NOTICE: This opinion is subject to
formal revision before publication in the preliminary print of the
United States Reports. Readers are requested to notify the
Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States,
Washington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal
errors, in order that corrections may be made before the
preliminary print goes to press.
SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
_________________
Nos. 14–840 and 14–841
_________________
FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION,
PETITIONER
14–840
v.
ELECTRIC POWER SUPPLY ASSOCIATION,
et al.
ENERNOC, INC., et al.,
PETITIONERS
14–841
v.
ELECTRIC POWER SUPPLY ASSOCIATION,
et al.
on writs of certiorari to the united states
court of appeals for the district of columbia circuit
[January 25, 2016]
Justice Kagan delivered the opinion of the
Court.
The Federal Power Act (FPA or Act), 41Stat.
1063, as amended, 16 U. S. C. §791a
et seq., authorizes the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission (FERC or Commission) to regulate “the sale of
electric energy at wholesale in interstate commerce,”
including both wholesale electricity rates and any rule or practice
“affecting” such rates. §§824(b), 824e(a).
But the law places beyond FERC’s power, and leaves to the
States alone, the regulation of “any other
sale”—most notably, any retail sale—of
electricity. §824(b). That statutory division generates a
steady flow of jurisdictional disputes because—in point of
fact if not of law—the wholesale and retail markets in
electricity are inextricably linked.
These cases concern a practice called
“demand response,” in which operators of wholesale
markets pay electricity consumers for commitments
not to use
power at certain times. That practice arose because wholesale
market operators can sometimes—say, on a muggy August
day—offer electricity both more cheaply and more reliably by
paying users to dial down their consumption than by paying power
plants to ramp up their production. In the regulation challenged
here, FERC required those market operators, in specified
circumstances, to compensate the two services
equivalently—that is, to pay the same price to demand
response providers for conserving energy as to generators for
making more of it.
Two issues are presented here. First, and
fundamen-tally, does the FPA permit FERC to regulate these demand
response transactions at all, or does any such rule impinge on the
States’ authority? Second, even if FERC has the requisite
statutory power, did the Commission fail to justify adequately why
demand response providers and electricity producers should receive
the same compensation? The court below ruled against FERC on both
scores. We disagree.
I
A
Federal regulation of electricity owes its
beginnings to one of this Court’s decisions. In the early
20th century, state and local agencies oversaw nearly all
generation, transmission, and distribution of electricity. But this
Court held in
Public Util. Comm’n of R. I. v.
Attleboro Steam & Elec. Co., 273 U. S. 83 –90
(1927), that the Commerce Clause bars the States from regulating
certain interstate electricity transactions, including wholesale
sales (
i.e., sales for resale) across state lines. That
ruling created what became known as the “
Attleboro
gap”—a regulatory void which, the Court pointedly
noted, only Congress could fill. See
id., at 90.
Congress responded to that invitation by passing
the FPA in 1935. The Act charged FERC’s predecessor agency
with undertaking “effective federal regulation of the
expanding business of transmitting and selling electric power in
interstate commerce.”
New York v.
FERC, 535
U. S. 1, 6 (2002) (quoting
Gulf States Util. Co. v.
FPC, 411 U. S. 747, 758 (1973) ). Under the statute,
the Commission has authority to regulate “the transmission of
electric energy in interstate commerce” and “the sale
of electric energy at wholesale in interstate commerce.” 16
U. S. C. §824(b)(1).
In particular, the FPA obligates FERC to oversee
all prices for those interstate transactions and all rules and
practices affecting such prices. The statute provides that
“[a]ll rates and charges made, demanded, or received by any
public utility for or in connection with” interstate
transmissions or wholesale sales—as well as “all
rulesand regulations affecting or pertaining to such rates or
charges”—must be “just and reasonable.”
§824d(a). And if “any rate [or] charge,” or
“any rule, regulation, practice, or contract affecting such
rate [or] charge[,]” falls short of that standard, the
Commission must rectify the problem: It then shall determine what
is “just and reasonable” and impose “the same by
order.” §824e(a).
Alongside those grants of power, however, the
Act also limits FERC’s regulatory reach, and thereby
maintains a zone of exclusive state jurisdiction. As pertinent
here, §824(b)(1)—the same provision that gives FERC
author-ity over wholesale sales—states that “this
subchapter,” including its delegation to FERC, “shall
not apply toany other sale of electric energy.” Accordingly,
the Commission may not regulate either within-state wholesale sales
or, more pertinent here, retail sales of electricity (
i.e.,
sales directly to users). See
New York, 535 U. S.,
at17, 23. State utility commissions continue to oversee those
transactions.
Since the FPA’s passage, electricity has
increasingly become a competitive interstate business, and
FERC’s role has evolved accordingly. Decades ago, state or
local utilities controlled their own power plants, transmission
lines, and delivery systems, operating as vertically integrated
monopolies in confined geographic areas. That is no longer so.
Independent power plants now abound, and almostall electricity
flows not through “the local power networks of the
past,” but instead through an interconnected
“grid” of near-nationwide scope. See
id., at 7
(“electricity that enters the grid immediately becomes a part
of a vast pool of energy that is constantly moving in interstate
commerce,” linking producers and users across the
country)
. In this new world, FERC often forgoes the
cost-based rate-setting traditionally used to prevent monopolistic
pricing. The Commission instead undertakes to ensure “just
and reasonable” wholesale rates by enhancing
competition—attempting, as we recently explained, “to
break down regulatory and economic barriers that hinder a free
market in wholesale electricity.”
Morgan Stanley Capital
Group Inc. v.
Public Util. Dist. No. 1 of Snohomish
Cty., 554 U. S. 527, 536 (2008) .
As part of that effort, FERC encouraged the
creation of nonprofit entities to manage wholesale markets on a
regional basis. Seven such wholesale market operators now serve
areas with roughly two-thirds of the country’s electricity
“load” (an industry term for the amount of electricity
used). See FERC, Energy Primer: A Handbook of Energy Market Basics
58–59 (Nov. 2015) (EnergyPrimer). Each administers a portion
of the grid, providing generators with access to transmission lines
and ensuring that the network conducts electricity reliably. See
ibid. And still more important for present purposes, each
operator conducts a competitive auction to set wholesale prices for
electricity.
These wholesale auctions serve to balance supply
and demand on a continuous basis, producing prices for electricity
that reflect its value at given locations and times throughout each
day. Such a real-time mechanism is needed because, unlike most
products, electricity cannot be stored effectively. Suppliers must
generate—every day, hour, and minute—the exact amount
of power necessary to meet demand from the utilities and other
“load-serving entities” (LSEs) that buy power at
wholesale for resale to users. To ensure that happens, wholesale
market operators obtain (1) orders from LSEs indicating how much
electricity they need at various times and (2) bids from generators
specifying how much electricity they can produce at those times and
how much they will charge for it. Operators accept the
generators’ bids in order of cost (least expensive first)
until they satisfy the LSEs’ total demand. The price of the
last unit of electricity purchased is then paid to every supplier
whose bid was accepted, regardless of its actual offer; and the
total cost is split among the LSEs in proportion to how much energy
they have ordered. So, for example, suppose that at 9 a.m. on
August 15 four plants serving Washington, D. C. can each
produce some amount of electricity for, respectively, $10/unit,
$20/unit, $30/unit, and $40/unit. And suppose that LSEs’
demand at that time and place is met after the operator accepts the
three cheapest bids. The first three generators would then all
receive $30/unit. That amount is (think back to Econ 101) the
marginal cost—
i.e., the added cost of meeting another
unit of demand—which is the price an efficient market would
produce. See 1 A. Kahn, The Economics of Regulation: Principles and
Institutions 65–67 (1988). FERC calls that cost (in jargon
that will soon become oddly familiar) the locational marginal
price, or LMP.[
1]
As in any market, when wholesale buyers’
demand for electricity increases, the price they must pay rises
correspondingly; and in those times of peak load, the grid’s
reliability may also falter. Suppose that by 2 p.m. on August 15,
it is 98 degrees in D. C. In every home, store, or office, people
are turning the air conditioning up. To keep providing power to
their customers, utilities and other LSEs must ask their market
operator for more electricity. To meet that spike in demand, the
operator will have to accept more expensive bids from suppliers.
The operator, that is, will have to agree to the $40 bid that it
spurned before—and maybe, beyond that, to bids of $50 or $60
or $70. In such periods, operators often must call on extremely
inefficient generators whose high costs of production cause them to
sit idle most of the time. See Energy Primer 41–42. As that
happens, LMP—the price paid by
all LSEs to
all
suppliers—climbs ever higher. And meanwhile, the increased
flow of electricity through the grid threatens to overload
transmission lines. See
id., at 44. As every consumer knows,
it is just when the weather is hottest and the need for air
conditioning most acute that blackouts, brownouts, and other
service problems tend to occur.
Making matters worse, the wholesale electricity
market lacks the self-correcting mechanism of other markets.
Usually, when the price of a product rises, buyers natu-rally
adjust by reducing how much they purchase. But con-sumers of
electricity—and therefore the utilities and other LSEs buying
power for them at wholesale—do not respond to price signals
in that way. To use the economic term, demand for electricity is
inelastic. That is in part because electricity is a necessity with
few ready substitutes: When the temperature reaches 98 degrees,
many people see no option but to switch on the AC. And still more:
Many State regulators insulate consumers from short-term
fluctuations in wholesale prices by insisting that LSEs set stable
retail rates. See
id., at 41, 43–44. That, one might
say, short-circuits the normal rules of economic behavior. Even in
peak periods, as costs surge in the wholesale market, consumers
feel no pinch, and so keep running the AC as before. That means, in
turn, that LSEs must keep buying power to send to those
users—no matter that wholesale prices spiral out of control
and increased usage risks overtaxing the grid.
But what if there were an alternative to that
scenario? Consider what would happen if wholesale market operators
could induce consumers to refrain from using (and so LSEs from
buying) electricity during peak periods. Whenever doing that costs
less than adding more power, an operator could bring electricity
supply and demand into balance at a lower price. And
simultaneously, the operator could ease pressure on the grid, thus
protecting against system failures. That is the idea behind the
practice at issue here: Wholesale demand response, as it is called,
pays consumers for commitments to curtail their use of power, so as
to curb wholesale rates and prevent grid breakdowns. See
id., at 44–46.[
2]
These demand response programs work through the
operators’ regular auctions. Aggregators of multiple users of
electricity, as well as large-scale individual users like factories
or big-box stores, submit bids to decrease electricity consumption
by a set amount at a set time for a set price. The wholesale market
operators treat those offers just like bids from generators to
increase supply. The operators, that is, rank order all the
bids—both to produce and to refrain from consuming
electricity—from least to most expensive, and then accept the
lowest bids until supply and demand come into equipoise. And, once
again, the LSEs pick up the cost of all those payments. So, to
return to our prior example, if a store submitted an offer
not to use a unit of electricity at 2 p.m. on August 15 for
$35, the operator would accept that bid before calling on the
generator that offered to produce a unit of power for $40. That
would result in a lower LMP—again, wholesale market
price—than if the market operator could not avail itself of
demand response pledges. See ISO/RTO Council, Harnessing the Power
of Demand: How ISOs and RTOs Are Integrating Demand Response Into
Wholesale Electricity Markets 40–43 (2007) (estimating that,
in one market, a demand response program reducing electricity usage
by 3% in peak hours would lead to price declines of 6% to 12%). And
it would decrease the risk of blackouts and other service
problems.
Wholesale market operators began using demand
response some 15 years ago, soon after they assumed the role of
overseeing wholesale electricity sales. Recognizing the value of
demand response for both system reliability and efficient pricing,
they urged FERC to allow them to implement such programs. See,
e.g., PJM Interconnection, L. L. C., Order
Accepting Tariff Sheets as Modified, 95 FERC ¶61,306 (2001);
California Independent System Operator Corp., Order
Conditionally Accepting for Filing Tariff Revisions, 91 FERC
¶61,256 (2000). And as demand response went into effect,
market participants of many kinds came to view it—in the
words of respondent Electric Power Supply Association
(EPSA)—as an “important element[ ] of robust,
competitive wholesale electricity markets.” App. 94, EPSA,
Comments on Proposed Rule on Demand Response Compensation in
Organized Wholesale Energy Markets (May 12, 2010).
Congress added to the chorus of voices praising
wholesale demand response. In the Energy Policy Act of 2005,
119Stat. 594 (EPAct), it declared as “the policy of the
United States” that such demand response “shall be
encouraged.” §1252(f), 119Stat. 966, 16
U. S. C. §2642 note. In particular, Congress
directed, the deployment of “technology and devices that
enable electricity customers to participate in . . .
demand response systems shall be facilitated, and unnecessary
barriers to demand response participation in energy . . .
markets shall be eliminated.”
Ibid.[
3]
B
Spurred on by Congress, the Commission
determined to take a more active role in promoting wholesale demand
response programs. In 2008, FERC issued Order No. 719, which (among
other things) requires wholesale market operators to receive demand
response bids from aggregators of electricity consumers, except
when the state regulatory authority overseeing those users’
retail purchases bars such demand response participation. See 73
Fed. Reg. 64119, ¶154 (codified 18 CFR §35.28(g)(1)
(2015)). That original order allowed operators to compensate demand
response providers differently from generators if they so chose. No
party sought judicial review.
Concerned that Order No. 719 had not gone far
enough, FERC issued the rule under review here in 2011, with one
commissioner dissenting. See
Demand Response Competition in
Organized Wholesale Energy Markets, Order No. 745, 76 Fed. Reg.
16658 (Rule) (codified 18 CFR §35.28(g)(1)(v)). The Rule
attempts to ensure “just and reasonable” wholesale
rates by requiring market operators to appropriately compensate
demand response providers and thus bring about “meaningful
demand-side participation” in the wholesale markets. 76 Fed.
Reg. 16658, ¶1, 16660, ¶10; 16 U. S. C.
§824d(a). The Rule’s most significant provision directs
operators, under two specified conditions, to pay LMP for any
accepted demand response bid, just as they do for successful supply
bids. See 76 Fed. Reg. 16666–16669, ¶¶45–67.
In other words, the Rule requires that demand response providers in
those circumstances receive as much for conserving electricity as
generators do for producing it.
The two specified conditions ensure that a bid
to use less electricity provides the same value to the wholesale
market as a bid to make more. First, a demand response bidder must
have “the capability to provide the service” offered;
it must, that is, actually be able to reduce electricity use and
thereby obviate the operator’s need to secure additional
power.
Id., at 16666, ¶¶48–49. Second,
paying LMP for a demand response bid “must be
cost-effective,” as measured by a standard called “the
net benefits test.”
Ibid., ¶48. That test makes
certain that accepting a lower-priced demand response bid over a
higher-priced supply bid will actually save LSEs (
i.e.,
wholesale purchasers) money. In some situations it will not, even
though accepting a lower-priced bid (by definition) reduces LMP.
That is because (to oversimplify a bit) LSEs share the cost of
paying successful bidders, and reduced electricity use makes some
LSEs drop out of the market, placing a proportionally greater
burden on those that are left. Each remaining LSE may thus wind up
paying more even though the total bill is lower; or said otherwise,
the costs associated with an LSE’s increased share of
compensating bids may exceed the savings that the LSE obtains from
a lower wholesale price.[
4] The
net benefits test screens out such counterproductive demand
response bids, exempting them from the Rule’s compensation
requirement. See
id., at 16659, 16666–16667,
¶¶3, 50–53. What remains are only those offers
whose acceptance will result in actual savings to wholesale
purchasers (along with more reliable service to end users). See
id., at 16671, ¶¶78–80.
The Rule rejected an alternative scheme for
compensating demand response bids. Several commenters had urged
that, in paying a demand response provider, an operator should
subtract from the ordinary wholesale price the savings that the
provider nets by not buying electricity on the retail market.
Otherwise, the commenters claimed, demand response providers would
receive a kind of“double-payment” relative to
generators. See
id., at 16663, ¶24. That proposal,
which the dissenting commissioner largely accepted, became known as
LMP minus G, or more simply LMP-G, where “G” stands for
the retail price of electricity. See
id., at 16668,
¶60, 16680 (Moeller, dissenting). But FERC explained that,
under the conditions it had specified, the value of an accepted
demand response bid to the wholesale market is identical to that of
an accepted supply bid because each succeeds in cost-effectively
“balanc[ing] supply and demand.”
Id., at 16667,
¶55. And, the Commission reasoned, that comparable value is
what ought to matter given FERC’s goal of strengthening
competition in the wholesale market: Rates should reflect not the
costs that each market participant incurs, but instead the services
it provides. See
id., at 16668, ¶62. Moreover, the Rule
stated, compensating demand response bids at their actual
value—
i.e., LMP—will help overcome various
technological barriers, including a lack of needed infrastructure,
that impede aggregators and large-scale users of electricity from
fully participating in demand response programs. See
id., at
16667–16668, ¶¶57–58.
The Rule also responded to comments challenging
FERC’s statutory authority to regulate the compensation
operators pay for demand response bids. Pointing to the
Commission’s analysis in Order No. 719, the Rule explained
that the FPA gives FERC jurisdiction over such bids because they
“directly affect[ ] wholesale rates.”
Id.,
at 16676, ¶112 (citing 74
id., at 37783, ¶47, and
18 U. S. C. §824d). Nonetheless, the Rule noted,
FERC would continue Order No. 719’s policy of allowing any
state regulatory body to prohibit consumers in its retail market
from taking part in wholesale demand response programs. See 76 Fed.
Reg. 16676, ¶114; 73
id., at 64119, ¶154.
Accordingly, the Rule does not require any “action[ ]
that would violate State laws or regulations.” 76
id.,
at 16676, ¶114.
C
A divided panel of the Court of Appeals for
the District of Columbia Circuit vacated the Rule as
“
ultra vires agency action.” 753 F. 3d 216,
225 (2014). The court held that FERC lacked authority to issue the
Rule even though “demand response compensation affects the
wholesale market.”
Id., at 221. The Commission’s
“jurisdiction to regulate practices ‘affecting’
rates,” the court stated, “does not erase the specific
limit[ ]” that the FPA imposes on FERC’s
regulation of retail sales.
Id., at 222. And the Rule, the
court concluded, exceeds that limit: In “luring
. . .
retail customers” into the wholesale
market, and causing them to decrease “levels of
retail
electricity consumption,” the Rule engages in “direct
regulation of the retail market.”
Id., at
223–224.
The Court of Appeals held, alternatively, that
the Rule is arbitrary and capricious under the Administrative
Procedure Act, 5 U. S. C. §706(2)(A), because FERC
failed to “adequately explain[ ]” why paying LMP
to demand response providers “results in just
compensation.” 753 F. 3d
, at 225. According to
the court, FERC did not “properly consider” the view
that such a payment would give those providers a windfall by
leaving them with “the full LMP
plus . . .
the savings associated with” reduced consumption.
Ibid. (quoting
Demand Response Competition in Organized
Wholesale Energy Markets: Order on Rehearing and Clarification,
Order No. 745–A (Rehearing Order), 137 FERC ¶61,215, p.
62,316 (2011) (Moeller, dissenting)). The court dismissed out of
hand the idea that “comparable contributions [could] be the
reason for equal compensation.” 753 F. 3d, at
225
.
Judge Edwards dissented. He explained that the
rules governing wholesale demand response have a “direct
effect . . . on wholesale electricity rates squarely
within FERC’s jurisdiction.”
Id., at 227. And in
setting those rules, he argued, FERC did not engage in
“direct regulation of the retail market”; rather,
“[a]uthority over retail rates . . . remains vested
solely in the States.”
Id., at 234 (internal quotation
marks omitted). Finally, Judge Edwards rejected the
majority’s view that the Rule is arbitrary and capricious. He
noted the substantial deference due to the Commission in cases
involving ratemaking, and concluded that FERC provided a
“thorough” and “reasonable” explanation for
choosing LMP as the appropriate compensation formula.
Id.,
at 236–238.
We granted certiorari, 575 U. S. ___
(2015), to decide whether the Commission has statutory authority to
regulate wholesale market operators’ compensation of demand
response bids and, if so, whether the Rule challenged here is
arbitrary and capricious. We now hold that the Commission has such
power and that the Rule is adequately reasoned. We accordingly
reverse.
II
Our analysis of FERC’s regulatory
authority proceeds in three parts. First, the practices at issue in
the Rule—market operators’ payments for demand response
commitments—directly affect wholesale rates. Second, in
addressing those practices, the Commission has not regulated retail
sales. Taken together, those conclusions establish that the Rule
complies with the FPA’s plain terms. And third, the contrary
view would conflict with the Act’s core purposes by
preventing all use of a tool that no one (not even EPSA) disputes
will curb prices and enhance reliability in the wholesale
electricity market.[
5]
A
The FPA delegates responsibility to FERC to
regulate the interstate wholesale market for electricity—both
wholesale rates and the panoply of rules and practices affecting
them. As noted earlier, the Act establishesa scheme for federal
regulation of “the sale of electric energy at wholesale in
interstate commerce.” 16 U. S. C. §824(b)(1);
see
supra, at 3. Under the statute, “[a]ll rates and
charges made, demanded, or received by any public utility for or in
connection with” interstate wholesale sales “shall be
just and reasonable”; so too shall “all rules and
regulations affecting or pertaining to such rates orcharges.”
§824d(a). And if FERC sees a violation of that standard, it
must take remedial action. More specifically, whenever the
Commission “shall find that any rate [or]
charge”—or “any rule, regulation, practice, or
contract affecting such rate [or] charge”—is
“unjust [or] unreasonable,” then the Commission
“shall determine the just and reasonable rate, charge[,]
rule, regulation, practice or contract” and impose “the
same by order.” §824e(a). That means FERC has the
authority—and, indeed, the duty—to ensure that rules or
practices “affecting” wholesale rates are just and
reasonable.
Taken for all it is worth, that statutory grant
could extend FERC’s power to some surprising places. As the
court below noted, markets in all electricity’s
inputs—steel, fuel, and labor most prominent among
them—might affect generators’ supply of power. See 753
F. 3d, at 221;
id., at 235 (Edwards, J., dissenting).
And for that matter, markets in just about everything—the
whole economy, as it were—might influence LSEs’ demand.
So if indirect or tangential impacts on wholesale electricity rates
sufficed, FERC could regulate now in one industry, now in another,
changing a vast array of rules and practices to implement its
vision of reasonableness and justice. We cannot imagine that was
what Congress had in mind.
For that reason, an earlier D. C. Circuit
decision adopted, and we now approve, a common-sense construction
ofthe FPA’s language, limiting FERC’s
“affecting” jurisdiction to rules or practices that
“
directly affect the [wholesale] rate.”
California Independent System Operator Corp. v.
FERC,
372 F. 3d 395, 403 (2004) (emphasis added); see 753
F. 3d, at 235 (Edwards, J., dissenting). As we have explained
in addressing similar terms like “relating to” or
“in connection with,” a non-hyperliteral reading is
needed to prevent the statute from assuming near-infinite breadth.
See
New York State Conference of Blue Cross & Blue Shield
Plans v.
Travelers Ins. Co., 514 U. S. 645, 655
(1995) (“If ‘relate to’ were taken to extend to
the furthest stretch of its indeterminacy, then for all practical
purposes [the statute] would never run its course”);
Maracich v.
Spears, 570 U. S. ___, ___ (2013)
(slip op., at 9) (“The phrase ‘in connection
with’ is essentially indeterminat[e] because connections,
like relations, stop nowhere” (internal quotation marks
omitted)). The Commission itself incorporated the D. C.
Circuit’s standard in addressing its authority to issue the
Rule. See 76 Fed. Reg. 16676, ¶112 (stating that FERC has
jurisdiction because wholesale demand response “directly
affects wholesale rates”). We think it right to do the
same.
Still, the rules governing wholesale demand
response programs meet that standard with room to spare. In general
(and as earlier described), wholesale market operators employ
demand response bids in competitive auctions that balance wholesale
supply and demand and thereby set wholesale prices. See
supra, at 7–8. The operators accept such bids if and
only if they bring down the wholesale rate by displacing
higher-priced generation. And when that occurs (most often in peak
periods), the easing of pressure on the grid, and the avoidance of
service problems, further contributes to lower charges. See Brief
for Grid Engineers et al. as
Amici Curiae 26–27.
Wholesale demand response, in short, is all about reducing
wholesale rates; so too, then, the rules and practices that
determine how those programs operate.
And that is particularly true of the formula
that operators use to compensate demand response providers. As in
other areas of life, greater pay leads to greater participation. If
rewarded at LMP, rather than at some lesser amount, more demand
response providers will enter more bids capable of displacing
generation, thus necessarily lowering wholesale electricity prices.
Further, the Commission found, heightened demand response
participation will put “downward pressure” on
generators’ own bids, encouraging power plants to offer their
product at reduced prices lest they come away empty-handed from the
bidding process. 76 Fed. Reg. 16660, ¶10. That, too, ratchets
down the rates wholesale purchasers pay. Compensation for demand
response thus directly affects wholesale prices. Indeed, it is hard
to think of a practice that does so more.
B
The above conclusion does not end our inquiry
into the Commission’s statutory authority; to uphold the
Rule, we also must determine that it does not regulate
retail electricity sales. That is because, as earlier
described, §824(b) “limit[s] FERC’s sale
jurisdiction to that at wholesale,” reserving regulatory
authority over retail sales (as well as intrastate wholesale sales)
to the States.
New York, 535 U. S., at 17 (emphasis
deleted); see 16 U. S. C. §824(b);
supra, at
3.[
6] FERC cannot take an
action transgressing that limit no matter how direct, or dramatic,
its impact on wholesale rates. Suppose, to take a far-fetched
example, that the Commission issued a regulation compelling every
consumer to buy a certain amount of electricity on the retail
market. Such a rule would necessarily determine the load purchased
on the wholesale market too, and thus would alter wholesale prices.
But even given that ineluctable consequence, the regulation would
exceed FERC’s authority, as defined in §824(b), because
it specifies terms of sale at retail—which is a job for the
States alone.[
7]
Yet a FERC regulation does not run afoul of
§824(b)’s proscription just because it
affects—even substantially—the quantity or terms of
retail sales. It is a fact of eco-nomic life that the wholesale and
retail markets in electricity, as in every other known product, are
not hermetically sealed from each other. To the contrary,
transactions that occur on the wholesale market have natural
consequences at the retail level. And so too, of necessity, will
FERC’s regulation of those wholesale matters. Cf.
Oneok,
Inc. v.
Learjet, Inc., 575 U. S. ___, ___ (2015)
(slip op., at 13) (noting that in the similarly structured world of
natural gas regulation, a “Platonic ideal” of strict
separation between federal and state realms cannot exist). When
FERC sets a wholesale rate, when it changes wholesale market rules,
when it allocates electricity as between wholesale
purchasers—in short, when it takes virtually any action
respecting wholesale transactions—it has some effect, in
either the short or the long term, on retail rates. That is of no
legal consequence. See,
e.g., Mississippi Power & Light
Co. v.
Mississippi ex rel. Moore, 487 U. S. 354
–373 (1988) (holding that an order regulating wholesale
purchases fell within FERC’s jurisdiction, and preempted
contrary state action, even though it clearly affected retail
prices);
Nantahala Power & Light Co. v.
Thornburg, 476 U. S. 953 –961, 970 (1986) (same);
FPC v.
Louisiana Power & Light Co., 406
U. S. 621 –641 (1972) (holding similarly in the natural
gas context). When FERC regulates what takes place on the wholesale
market, as part of carrying out its charge to improve how that
market runs, then no matter the effect on retail rates,
§824(b) imposes no bar.
And in setting rules for demand response, that
is all FERC has done. The Commission’s Rule
addresses—and addresses only—transactions occurring on
the wholesale market. Recall once again how demand response
works—and forgive the coming italics. See
supra, at
7–8.
Wholesale market operators administer the entire
program, receiving every demand response bid made. Those operators
accept such a bid at the mandated price when (and only when) the
bid provides value to the
wholesale market by balancing
supply and demand more
“cost-effective[ly]”—
i.e., at a lower cost
to
wholesale purchasers—than a bid to generate power.
76 Fed. Reg. 16659, 16666, ¶2, 48. The compensation paid for a
successful bid (LMP) is whatever the operator’s auction has
determined is the marginal price of
wholesale electricity at
a particular location and time. See
id., at 16659, ¶2.
And those footing the bill are the same
wholesale purchasers
that have benefited from the lower
wholesale price demand
response participation has produced. See
id., at 16674,
¶¶99–100. In sum, whatever the effects at the
retail level, every aspect of the regulatory plan happens
exclusively on the wholesale market and governs exclusively that
market’s rules.
What is more, the Commission’s
justifications for regulating demand response are all about, and
only about, improving the wholesale market. Cf.
Oneok, 575
U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 11) (considering “the
target at which [a] law
aims” in determining
whether a State is properly regulating retail or, instead,
improperly regulating wholesale sales). In Order No. 719, FERC
explained that demand response participation could help create a
“well-functioning competitive wholesale electric energy
market” with “reduce[d] wholesale power prices”
and “enhance[d] reliability.” 73 Fed. Reg. 64103,
¶16. And in the Rule under review, FERC expanded on that
theme. It listed the several ways in which “demand response
in organized wholesale energy markets can help improve the
functioning and competitiveness of those markets”: by
replacing high-priced, inefficient generation; exerting
“downward pressure” on “generator bidding
strategies”; and “support[ing] system
reliability.” 76
id., at 16660, ¶10; see Notice
of Proposed Rulemaking for Order No. 745, 75
id., at
15363–15364, ¶4 (2010) (noting similar aims);
supra, at 7–8. FERC, that is, focused wholly on the
benefits that demand response participation (in the wholesale
market) could bring to the wholesale market. The retail market
figures no more in the Rule’s goals than in the mechanism
through which the Rule operates.
EPSA’s primary argument that FERC has
usurped state power (echoed in the dissent) maintains that the Rule
“effectively,” even though not
“nominal[ly],” regulates retail prices. See,
e.g., Brief for Respondents 1, 10, 23–27, 35–39;
Tr. of Oral Arg. 26, 30;
post, at 4–6. The argument
begins on universally accepted ground: Under §824(b), only the
States, not FERC, can set retail rates. See,
e.g.,
FPC v.
Conway Corp., 426 U. S. 271, 276 (1976) .
But as EPSA concedes, that tenet alone cannot make its case,
because FERC’s Rule does not set actual rates: States
continue to make or approve all retail rates, and in doing so may
insulate them from price fluctuations in the wholesale market. See
Brief for Respondents 39. Still, EPSA contends, rudimentary
economic analysis shows that the Rule does the “functional
equivalen[t]” of setting—more particularly, of
raising—retail rates.
Id., at 36. That is because the
opportunity to make demand response bids in the wholesale market
changes consumers’ calculations. In deciding whether to buy
electricity at retail, economically-minded consumers now consider
both the cost of making such a purchase
and the cost
of forgoing a possible demand response payment. So, EPSA explains,
if a factory can buy electricity for $10/unit, but can earn $5/unit
for
not buying power at peak times, then the effective
retail rate at those times is $15/unit: the $10 the factory paid at
retail plus the $5 it passed up. See
id., at 10. And by thus
increasing effective retail rates, EPSA concludes, FERC trespasses
on the States’ ground.
The modifier “effective” is doing
quite a lot of work in that argument—more work than any
conventional understanding of rate-setting allows. The standard
dictionary definition of the term “rate” (as used with
reference to prices) is “[a]n amount paid or charged for a
good or service.” Black’s Law Dictionary 1452 (10th ed.
2014); see,
e.g., 13 Oxford English Dictionary 208–209
(2d ed. 1989) (“rate” means “price,”
“cost,” or “sum paid or asked for a
. . . thing”). To set a retail electricity rate is
thus to establish the amount of money a consumer will hand over in
exchange for power. Nothing in §824(b) or any other part of
the FPA suggests a more expansive notion, in which FERC sets a rate
for electricity merely by altering consumers’ incentives to
purchase that product.[
8] And
neither does anything in this Court’s caselaw. Our decisions
uniformly speak about rates, for electricity and all else, in only
their most prosaic, garden-variety sense. As the Solicitor General
summarized that view, “the rate is what it is.” Tr. of
Oral Arg. 7. It is the price paid, not the price paid
plus
the cost of a forgone economic opportunity.
Consider a familiar scenario to see what is odd
about EPSA’s theory. Imagine that a flight is overbooked. The
airline offers passengers $300 to move to a later plane that has
extra seats. On EPSA’s view, that offer adds $300—the
cost of not accepting the airline’s proffered
payment—to the price of every continuing passenger’s
ticket. So a person who originally spent $400 for his ticket, and
decides to reject the airline’s proposal, paid an
“effective” price of $700. But would any passenger
getting off the plane say he had paid $700 to fly? That is highly
unlikely. And airline lawyers and regulators (including many, we
are sure, with economics Ph. D.’s) appear to share that
common-sensical view. It is in fact illegal to “increase the
price” of “air transportation . . . after
[such] air transportation has been purchased by the
consumer.” 14 CFR §399.88(a) (2015). But it is a safe
bet that no airline has ever gotten into trouble by offering a
payment not to fly.[
9]
And EPSA’s “effective price
increase” claim fares even worse when it comes to payments
not to use electricity. In EPSA’s universe, a wholesale
demand response program raises retail rates by compelling consumers
to “pay” the price of forgoing demand response
compensation. But such a consumer would be even more surprised than
our air traveler to learn of that price hike, because the natural
consequence of wholesale demand response programs is to bring
down retail rates. Once again, wholesale market operators
accept demand response bids only if those offers lower the
wholesale price. See
supra, at 7–8. And when wholesale
prices go down, retail prices tend to follow, because state
regulators can, and mostly do, insist that wholesale buyers
eventually pass on their savings to consumers. EPSA’s
theoretical construct thus runs headlong into the real world of
electricity sales—where the Rule does anything but increase
retail prices.
EPSA’s second argument that FERC intruded
into the States’ sphere is more historical and purposive in
nature. According to EPSA, FERC deliberately “lured [retail
customers] into the[ ] wholesale markets”—and,
more, FERC did so “only because [it was] dissatisfied with
the States’ exercise of their undoubted authority”
under §824(b) to regulate retail sales. Brief for Respondents
23; see
id., at 2–3, 31, 34. In particular, EPSA
asserts, FERC disapproved of “many States’ continued
preference” for stable pricing—that is, for insulating
retail rates from short-term fluctuations in wholesale costs.
Id., at 28. In promoting demand response programs—or,
in EPSA’s somewhat less neutral language, in “forc[ing]
retail customers to respond to wholesale price
signals”—FERC acted “for the express purpose of
overriding” that state policy.
Id., at 29, 49.
That claim initially founders on the true facts
of how wholesale demand response came about. Contra EPSA, the
Commission did not invent the practice. Rather, and as described
earlier, the impetus came from wholesale market operators. See
supra, at 8. In designing their newly organized markets,
those operators recognized almost at once that demand response
would lower wholesale electricity prices and improve the
grid’s reliability. So they quickly sought, and obtained,
FERC’s approval to institute such programs. Demand response,
then, emerged not as a Commission power grab, but instead as a
market-generated innovation for more optimally balancing wholesale
electricity supply and demand.
And when, years later (after Congress, too,
endorsed the practice), FERC began to play a more proactive role,
it did so for the identical reason: to enhance the wholesale, not
retail, electricity market. Like the market operators, FERC saw
that sky-high demand in peak periods threatened network breakdowns,
compelled purchases from inefficient generators, and consequently
drove up wholesale prices. See,
e.g., 73 Fed. Reg. 64103,
¶16; 76
id., at 16660, ¶10; see
supra, at
6–7. Addressing those problems—which demand response
does—falls within the sweet spot of FERC’s statutory
charge. So FERC took action promoting the practice. No doubt FERC
recognized connections, running in both directions, between the
States’ policies and its own. The Commission understood that
by insulating consumers from price fluctuations, States contributed
to the wholesale market’s difficulties in optimally balancing
supply and demand. See 76 Fed. Reg. 16667–16668,
¶¶57, 59;
supra, at 6–7. And FERC realized
that increased use of demand response in that market would (by
definition) inhibit retail sales otherwise subject to State
control. See 73 Fed. Reg. 64167. But nothing supports EPSA’s
more feverish idea that the Commission’s interest in
wholesale demand response emerged from a yen to usurp State
authority over, or impose its own regulatory agenda on, retail
sales. In promoting demand response, FERC did no more than follow
the dictates of its regulatory mission to improve the
competitiveness, efficiency, and reliability of the wholesale
market.
Indeed, the finishing blow to both of
EPSA’s arguments comes from FERC’s notable solicitude
toward the States. As explained earlier, the Rule allows any State
regulator to prohibit its consumers from making demand response
bids in the wholesale market. See 76
id., at 16676,
¶114; 73
id., at 64119, ¶154;
supra, at 12.
Although claiming the ability to negate such state decisions, the
Commission chose not to do so in recognition of the linkage between
wholesale and retail markets and the States’ role in
overseeing retail sales. See 76 Fed. Reg. 16676,
¶¶112–114. The veto power thus granted to the
States belies EPSA’s view that FERC aimed to
“obliterate[ ]” their regulatory authority or
“override” their pricing policies. Brief for
Respondents 29, 33. And that veto gives States the means to block
whatever “effective” increases in retail rates demand
response programs might be thought to produce. Wholesale demand
response as implemented in the Rule is a program of cooperative
federalism, in which the States retain the last word. That feature
of the Rule removes any conceivable doubt as to its compliance with
§824(b)’s allocation of federal and state authority.
C
One last point, about how EPSA’s
position would subvert the FPA.
EPSA’s jurisdictional claim, as may be
clear by now, stretches very far. Its point is not that this single
Rule, relating to compensation levels, exceeds FERC’s power.
Instead, EPSA’s arguments—that rewarding energy
conservation raises effective retail rates and that
“luring” consumers onto wholesale markets aims to
disrupt state policies—suggest that the entire practice of
wholesale demand response falls outside what FERC can regulate.
EPSA proudly embraces that point: FERC, it declares, “has no
business regulating ‘demand response’ at all.”
Id., at 24. Under EPSA’s theory, FERC’s earlier
Order No. 719, although never challenged, would also be ultra vires
because it requires operators to open their markets to demand
response bids. And more: FERC could not even approve an
operator’s voluntary plan to administer a demand response
program. See Tr. of Oral Arg. 44. That too would improperly allow a
retail customer to participate in a wholesale market.
Yet state commissions could not regulate demand
response bids either. EPSA essentially concedes this point. See
Brief for Respondents 46 (“That may well be true”). And
so it must. The FPA “leaves no room either for direct state
regulation of the prices of interstate wholesales” or for
regulation that “would indirectly achieve the same
result.”
Northern Natural Gas Co. v.
State
Corporation Comm’n of Kan., 372 U. S. 84, 91 (1963)
. A State could not oversee offers, made in a wholesale market
operator’s auction, that help to set wholesale prices. Any
effort of that kind would be preempted.
And all of that creates a problem. If neither
FERC nor the States can regulate wholesale demand response, then by
definition no one can. But under the Act, no electricity
transaction can proceed unless it is regulable by someone. As
earlier described, Congress passed the FPA precisely to eliminate
vacuums of authority over the electricity markets. See
supra, at 2–3. The Act makes federal and state powers
“complementary” and “comprehensive,” so
that “there [will] be no ‘gaps’ for private
interests to subvert the public welfare.”
Louisiana Power
& Light Co., 406 U. S., at 631. Or said otherwise, the
statute prevents the creation of any regulatory “no
man’s land.”
FPC v.
Transcontinental Gas Pipe
Line Corp., 365 U. S. 1, 19 (1961) ; see
id., at
28. Some entity must have jurisdiction to regulate each and every
practice that takes place in the electricity markets, demand
response no less than any other.[
10]
For that reason, the upshot of EPSA’s view
would be to extinguish the wholesale demand response program in its
entirety. Under the FPA, each market operator must submit to FERC
all its proposed rules and procedures. See 16 U. S. C.
§§824d(c)–(d); 18 CFR §§35.28(c)(4),
35.3(a)(1). Assume that, as EPSA argues, FERC could not authorize
any demand response program as part of that package. Nor could FERC
simply allow such plans to go into effect without its consideration
and approval. There are no “off the books” programs in
the wholesale electricity markets—because, once again, there
is no regulatory “no man’s land.”
Transcontinental, 365 U. S., at 19. The FPA mandates
that FERC review, and ensure the reasonableness of, every wholesale
rule and practice. See 16 U. S. C. §§824d(a),
824e(a);
supra, at 3, 14–15. If FERC could not carry
out that duty for demand response, then those programs could not go
forward.
And that outcome would flout the FPA’s
core objects. The statute aims to protect “against excessive
prices” and ensure effective transmission of electric power.
Pennsylvania Water & Power Co. v.
FPC, 343
U. S. 414, 418 (1952) ; see
Gulf States Util. Co. v.
FPC, 411 U. S. 747, 758 (1973) . As shown above, FERC
has amply explained how wholesale demand response helps to achieve
those ends, by bringing down costs and preventing service
interruptions in peak periods. See
supra, at 20. No one
taking part in the rulemaking process—not even
EPSA—seriously challenged that account. Even as he objected
to FERC’s compensation formula, Commissioner Moeller noted
the unanimity of opinion as to demand response’s value:
“[N]owhere did I review any comment or hear any testimony
that questioned the benefit of having demand response resources
participate in the organized wholesale energy markets. On this
point, there is no debate.” 76 Fed. Reg. 16679; see also App.
82, EPSA, Comments on Proposed Rule (avowing “full[ ]
support” for demand response participation in wholesale
markets because of its “economic and operational”
benefits).[
11] Congress
itself agreed, “encourag[ing]” greater use of demand
response participation at the wholesale level. EPAct
§1252(f ), 119Stat. 966. That undisputed judgment
extinguishes any last flicker of life in EPSA’s argument. We
will not read the FPA, against its clear terms, to halt a practice
that so evidently enables the Commission to fulfill its statutory
duties of holding down prices and enhancing reliability in the
wholesale energy market.
III
These cases present a second, narrower
question: Is FERC’s decision to compensate demand response
providers at LMP—the same price paid to
generators—arbitrary and capricious? Recall here the basic
issue. See
supra, at 9–12. Wholesale market operators
pay a single price—LMP—for all successful bids to
supply electricity at a given time and place. The Rule orders
operators to pay the identical price for a successful bid to
conserve electric-ity so long as that bid can satisfy a “net
benefits test”—meaning that it is sure to bring down
costs for wholesale purchasers. In mandating that payment, FERC
rejected an alternative proposal under which demand response
providers would receive LMP minus G (LMP-G), where G is the retail
rate for electricity. According to EPSA and others favoring that
approach, demand response providers get a windfall—a kind of
“double-payment”—unless market operators subtract
the savings associated with conserving electricity from the
ordinary compensation level. 76 Fed. Reg. 16663, ¶24. EPSA now
claims that FERC failed to adequately justify its choice of LMP
rather than LMP-G.
In reviewing that decision, we may not
substitute our own judgment for that of the Commission. The
“scope of review under the ‘arbitrary and
capricious’ standard is narrow.”
Motor Vehicle Mfrs.
Assn. of United States, Inc. v.
State Farm Mut. Automobile
Ins. Co., 463 U. S. 29, 43 (1983) . A court is not to ask
whether a regulatory decision is the best one possible or even
whether it is better than the alternatives. Rather, the court must
uphold a rule if the agency has “examine[d] the relevant
[considerations] and articulate[d] a satisfactory explanation for
its action[,] including a rational connection between the facts
found and the choice made.”
Ibid. (internal quotation
marks omitted). And nowhere is that more true than in a technical
area like electricity rate design: “[W]e afford great
deference to the Commission in its rate decisions.”
Morgan
Stanley, 554 U. S., at 532.
Here, the Commission gave a detailed explanation
of its choice of LMP. See 76 Fed. Reg. 16661–16669,
¶¶18–67. Relying on an eminent regulatory
economist’s views, FERC chiefly reasoned that demand response
bids should get the same compensation as generators’ bids
because both provide the same value to a wholesale market. See
id., at 16662–16664, 16667–16668,
¶¶20, 31, 57, 61; see also App. 829–851, Reply
Affidavit of Dr. Alfred E. Kahn (Aug. 30, 2010) (Kahn Affidavit).
FERC noted that a market operator needs to constantly balance
supply and demand, and that either kind of bid can perform that
service cost-effectively—
i.e., in a way that lowers
costs for wholesale purchasers. See 76 Fed. Reg. 16667–16668,
¶¶56, 61. A compensation system, FERC concluded,
therefore should place the two kinds of bids “on a
competitive par.”
Id., at 16668, ¶61 (quoting
Kahn Affidavit); see also App. 830, Kahn Affidavit (stating that
“economic efficiency requires” compensating the two
equally given their equivalent function in a “competitive
power market[ ]”). With both supply and demand response
available on equal terms, the operator will select whichever bids,
of whichever kind, provide the needed electricity at the lowest
possible cost. See Rehearing Order, 137 FERC, at
62,301–62,302, ¶68 (“By ensuring that both
. . . receive the same compensation for the same service,
we expect the Final Rule to enhance the competitiveness” of
wholesale markets and “result in just and reasonable
rates”).
That rationale received added support from
FERC’s adoption of the net benefits test. The Commission
realized during its rulemaking that in some circumstances a demand
response bid—despite reducing the wholesale rate—does
not provide the same value as generation. See 76 Fed. Reg.
16664–16665, ¶38. As described earlier, that happens
when the distinctive costs associated with compensating a demand
response bid exceed the savings from a lower wholesale rate: The
purchaser then winds up paying more than if the operator had
accepted the best (even though higher priced) supply bid available.
See
supra, at 10–11. And so FERC developed the net
benefits test to filter out such cases. See 76 Fed. Reg.
16666–16667, ¶¶50–53. With that standard in
place, LMP is paid only to demand response bids that benefit
wholesale purchasers—in other words, to those that function
as “cost-effective alternative[s] to the next highest-bid
generation.”
Id., at 16667, ¶54. Thus, under the
Commission’s approach, a demand response provider will
receive the same compensation as a generator only when it is in
fact providing the same service to the wholesale market. See
ibid., ¶53.
The Commission responded at length to
EPSA’s con-trary view that paying LMP, even in that
situation, will overcompensate demand response providers because
they are also “effectively receiv[ing] ‘G,’ the
retail rate that they do not need to pay.”
Id., at
16668, ¶60. FERC explained that compensation ordinarily
reflects only the value of the service an entity provides—not
the costs it incurs, or benefits it obtains, in the process. So
when a generator presents a bid, “the Commission does not
inquire into the costs or benefits of production.”
Ibid., ¶62. Different power plants have different cost
structures. And, indeed, some plants receive tax credits and
similar incentive payments for their activities, while others do
not. See Rehearing Order, 137 FERC, at 62,301, ¶65, and n.
122. But the Commission had long since decided that such matters
are irrelevant: Paying LMP to all generators—although some
then walk away with more profit and some with
less—“encourages more efficient supply and demand
decisions.” 76 Fed. Reg. 16668, ¶62 (internal quotation
marks omitted). And the Commission could see no economic reason to
treat demand response providers any differently. Like generators,
they too experience a range of benefits and costs—both the
benefits of not paying for electricity and the costs of not using
it at a certain time. But, FERC again concluded, that is
immaterial: To increase competition and optimally balance supply
and demand, market operators should compensate demand response
providers, like generators, based on their contribution to the
wholesale system. See
ibid.; 137 FERC, at 62,300,
¶60.
Moreover, FERC found, paying LMP will help
demand response providers overcome certain barriers to
participation in the wholesale market. See 76 Fed. Reg.
16667–16668, ¶¶57–59. Commenters had detailed
significant start-up expenses associated with demand response,
including the cost of installing necessary metering technol-ogy and
energy management systems. See
id., at 16661, ¶18,
16667–16668, ¶57; see also,
e.g., App. 356,
Viridity Energy, Inc., Comments on Proposed Rule on Demand Response
Compensation in Organized Wholesale Energy Markets (May 13, 2010)
(noting the “capital investments and operational changes
needed” for demand response participation). The Commission
agreed that such factors inhibit potential demand responders from
competing with generators in the wholesale markets. See 76 Fed.
Reg. 16668, ¶59. It concluded that rewarding demand response
at LMP (which is, in any event, the price reflecting its value to
the market) will encourage that competition and, in turn, bring
down wholesale prices. See
ibid.
Finally, the Commission noted that determining
the “G” in the formula LMP-G is easier proposed than
accomplished. See
ibid., ¶63. Retail rates vary across
and even within States, and change over time as well. Accordingly,
FERC concluded, requiring market operators to incorporate G into
their prices, “even though perhaps feasible,” would
“create practical difficulties.”
Ibid. Better,
then, not to impose that administrative burden.
All of that together is enough. The Commission,
not this or any other court, regulates electricity rates. The
dis-puted question here involves both technical understanding and
policy judgment. The Commission addressed that issue seriously and
carefully, providing reasons in support of its position and
responding to the principal alternative advanced. In upholding that
action, we do not discount the cogency of EPSA’s arguments in
favor of LMP-G. Nor do we say that in opting for LMP instead, FERC
made the better call. It is not our job to render that judgment, on
which reasonable minds can differ. Our important but limited role
is to ensure that the Commission engaged in reasoned
decisionmaking—that it weighed competing views, selected a
compensation formula with adequate support in the record, and
intelligibly explained thereasons for making that choice. FERC
satisfied that standard.
IV
FERC’s statutory authority extends to
the Rule at issue here addressing wholesale demand response. The
Rule governs a practice directly affecting wholesale electricity
rates. And although (inevitably) influencing the retail market too,
the Rule does not intrude on the States’ power to regulate
retail sales. FERC set the terms of transactions occurring in the
organized wholesale markets, so as to ensure the reasonableness of
wholesale prices and the reliability of the interstate
grid—just as the FPA contemplates. And in choosing a
compensation formula, the Commission met its duty of reasoned
judgment. FERC took full account of the alternative policies
proposed, and adequately supported and explained its decision.
Accordingly, we reverse the judgment of the Court of Appeals for
the District of Columbia Circuit and remand the cases for further
proceedings consistent with this opinion.
It is so ordered.
Justice Alito took no part in the consideration
or decision of these cases.