unless in aid of them. It is in theory impossible to reconcile the
idea of a promise which obliges with a power to make a law which
can vary the effect of it."
3 Hamilton's Works 518-519.
These views have not heretofore been questioned here. In the
Sinking Fund Cases, 99 U. S. 700,
99 U. S. 719,
Chief Justice Waite, speaking for the majority, declared:
"The United States are as much bound by their contracts as are
individuals. If they repudiate their obligations, it is as much
repudiation, with all the wrong and reproach that term implies, as
it would be if the repudiator had been a state or a municipality or
a citizen. No change can be made in the title created by the grant
of the lands, or in the contract for the subsidy bonds, without the
consent of the corporation. All this is indisputable."
And in the same cause (
99 U. S. 731-732), Mr. Justice Strong, speaking for
himself, affirmed:
"It is as much beyond the power of a legislature, under any
pretence, to alter a contract into which the government has entered
with a private individual, as it is for any other party to a
contract to change its terms without the consent of the person
contracting with him. As to its contract the government in all its
departments has laid aside its sovereignty, and it stands on the
same footing with private contractors."
Can the government, obliged as though a private person to
observe the terms of its contracts, destroy them by legislative
changes in the currency and by statutes forbidding one to hold the
thing which it has agreed to deliver? If an individual should
undertake to annul or lessen his obligation by secreting or
manipulating his assets with the intent to place them beyond the
reach of creditors, the attempt would be denounced as fraudulent,
wholly ineffective.
Page 294 U. S. 381
Counsel for the government and railway companies asserted with
emphasis that incalculable financial disaster would follow refusal
to uphold, as authorized by the Constitution, impairment and
repudiation of private obligations and public debts. Their forecast
is discredited by manifest exaggeration. But, whatever may be the
situation now confronting us, it is the outcome of attempts to
destroy lawful undertakings by legislative action, and this we
think the Court should disapprove in no uncertain terms.
Under the challenged statutes, it is said the United States have
realized profits amounting to $2,800,000,000. [
Footnote 2/5] But this assumes that gain may be
generated by legislative fiat. To such counterfeit profits there
would be no limit; with each new debasement of the dollar they
would expand. Two billions might be ballooned indefinitely to
twenty, thirty, or what you will.
Loss of reputation for honorable dealing will bring us unending
humiliation; the impending legal and moral chaos is appalling.
[
Footnote 2/1]
In his Annual Report, 1926, 80-81, the Secretary of the Treasury
said:
"Gold and silver certificates are in fact mere 'warehouse
receipts' issued by the Government in exchange for gold coin or
bullion deposited in the one case, or standard silver dollars
deposited in the other case, or against gold or standard silver
dollars, respectively withdrawn from the general fund of the
Treasury. . . . Gold certificates, United States notes, Treasury
notes of 1890, and Federal reserve notes are directly redeemable in
gold."
In his letter with the Annual Report, for 1933, 375, he showed
that, on June 30, 1933, $1,230,717,109 was held in trust against
gold certificates and Treasury notes of 1890. The Treasury notes of
1890 then outstanding did not exceed about $1,350,000. Tr. Rep.
1926, 80.
[
Footnote 2/2]
"It may well be doubted whether the nature of society and of
government does not prescribe some limits to the legislative power,
and, if any be prescribed, where are they to be found, if the
property of an individual, fairly and honestly acquired, may be
seized without compensation."
Chief Justice Marshall in
Fletcher v.
Peck, 6 Cranch. 87,
10 U. S.
135.
[
Footnote 2/3]
He said:
"This amendment has for its purpose the bringing down or
cheapening of the dollar, that being necessary in order to raise
agricultural and commodity prices. . . . The first part of the
amendment has to do with conditions precedent to action being taken
later."
"It will be my task to show that, if the amendment shall prevail
it has potentialities as follows: it may transfer from one class to
another class in these United States value to the extent of almost
$200,000,000,000. This value will be transferred, first, from those
who own the bank deposits. Secondly,this value will be transferred
from those who own bonds and fixed investments."
Cong. Record, April, 1933, pp. 2004, 2216, 2217, 2219.
[
Footnote 2/4]
"AN ACT relating to Philippine currency reserves on deposit in
the United States."
"
Be it enacted by the Senate and House of Representatives of
the United States of America in Congress assembled, That the
Secretary of the Treasury is authorized and directed, when the
funds therefor are made available, to establish on the books of the
Treasury a credit in favor of the Treasury of the Philippine
Islands for $23,862,750.78, being an amount equal to the increase
in value (resulting from the reduction of the weight of the gold
dollar) of the gold equivalent at the opening of business on
January 31, 1934, of the balances maintained at that time in banks
in the continental United States by the Government of the
Philippine Islands for its gold standard fund and its Treasury
certificate fund less the interest received by it on such
balances."
"Sec. 2. There is hereby authorized to be appropriated, out of
the receipts covered into the Treasury under section 7 of the Gold
Reserve Act of 1934, by virtue of the reduction of the weight of
the gold dollar by the proclamation of the President on January 31,
1934, the amount necessary to establish the credit provided for in
section 1 of this Act."
Approved June 19, 1934.
[
Footnote 2/5]
In radio address concerning the plans of the Treasury, August
28, 1934, the Secretary of Treasury, as reported by the Commercial
and Financial Chronicle of September 1, 1934, stated:
"But we have another cash drawer in the Treasury, in addition to
the drawer which carries our working balance. This second drawer I
will call the 'gold' drawer. In it is the very large sum of
$2,800,000,000, representing 'profit' resulting from the change in
the gold content of the dollar. Practically all of this 'profit'
the Treasury holds in the form of gold and silver. The rest is in
other assets."
"I do not propose here to subtract this $2,800,000,000 from the
net increase of $4,400,000,000 in the national debt, thereby
reducing the figure to $1,600,000,000. And the reason why I do not
subtract it is this: for the present, this $2,800,000,000 is under
lock and key. Most of it, by authority of Congress, is segregated
in the so-called stabilization fund, and, for the present, we
propose to keep it there. But I call your attention to the fact
that ultimately we expect this 'profit' to flow back into the
stream of our other revenues, and thereby reduce the national
debt."