Goldman Sachs Group, Inc. v. Arkansas Teacher Retirement System, 594 U.S. ___ (2021)

Docket No. 20-222
Granted: December 11, 2020
Argued: March 29, 2021
Decided: June 21, 2021
Justia Summary

Plaintiffs filed a securities-fraud class action alleging that Goldman violated securities laws prohibiting material misrepresentations and omissions in connection with the sale of securities, 15 U.S.C. 78j(b); 17 CFR 240.10b–5, and maintained an artificially inflated stock price by repeatedly making false and misleading generic statements about its ability to manage conflicts. Seeking to certify a class of Goldman shareholders, Plaintiffs invoked the “basic presumption” that investors rely on the market price of a company’s security, which in an efficient market will reflect all of the company’s public statements, including misrepresentations. The Second Circuit affirmed certification of the class.


Annotation
Primary Holding

In considering securities fraud class certification, the defendant bears the burden of proving a lack of price impact caused by its allegedly fraudulent statements impact by a preponderance of the evidence; the court must consider the generic nature of those statements.


Syllabus

NOTE: Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued. The syllabus constitutes no part of the opinion of the Court but has been prepared by the Reporter of Decisions for the convenience of the reader. See United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co., 200 U.S. 321, 337.

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

Syllabus

GOLDMAN SACHS GROUP, INC., et al. v. ARKANSAS TEACHER RETIREMENT SYSTEM, et al.

certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the second circuit

No. 20–222. Argued March 29, 2021—Decided June 21, 2021


Opinions
NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested to notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States, Washington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in order that corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to press.

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

_________________

No. 20–222

_________________

GOLDMAN SACHS GROUP, INC., et al., PETITIONERS v. ARKANSAS TEACHER RETIREMENT SYSTEM, et al.

on writ of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the second circuit

[June 21, 2021]

Justice Barrett delivered the opinion of the Court.

This case involves a securities-fraud class action filed by several pension funds against The Goldman Sachs Group, Inc., and three of its former executives (collectively, Goldman). Plaintiffs allege that Goldman maintained an artificially inflated stock price by making generic statements about its ability to manage conflicts—for example, “We have extensive procedures and controls that are designed to identify and address conflicts of interest.” Plaintiffs say that Goldman’s generic statements were false or misleading in light of several undisclosed conflicts of interest, and that once the truth about Goldman’s conflicts came out, Goldman’s stock price dropped and shareholders suffered losses.

Below, this securities-fraud class action proceeded in typical fashion. Plaintiffs sought to certify a class of Goldman shareholders by invoking the presumption endorsed by this Court in Basic Inc. v. Levinson, 485 U.S. 224 (1988). The Basic presumption is premised on the theory that investors rely on the market price of a company’s security, which in an efficient market incorporates all of the company’s public misrepresentations. For its part, Goldman sought to defeat class certification by rebutting the Basic presumption through evidence that its alleged misrepresentations actually had no impact on its stock price. After determining that Goldman had failed to carry its burden of proving a lack of price impact, the District Court certified the class, and the Second Circuit affirmed.

In this Court, Goldman argues that the Second Circuit erred twice: first, by holding that the generic nature of its alleged misrepresentations is irrelevant to the price impact inquiry; and second, by assigning Goldman the burden of persuasion to prove a lack of price impact.

On the first question, the parties now agree, as do we, that the generic nature of a misrepresentation often is important evidence of price impact that courts should consider at class certification. Because we conclude that the Second Circuit may not have properly considered the generic nature of Goldman’s alleged misrepresentations, we vacate and remand for the Court of Appeals to reassess the District Court’s price impact determination. On the second question, we agree with the Second Circuit that our precedents require defendants to bear the burden of persuasion to prove a lack of price impact by a preponderance of the evidence. We emphasize, though, that the burden of persuasion should rarely be outcome determinative.

I

A

Section 10(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 and its implementing regulation, Rule 10b–5, prohibit material misrepresentations and omissions in connection with the sale of securities. 48Stat. 881, as amended, 15 U. S. C. §78j(b); 17 CFR §240.10b–5 (2020). We have inferred from these provisions an implied private cause of action permitting the recovery of damages for securities fraud. Halliburton Co. v. Erica P. John Fund, Inc., 573 U.S. 258, 267 (2014) (Halliburton II ). To recover damages, a private plaintiff must prove, among other things, a material misrepresentation or omission by the defendant and the plaintiff ’s reliance on that misrepresentation or omission. Ibid.

This case concerns the element of reliance. The “traditional (and most direct) way” for a plaintiff to prove reliance is to show that he was aware of a defendant’s misrepresentation and engaged in a transaction based on that misrepresentation. Ibid. (internal quotation marks omitted). In Basic, however, we held that a plaintiff may also invoke a rebuttable presumption of reliance based on the fraud-on-the-market theory. 485 U. S., at 241–247.

The “fundamental premise” of the fraud-on-the-market theory underlying Basic’s presumption is “that an investor presumptively relies on a misrepresentation so long as it was reflected in the market price at the time of his transaction.” Erica P. John Fund, Inc. v. Halliburton Co., 563 U.S. 804, 813 (2011). To invoke the Basic presumption, a plaintiff must prove: (1) that the alleged misrepresentation was publicly known; (2) that it was material; (3) that the stock traded in an efficient market; and (4) that the plaintiff traded the stock between the time the misrepresentation was made and when the truth was revealed. Halliburton II, 573 U. S., at 268. The defendant may then rebut the presumption through “[a]ny showing that severs the link between the alleged misrepresentation and either the price received (or paid) by the plaintiff, or his decision to trade at a fair market price.” Basic, 485 U. S., at 248.

Although the Basic presumption “can be invoked by any Rule 10b–5 plaintiff,” it has “particular significance in securities-fraud class actions.” Amgen Inc. v. Connecticut Retirement Plans and Trust Funds, 568 U.S. 455, 462 (2013). The presumption allows class-action plaintiffs to prove reliance through evidence common to the class. That in turn makes it easier for plaintiffs to establish the predominance requirement of Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 23, which requires that “questions of law or fact common to class members predominate” over individualized issues. Fed. Rule Civ. Proc. 23(b)(3). Indeed, without the Basic presumption, individualized issues of reliance ordinarily would defeat predominance and “preclude certification” of a securities-fraud class action. Amgen, 568 U. S., at 462–463; see Halliburton II, 573 U. S., at 281–282.

As a result, class-action plaintiffs must prove the Basic prerequisites before class certification—with one exception. In Amgen, we held that materiality should be left to the merits stage because it does not bear on Rule 23’s predominance requirement. 568 U. S., at 466–468. The remaining Basic prerequisites—publicity, market efficiency, and market timing—“must be satisfied” by plaintiffs “before class certification.” Halliburton II, 573 U. S., at 276.

Satisfying those prerequisites, however, does not guarantee class certification. We held in Halliburton II that defendants may rebut the Basic presumption at class certification by showing “that an alleged misrepresentation did not actually affect the market price of the stock.” Id., at 284. If a misrepresentation had no price impact, then Basic’s fundamental premise “completely collapses, rendering class certification inappropriate.” Id., at 283.

B

Respondents here—whom we’ll call Plaintiffs—are Goldman shareholders. They brought this securities-fraud class action against Goldman in the Southern District of New York, alleging violations of §10(b) and Rule 10b–5.

The specific theory of securities fraud that Plaintiffs allege is known as inflation maintenance. Under this theory, a misrepresentation causes a stock price “to remain inflated by preventing preexisting inflation from dissipating from the stock price.” FindWhat Investor Group v. FindWhat.com, 658 F.3d 1282, 1315 (CA11 2011).[1]

Plaintiffs allege here that between 2006 and 2010, Goldman maintained an inflated stock price by making repeated misrepresentations about its conflict-of-interest policies and business practices. The alleged misrepresentations are generic statements from Goldman’s SEC filings and annual reports, including the following:

“We have extensive procedures and controls that are designed to identify and address conflicts of interest.” App. 216 (emphasis and boldface deleted).

“Our clients’ interests always come first.” Id., at 162 (same).

“Integrity and honesty are at the heart of our business.” Id., at 163 (same).

According to Plaintiffs, these statements were false or misleading—and caused Goldman’s stock to trade at artificially inflated levels—because Goldman had in fact engaged in several allegedly conflicted transactions without disclosing the conflicts. Plaintiffs further allege that once the market learned the truth about Goldman’s conflicts from a Government enforcement action and subsequent news reports, the inflation in Goldman’s stock price dissipated, causing the price to drop and shareholders to suffer losses.

After Goldman unsuccessfully moved to dismiss the case, Plaintiffs moved to certify the class, invoking the Basic presumption. In response, Goldman sought to rebut the Basic presumption by proving a lack of price impact. Both parties submitted extensive expert testimony on the issue.

The District Court certified the class, but the Second Circuit authorized a Rule 23(f ) appeal and vacated the class-certification order. 879 F.3d 474 (2018). The Second Circuit held that Goldman, as the defendant, bears the burden of persuasion to prove a lack of price impact by a preponderance of the evidence. But it concluded that the District Court erred by holding Goldman to a higher burden of proof and by refusing to consider some of Goldman’s price impact evidence.

On remand, the District Court certified the class again, finding that Goldman’s expert testimony failed to establish by a preponderance of the evidence that its alleged misrepresentations had no price impact. The Second Circuit again authorized a Rule 23(f ) appeal and this time affirmed in a divided decision. 955 F.3d 254 (2020). As relevant here, the Court of Appeals held that the District Court’s price impact determination was not an abuse of discretion. In dissent, Judge Sullivan concluded that “the generic quality of Goldman’s alleged misstatements, coupled with” Goldman’s expert testimony, compelled the conclusion that Goldman proved a lack of price impact. Id., at 278–279.

We granted certiorari. 592 U. S. ___ (2020).

II

Goldman argues that the Second Circuit erred in two respects: first, by concluding that the generic nature of alleged misrepresentations is irrelevant to the price impact question; and second, by placing the burden of persuasion on Goldman to prove a lack of price impact. We address these arguments in turn.

A

1

On the first question—whether the generic nature of a misrepresentation is relevant to price impact—the parties’ dispute has largely evaporated. Plaintiffs now concede that the generic nature of an alleged misrepresentation often will be important evidence of price impact because, as a rule of thumb, “a more-general statement will affect a security’s price less than a more-specific statement on the same question.” Brief for Respondents 15; see Tr. of Oral Arg. 6–7, 59, 79. The parties further agree that courts may consider expert testimony and use their common sense in assessing whether a generic misrepresentation had a price impact. See Tr. of Oral Arg. 12, 64. And they likewise agree that courts may assess the generic nature of a misrepresentation at class certification even though it also may be relevant to materiality, which Amgen reserves for the merits. See id., at 23, 65.

We share the parties’ view. In assessing price impact at class certification, courts “ ‘should be open to all probative evidence on that question—qualitative as well as quantitative—aided by a good dose of common sense.’ ” In re Allstate Corp. Securities Litig., 966 F.3d 595, 613, n. 6 (CA7 2020) (quoting Langevoort, Judgment Day for Fraud-on-the-Market: Reflection on Amgen and the Second Coming of Halliburton, 57 Ariz. L. Rev. 37, 56 (2015); emphasis added). That is so regardless whether the evidence is also relevant to a merits question like materiality. As we have repeatedly explained, a court has an obligation before certifying a class to “determin[e] that Rule 23 is satisfied, even when that requires inquiry into the merits.” Comcast Corp. v. Behrend, 569 U.S. 27, 35 (2013); see Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. v. Dukes, 564 U.S. 338, 351, and n. 6 (2011). And under Halliburton II, a court cannot conclude that Rule 23’s requirements are satisfied without considering all evidence relevant to price impact. See 573 U. S., at 284.[2]

The generic nature of a misrepresentation often will be important evidence of a lack of price impact, particularly in cases proceeding under the inflation-maintenance theory. Under that theory, price impact is the amount of price inflation maintained by an alleged misrepresentation—in other words, the amount that the stock’s price would have fallen “without the false statement.” Glickenhaus & Co. v. Household Int’l, Inc., 787 F.3d 408, 415 (CA7 2020). Plaintiffs typically try to prove the amount of inflation indirectly: They point to a negative disclosure about a company and an associated drop in its stock price; allege that the disclosure corrected an earlier misrepresentation; and then claim that the price drop is equal to the amount of inflation maintained by the earlier misrepresentation. See, e.g., id., at 413–417; In re Vivendi, S. A. Securities Litig., 838 F.3d 223, 233–237, 253–259 (CA2 2016).

But that final inference—that the back-end price drop equals front-end inflation—starts to break down when there is a mismatch between the contents of the misrepresentation and the corrective disclosure. That may occur when the earlier misrepresentation is generic (e.g., “we have faith in our business model”) and the later corrective disclosure is specific (e.g., “our fourth quarter earnings did not meet expectations”). Under those circumstances, it is less likely that the specific disclosure actually corrected the generic misrepresentation, which means that there is less reason to infer front-end price inflation—that is, price impact—from the back-end price drop.

2

The parties do not dispute any of this. They disagree only about whether the Second Circuit properly considered the generic nature of Goldman’s alleged misrepresentations. Because the Second Circuit’s opinions leave us with sufficient doubt on this score, we remand for further consideration.[3] On remand, the Second Circuit must take into account all record evidence relevant to price impact, regardless whether that evidence overlaps with materiality or any other merits issue.

B

Goldman also argues that the Second Circuit erred by requiring Goldman, rather than Plaintiffs, to bear the burden of persuasion on price impact at class certification. Goldman relies exclusively on Federal Rule of Evidence 301, which provides in full:

“In a civil case, unless a federal statute or these rules provide otherwise, the party against whom a presumption is directed has the burden of producing evidence to rebut the presumption. But this rule does not shift the burden of persuasion, which remains on the party who had it originally.”

According to Goldman, Rule 301 applies to the Basic presumption at class certification, and, as a result, a plaintiff ’s satisfaction of the Basic prerequisites shifts only the burden of production to the defendant. Once a defendant discharges that burden by producing any competent evidence of a lack of price impact, Goldman says, the Basic presumption is rebutted and the plaintiff must carry the burden of persuasion to show price impact.

We disagree. We have held that Rule 301 “in no way restricts the authority of a court . . . to change the customary burdens of persuasion” pursuant to a federal statute. NLRB v. Transportation Management Corp., 462 U.S. 393, 404, n. 7 (1983). And we have at times exercised that authority to reassign the burden of persuasion to the defendant upon a prima facie showing by the plaintiff. See, e.g., Teamsters v. United States, 431 U.S. 324, 359, and n. 45 (1977); Franks v. Bowman Transp. Co., 424 U.S. 747, 772–773 (1976).

Goldman does not ask us to revisit these precedents. So the threshold question here is not whether we have the authority to assign defendants the burden of persuasion to prove a lack of price impact, but instead whether we already exercised that authority in establishing the Basic framework pursuant to the securities laws. We conclude that Basic and Halliburton II did just that.

Basic held that defendants may rebut the presumption of reliance if they “show that the misrepresentation in fact did not lead to a distortion of price.” 485 U. S., at 248 (emphasis added). To do so, Basic said, defendants may make “[a]ny showing that severs the link between the alleged misrepresentation and . . . the price received (or paid) by the plaintiff.” Ibid. (emphasis added). Similarly, Halliburton II held that defendants may rebut the Basic presumption at class certification “by showing . . . that the particular misrepresentation at issue did not affect the stock’s market price.” 573 U. S., at 279 (emphasis added).

Goldman and Justice Gorsuch argue that these references to a defendant’s “showing” refer to the defendant’s burden of production. Post, at 6–8 (dissenting opinion) (hereinafter the dissent). On this reading, Basic and Halliburton II require a defendant merely to offer “evidence that, if believed, would support a finding” of a lack of price impact. Post, at 5. But Basic and Halliburton II plainly require more: The defendant must “in fact” “seve[r] the link” between a misrepresentation and the price paid by the plaintiff—and a defendant’s mere production of some evidence relevant to price impact would rarely accomplish that feat.[4]

Accepting Goldman and the dissent’s argument would also effectively negate Halliburton II ’s holding that plaintiffs need not directly prove price impact in order to invoke the Basic presumption. 573 U. S., at 278–279. If, as they urge, the defendant could defeat Basic’s presumption by introducing any competent evidence of a lack of price impact—including, for example, the generic nature of the alleged misrepresentations—then the plaintiff would end up with the burden of directly proving price impact in almost every case. And that would be nearly indistinguishable from the regime that Halliburton II rejected.

Thus, the best reading of our precedents—as the Courts of Appeals to have considered the issue have recognized—is that the defendant bears the burden of persuasion to prove a lack of price impact. See Waggoner v. Barclays PLC, 875 F.3d 79, 99–104 (CA2 2017) (“the phrase ‘[a]ny showing that severs the link’ aligns more logically with imposing a burden of persuasion rather than a burden of production”); In re Allstate, 966 F. 3d, at 610–611 (“Basic said that ‘[a]ny showing that severs the link’ would be sufficient to rebut the presumption, not that mere production of evidence would defeat the presumption” (citation omitted)). We likewise agree with the Courts of Appeals that the defendant must carry that burden by a preponderance of the evidence. See Waggoner, 875 F. 3d, at 99; In re Allstate, 966 F. 3d, at 610.

Although the defendant bears the burden of persuasion, the allocation of the burden is unlikely to make much difference on the ground. In most securities-fraud class actions, as in this one, the plaintiffs and defendants submit competing expert evidence on price impact. The district court’s task is simply to assess all the evidence of price impact—direct and indirect—and determine whether it is more likely than not that the alleged misrepresentations had a price impact. The defendant’s burden of persuasion will have bite only when the court finds the evidence in equipoise—a situation that should rarely arise. Cf. Medina v. California, 505 U.S. 437, 449 (1992) (preponderance of the evidence burden matters “only in a narrow class of cases where the evidence is in equipoise”).

*  *  *

The Second Circuit correctly placed the burden of proving a lack of price impact on Goldman. But because it is unclear whether the Second Circuit properly considered the generic nature of Goldman’s alleged misrepresentations in reviewing the District Court’s price impact determination, we vacate the judgment of the Second Circuit and remand the case for further proceedings consistent with this opinion.

It is so ordered.

Notes
1  Although some Courts of Appeals have approved the inflation-maintenance theory, this Court has expressed no view on its validity or its contours. We need not and do not do so in this case.
2  We recognize that materiality and price impact are overlapping concepts and that the evidence relevant to one will almost always be relevant to the other. But “a district court may not use the overlap to refuse to consider the evidence.” In re Allstate, 966 F. 3d, at 608. Instead, the district court must use the evidence to decide the price impact issue “while resisting the temptation to draw what may be obvious inferences for the closely related issues that must be left for the merits, including materiality.” Id., at 609.
3  Compare 955 F.3d 254, 268 (2020) (“Whether alleged misstatements are too general to demonstrate price impact has nothing to do with the issue of whether common questions predominate over individual ones” (emphasis added)); id., at 270 (“The inflation-maintenance theory does not discriminate between general and specific misstatements”), with 879 F.3d 474, 485–486 (2018) (correctly requiring the District Court to consider Goldman’s price impact evidence notwithstanding overlap with materiality).
4 The dissent points out that, as a general rule, presumptions shift only the burden of production. Post, at 2–4. We don’t disagree, but we read Basic and Halliburton II as a clear departure from that general rule.
SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

_________________

No. 20–222

_________________

GOLDMAN SACHS GROUP, INC., et al., PETITIONERS v. ARKANSAS TEACHER RETIREMENT SYSTEM, et al.

on writ of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the second circuit

[June 21, 2021]

Justice Sotomayor, concurring in part and dissenting in part.

I agree with the Court’s answers to the questions presented, and I accordingly join Parts I, II–A–1, and II–B of the Court’s opinion. Under Basic Inc. v. Levinson, 485 U.S. 224 (1988), securities plaintiffs may demonstrate reliance by invoking the rebuttable presumption that investors rely on any misrepresentations reflected in a security’s market price. Id., at 241–247. The Basic presumption is particularly useful to class-action plaintiffs who, without the presumption, ordinarily could not demonstrate that questions common to the class predominate over individual ones. Ante, at 3–4. Defendants, for their part, may rebut the Basic presumption by demonstrating that the alleged misrepresentations did not in fact affect the security’s price. Ante, at 3. So-called “price impact” may be disproved with a variety of evidence, alone or in combination. As the Court holds today, one potentially relevant piece of evidence may be the “generic nature” of the misrepresentation. Ante, at 6–8.

I do not, however, join the Court’s judgment to vacate and remand because I believe the Second Circuit “properly considered the generic nature of Goldman’s alleged misrepre- sentations.” Ante, at 8. On appeal, Goldman did not contend that the District Court improperly refused to consider the generic nature of the alleged misstatements as evidence of price impact (or lack thereof ). Instead, Goldman argued that “general statements, like those challenged here, are incapable of impacting a company’s stock price as a matter of law” because they are “ ‘too general to cause a reasonable investor to rely upon them.’ ” Brief for Appellants in No. 18–3667 (CA2), pp. 43, 46. Goldman reasoned that “the challenged statements are incapable of maintaining inflation in a stock price for the same reasons that those statements are immaterial as a matter of law (as well as fact).” Id., at 48.

The Second Circuit properly rejected Goldman’s argument. The court explained that although “Goldman is not formally asking for a materiality test,” its proposed rule would “essentially requir[e] courts to ask” at the class- certification stage “whether the alleged misstatements are, in Goldman’s words, ‘immaterial as a matter of law.’ ” 955 F.3d 254, 267 (2020). But “materiality is irrelevant at the Rule 23 stage.” Id., at 268 (citing Amgen Inc. v. Connecticut Retirement Plans and Trust Funds, 568 U.S. 455, 468 (2013)). “If general statements cannot maintain price inflation because no reasonable investor would have relied on them, then the question of inactionable generality is common to the class.” 955 F. 3d, at 268.

In declining to adopt Goldman’s proposed rule that generic misstatements cannot have a price impact (as a matter of law), the Second Circuit nowhere held that the generic nature of an alleged misstatement could not serve as evidence of price impact (as a matter of fact). Nor did the Second Circuit refuse to consider such evidence in affirming the District Court’s finding that Goldman failed to rebut the Basic presumption. The Court nevertheless reads a handful of sentences in the Second Circuit’s opinion to create “doubt” over whether the Court of Appeals refused to consider “all record evidence relevant to price impact.” Ante, at 9; see also ante, at 9, n. 3. But such statements must be viewed in the context of Goldman’s now-abandoned argument that generic misrepresentations have no price impact as a matter of law. Take, for example, the Second Circuit’s statement that “[w]hether alleged misstatements are too general to demonstrate price impact has nothing to do with the issue of whether common questions predominate over individual ones.” 955 F. 3d, at 268. Fairly read in light of Goldman’s appellate briefing, that sentence addresses only Goldman’s argument that general statements are always per se irrelevant. That is why the Second Circuit observed several sentences later that “Goldman’s test is materiality by another name.” Ibid. At the same time, the court was careful to emphasize that defendants “may attempt to disprove [price impact] at class certification” even though the inquiry “resembles materiality.”[1]* Id., at 267.

In short, the Second Circuit did not address whether the generic nature of a misstatement may be used as evidence to disprove price impact for a simple reason: Goldman identified no error in the District Court’s treatment of such evidence. Goldman did not press the argument in the Second Circuit that it now urges here, and the Second Circuit did not reject the proposition that this Court now adopts. Thus, the argument Goldman seeks to press on remand is unpre- served, and nothing in the Second Circuit’s opinion misstates the law. Because affirmance is appropriate under these circumstances, I respectfully dissent from Part II–A–2 of the Court’s opinion and from the judgment of the Court.

Notes
1 *Indeed, in a prior appeal in this case, an earlier Second Circuit panel vacated an order of the District Court in part because it had refused to consider price-impact evidence that overlapped with materiality. See 879 F.3d 474, 486 (2018) (holding that “[a]lthough price impact touches on materiality, which is not an appropriate consideration at the class certification stage,” courts nonetheless must consider evidence regarding “[w]hether a misrepresentation was reflected in the market price at the time of the transaction”). It is hard to imagine that the Second Circuit here was unaware of (or intended to depart from) the prior panel’s holding.
SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

_________________

No. 20–222

_________________

GOLDMAN SACHS GROUP, INC., et al., PETITIONERS v. ARKANSAS TEACHER RETIREMENT SYSTEM, et al.

on writ of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the second circuit

[June 21, 2021]

Justice Gorsuch, with whom Justice Thomas and Justice Alito join, concurring in part and dissenting in part.

I join all but Part II–B of the Court’s opinion. There, the Court holds that the defendant, rather than the plaintiff, “bear[s] the burden of persuasion on price impact.” Ante, at 9. Respectfully, I disagree.

We start from common ground. Basic Inc. v. Levinson, 485 U.S. 224, 245–247 (1988), sought to import fraud on the market theory from economics into securities litigation. In doing so, Basic posited two things—first, in an efficient market a company’s stock price generally reflects any public and material information about the company; second, investors generally rely on a company’s stock price as an indicator of the firm’s true value. Ibid. Given these economic assumptions, the Court held that securities fraud plaintiffs can presumptively meet their burden of proving reliance on an alleged misrepresentation by proving four things: (1) the defendant’s alleged misrepresentation was publicly known; (2) it was material; (3) the stock traded in an efficient market; and (4) the plaintiff purchased the stock at the market price between the time the misrepresentation was made and the truth was revealed. See Halliburton Co. v. Erica P. John Fund, Inc., 573 U.S. 258, 277–278 (2014) (Halliburton II).

The presumption of reliance not only helps a plaintiff prove one of the essential elements of a securities fraud claim. Certain class actions require that “questions of law or fact common to class members predominate over any questions affecting only individual members.” Fed. Rule Civ. Proc. 23(b)(3). So to the extent a court is able to presume reliance by everyone who purchased an affected stock, Basic can help avoid individualized questions that otherwise might stand in the way of proceeding with a securities fraud action on a classwide basis. Erica P. John Fund, Inc. v. Halliburton Co., 563 U.S. 804, 809–811 (2011) (Halliburton I).

At the same time, Basic’s presumption of reliance has only ever been just that. Everyone accepts that, if a defendant undermines one of the assumptions on which it rests, the presumption dissipates. So, for example, if the defendant’s alleged misrepresentation did not actually affect the market price, there can be no ground for presuming anyone relied on that misrepresentation when purchasing the stock. Halliburton II, 573 U. S., at 279. Similarly, if a particular plaintiff did not care about the integrity of the market price when purchasing a stock, there is no basis for presuming that individual’s reliance. Id., at 276.

Before us, the only meaningful dispute concerns what burden a defendant bears when it comes to rebutting the Basic presumption. Does the defendant carry only a burden of production, or does the defendant sometimes carry a burden of persuasion? In my view, only a burden of production is involved.

Start with what we have said about presumptions like Basic’s. This Court has long recognized that a “ ‘ “presumption” properly used refers only to a device for allocating the production burden.’ ” Texas Dept. of Community Affairs v. Burdine, 450 U.S. 248, 255, n. 8 (1981). Throughout the law, courts have sometimes created presumptions to help plaintiffs prove their cases when direct evidence can be hard to come by. See Basic, 485 U. S., at 245. These presumptions operate by allowing the plaintiff to prove only certain specified “predicate fact[s]” at the outset. St. Mary’s Honor Center v. Hicks, 509 U.S. 502, 506 (1993). If the plaintiff does so, an inference or “presumption” arises that the plaintiff has met its burden of persuasion, at least “in the absence” of some competing “explanation.” Ibid. (internal quotation marks omitted). At that point, the defendant bears a burden of production to present evidence that, if “taken as true,” would “permit the conclusion” that the presumption in the plaintiff ’s favor is mistaken. Id., at 509 (emphasis deleted). If the defendant produces such evidence, the presumption “drops from the case.” Id., at 507 (internal quotation marks omitted). “[T]he trier of fact” then “proceeds to decide the ultimate question.” Id., at 511. Throughout this whole back-and-forth process, the burden of persuasion never shifts: The “plaintiff at all times bears the ultimate burden of persuasion” to prove all aspects of its cause of action. Ibid. (internal quotation marks omitted).

The Court has explained that nearly “all presumptions” operate in this way. Id., at 507. The Federal Rules of Evidence confirm the point too. Rule 301, titled “Presumptions in Civil Cases Generally,” provides that “the party against whom a presumption is directed has the burden of producing evidence to rebut the presumption,” but “the burden of persuasion . . . remains on the party who had it originally.” Again, a burden of production may shift to the defendant, but never the burden of persuasion.

Title VII practice offers a familiar illustration of these principles. There, the plaintiff bears the ultimate burden of proving that his employer intentionally discriminated against him because of his race or some other unlawful factor. See St. Mary’s Honor Center, 509 U. S., at 511. But because direct evidence of intentional discrimination can be “elusive,” the Court has created a presumption. See id., at 506 (internal quotation marks omitted). If a plaintiff proves certain “predicate fact[s]”—for example, that he is black, that he was fired from a job for which he was qualified, and that the job remained open and was ultimately filled by a white person—an inference or presumption of intentional discrimination arises. Ibid. At that point, the defendant bears the burden of producing evidence that, if accepted as true, shows it fired the plaintiff for only legitimate business reasons. Id., at 506–507. Should that happen, the presumption of intentional discrimination disappears and the trier of fact must weigh the parties’ competing proof. Id., at 510–511. None of that means the plaintiff ’s indirect evidence of discrimination also disappears. It simply means the trier of fact must consider any inferences arising from that indirect evidence while also considering the defendant’s evidence and any other proof the plaintiff submits. See id., at 511. “[A]t all times” throughout the litigation, however, the plaintiff bears the “ultimate burden of persuading the trier of fact that he has been the victim of intentional discrimination.” Id., at 507–508 (brackets and internal quotation marks omitted).

Since the Court first started tangling with the fraud on the market theory in Basic, it has followed these traditional rules. Consistently, our decisions have “made clear” that Basic’s “presumption” of reliance is “just that.” Halliburton I, 563 U. S., at 811. Much as the Court said it created the Title VII presumption to help prove the “elusive” question of intentional discrimination, Basic said it created its presumption of reliance to relieve “an unnecessarily unrealistic evidentiary burden” on securities fraud plaintiffs. 485 U. S., at 245. And when creating its presumption Basic expressly cited Rule 301. Ibid.

The process Basic outlined matches traditional understandings too. The Court explained that a plaintiff ’s ability to prove certain “threshold facts”—about market operations and the publicity of the misstatement—gives rise to a “presumption” of reliance. See id., at 248, and n. 27. After such a showing, the Court continued, a defendant may then proceed to “rebut the presumption.” Id., at 248. Nowhere in any of this did Basic suggest the order of operations governing its presumption should differ in any way from those governing others commonly found in the law and subject to Rule 301. Nor is there any doubt which party has the burden of persuasion on the question of reliance in securities fraud cases like ours. From start to finish, the plaintiff has the burden to satisfy that essential element of its claim. Basic’s presumption of reliance thus “does not shift” any burden of persuasion—that always “remains” with the plaintiff. Fed. Rule Evid. 301; see also St. Mary’s Honor Center, 509 U. S., at 506–508.

Consider how all this works in routine securities fraud cases. Once a plaintiff proves the four “predicate facts” Basic specified, see supra, at 1, a presumption of reliance attaches. At that point, the defendant bears the burden of producing evidence that, if believed, would support a finding that the plaintiff did not actually rely on its alleged misrepresentation. As we have seen, a defendant might do so by producing evidence suggesting that its alleged misrepresentation did not have an impact on market price or that the plaintiff was indifferent to the alleged misrepresentation. Upon such a showing, the presumption of reliance drops from the case and the trier of fact must decide the question of reliance vel non, cognizant of the fact the plaintiff bears the burden of proving reliance like any other essential elements of its claim. Again, that does not mean the plaintiff ’s indirect proof disappears. A court may still infer from the Basic predicates that a particular misstatement was incorporated into the stock price and that the plaintiff relied on the integrity of that price. Both sides are free to present additional proof too. It’s simply that a court no longer must find reliance. See St. Mary’s Honor Center, 509 U. S., at 511.

The Court disputes none of this. It does not even try to defend on the merits its unusual suggestion that the defendant carries some burden of persuasion in a plaintiff ’s claim for securities fraud. Instead, the Court contends only that precedent ties our hands.

Primarily, the Court points to a single clause in a single sentence in Basic observing that a defendant may rebut the presumption of reliance with “[a]ny showing that severs the link between the alleged misrepresentation” and the stock price. See ante, at 10 (quoting Basic, 485 U. S., at 248) (emphasis deleted). The Court then splices that clause together with another clause in a preceding sentence explaining that, before Basic, lower courts had said a defendant rebuts the fraud on the market presumption by showing “that the misrepresentation in fact did not lead to a distortion of price.” Ante, at 10 (quoting Basic, 485 U. S., at 248; emphasis deleted).

But what does this prove? Surely this language confirms an important and by now familiar point: Once a defendant produces evidence that, if believed, shows that fraud on the market theory does not hold in its particular case because its alleged misrepresentation in fact failed to affect the stock price, the presumption of reliance drops away. On the Court’s reading today, however, this language doesn’t just carry that obvious meaning. We are told it also must mean that Basic intended to shift the “burden of persuasion” with respect to “price impact” to the defendant—at least “at class certification”—because the “mere production of some evidence relevant to price impact would rarely accomplish th[e] feat” of “in fact” “ sever[ing] the link between a misrepresentation and the price paid” for the stock. Ante, at 10–11 (internal quotation marks omitted; emphasis deleted).

That much does not follow. Not only has this Court often said it is a mistake to parse terms in a judicial opinion with the kind of punctilious exactitude due statutory language. See Reiter v. Sonotone Corp., 442 U.S. 330, 341 (1979). Even read for all they are worth, the handful of words on which the Court rests its entire holding today—a “showing” that “in fact” “sever[s] the link”—cannot begin to carry the weight the Court assigns them. See ante, at 10 (emphasis deleted). These terms do not even appear together in Basic: The Court has to pluck the phrase “in fact” from one sentence and the phrase “[a] showing that severs the link” from another, and then combine them to create a new clause that appears nowhere in the U. S. Reports—a “showing” that “in fact sever[s] the link.” Ante, at 10 (internal quotation marks omitted). Even then, the Court’s newly handcrafted phrase does not so much as mention the terms “burden of persuasion” or “price impact.”

The hard truth is that in the 30-plus years since Basic this Court has never (before) suggested that plaintiffs are relieved from carrying the burden of persuasion on any aspect of their own causes of action. To the contrary, when discussing the presumption it created, Basic expressly referenced Rule 301 and invoked its normal order of operations. And this Court has long explained that presumptions “properly used” refer only to devices “for allocating the production burden,” and not the burden of persuasion. Burdine, 450 U. S., at 255, n. 8 (internal quotation marks omitted). Are we really to believe that Basic—while referencing traditional understandings embodied in Rule 301 and just seven years after Burdine—secretly meant to depart from traditional and “proper” understandings about how presumptions work? Thanks to spliced clauses found in two sentences this Court has never before read that way? All while using words that carry another and much more natural meaning? To state the theory is to refute it.

If Basic doesn’t command today’s result, the Court offers a backup theory. Separately, it insists, Halliburton II requires us to shift a burden of persuasion to the defendant. Specifically, the Court points to the fact that Halliburton II reaffirmed Basic’s holding that a plaintiff need not show reliance “directly,” but may do so “presumptively” by carrying the burden of proving the four Basic factual predicates. 573 U. S., at 278. A decision holding that the defendant merely bore the burden of producing evidence suggesting a lack of price impact at class certification, the Court now submits, “would be nearly indistinguishable from the regime that Halliburton II rejected.” Ante, at 11.

That much does not follow either. Like Basic, Halliburton II concerned what facts a plaintiff must produce to generate a presumption of reliance. This case is about what defendants must do to rebut that presumption. Deciding one does not resolve the other. To say these issues are “indistinguishable” is to miss the entire point of a presumption: It allows the plaintiff to state a prima facie case based on inference and requires the defendant to bear the burden of producing evidence in response; once the defendant does so, the presumption has served its purpose and drops from the case. At that point, the factfinder now has the benefit of evidence from both sides and must decide the case with reference to the plaintiff ’s burden of persuasion. Nothing in Halliburton II suggests a departure from these principles, let alone that some burden of persuasion secretly shifts to the defendant in a plaintiff ’s claim for securities fraud. To the contrary, that decision arose in the class certification context and expressly reaffirmed that “[t]he Basic presumption does not relieve plaintiffs of the burden of proving” they have satisfied “the predominance requirement of Rule 23(b)(3).” 573 U. S., at 276.

The Court has no answer to any of this. Instead, it replies only by touting the fact that two Court of Appeals decisions have read Basic and Halliburton II as it does. Ante, at 11. But this is a non sequitur. The Court does not suggest that a pair of lower court opinions represents some robust judicial consensus. Nor does the Court suggest those opinions free us from having to interpret the law for ourselves. After all, “[o]ur duty is to follow the law as we find it, not to follow rotely whatever lower courts might once have said about it.” BP p.l.c. v. Mayor and City Council of Baltimore, 593 U. S. ___, ___–___ (2021) (slip op., at 11–12). The fact remains that nothing in our prior decisions has ever placed a burden of persuasion on the defendant with respect to any aspect of the plaintiff ’s case. It is incumbent on the plaintiff to prove reliance, not the defendant to disprove it. If a majority of the Court today really believes some novel new burden of persuasion should be placed on the defendant, it ought to say so. Past decisions—by this Court or others—cannot be blamed for today’s result.

Perhaps recognizing the incongruity of its conclusion, the Court goes out of its way to downplay its significance. We’re told that “on the ground” today’s holding “is unlikely to make much difference” because “[i]n most securities-fraud class actions . . . the plaintiffs and defendants submit competing expert evidence on price impact.” Ante, at 12. And in cases like these, “[t]he district court’s task,” according to the Court, “is simply to assess all the evidence of price impact” and “determine whether it is more likely than not that the alleged misrepresentations had a price impact.” Ibid.

This is a curious disavowal. Obviously, the Court thinks the issue important enough to spend the time and effort to rejigger the burden of persuasion. Now, though, it says none of this matters because most cases come down to a dispute over evidence of price impact irrespective of the presumption. The Court’s suggestion that the burden of persuasion will “rarely” make a “difference” misses the point too. The whole reason we allocate the burden of persuasion is to resolve close cases by providing a tie breaker where the burden does make a difference. That close cases may not be common ones is no justification for indifference about how the law resolves them.

Respectfully, I dissent.


Materials
Jul 23, 2021 JUDGMENT ISSUED.
Jun 21, 2021 Judgment VACATED and case REMANDED. Barrett, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which Roberts, C. J., and Breyer, Kagan, and Kavanaugh, JJ., joined in full; in which Thomas, Alito, and Gorsuch, JJ., joined as to Parts I and II–A; and in which Sotomayor, J., joined as to Parts I, II–A–1, and II–B. Sotomayor, J., filed an opinion concurring in part and dissenting in part. Gorsuch, J., filed an opinion concurring in part and dissenting in part, in which Thomas and Alito, JJ., joined.
Mar 29, 2021 Argued. For petitioners: Kannon K. Shanmugam, Washington, D. C. For United States, as amicus curiae: Sopan Joshi, Assistant to the Solicitor General, Department of Justice, Washington, D. C. For respondents: Thomas C. Goldstein, Bethesda, Md.
Mar 19, 2021 Reply of petitioners Goldman Sachs Group, Inc., et al. filed. (Distributed)
Mar 8, 2021 Motion of the Acting Solicitor General for leave to participate in oral argument as amicus curiae and for divided argument GRANTED.
Mar 3, 2021 Brief amici curiae of Evidence Law Professors filed. (Distributed)
Mar 3, 2021 Brief amici curiae of Financial Economists filed. (Distributed)
Mar 3, 2021 Brief amici curiae of Former SEC Officials filed. (Distributed)
Mar 3, 2021 Brief amicus curiae of Better Markets, Inc. filed. (Distributed)
Mar 3, 2021 Brief amicus curiae of The North American Securities Administrators Association, Inc. filed. (Distributed)
Mar 3, 2021 Brief amici curiae of Institutional Investors filed. (Distributed)
Mar 3, 2021 Brief amicus curiae of National Association of Shareholder and Consumer Attorneys filed. (Distributed)
Mar 3, 2021 Brief amici curiae of Public Citizen and Public Citizen Foundation filed. (Distributed)
Mar 3, 2021 Brief amici curiae of Professors of Securities Law and Complex Litigation filed. (Distributed)
Mar 3, 2021 Brief amici curiae of State of New Mexico et al. filed. (Distributed)
Feb 26, 2021 Motion of the Acting Solicitor General for leave to participate in oral argument as amicus curiae and for divided argument filed.
Feb 24, 2021 Brief of respondents Arkansas Teacher Retirement System, et al. filed. (Distributed)
Feb 22, 2021 CIRCULATED.
Feb 11, 2021 Record from the U.S.C.A. 2nd Circuit, along with SEALED material been electronically filed.
Feb 11, 2021 Record from the U.S.D.C. Southern District of New York is electronic and located on Pacer, with the exception of 1 Box of Sealed records.
Feb 4, 2021 Record requested from the U.S.C.A. 2nd Circuit.
Feb 1, 2021 Brief amicus curiae of Retail Litigation Center, Inc. filed.
Feb 1, 2021 SET FOR ARGUMENT on Monday, March 29, 2021.
Feb 1, 2021 Brief amicus curiae of United States support of neither party filed.
Feb 1, 2021 Brief amici curiae of Financial Economists filed.
Feb 1, 2021 Brief amici curiae of American International Group, Inc. et al. filed.
Feb 1, 2021 Brief amici curiae of Former SEC Officials and Law Professors filed.
Feb 1, 2021 Brief amicus curiae of The Society for Corporate Governance filed.
Feb 1, 2021 Brief amici curiae of Securities and Financial Markets Association, et al. filed.
Feb 1, 2021 Brief amicus curiae of Washington Legal Foundation filed.
Jan 25, 2021 Joint appendix (2 volumes & 1 supplemental) filed. (Statement of costs filed)
Jan 25, 2021 Brief of petitioners Goldman Sachs Group, Inc., et al. filed.
Jan 14, 2021 Blanket Consent filed by Respondent, Arkansas Teacher Retirement System, et al.
Jan 14, 2021 Blanket Consent filed by Petitioner, Goldman Sachs Group, Inc., et al.
Dec 11, 2020 Petition GRANTED.
Dec 7, 2020 DISTRIBUTED for Conference of 12/11/2020.
Nov 17, 2020 DISTRIBUTED for Conference of 12/4/2020.
Nov 17, 2020 Reply of petitioners Goldman Sachs Group, Inc., et al. filed. (Distributed)
Oct 26, 2020 Motion to delay distribution of the petition for a writ certiorari until November 17, 2020 granted.
Oct 21, 2020 Brief of respondents Arkansas Teacher Retirement System, et al. in opposition filed.
Oct 21, 2020 Motion of petitioner to delay distribution of the petition for a writ of certiorari under Rule 15.5 from November 4, 2020 to November 17, 2020, submitted to The Clerk.
Sep 24, 2020 Brief amici curiae of Former SEC Officials and Law Professors filed.
Sep 24, 2020 Brief amicus curiae of Retail Litigation Center, Inc. filed.
Sep 24, 2020 Brief amicus curiae of Washington Legal Foundation filed.
Sep 24, 2020 Brief amici curiae of Financial Economists filed.
Sep 24, 2020 Brief amicus curiae of The Society for Corporate Governance filed.
Sep 24, 2020 Brief amici curiae of Securities and Financial Markets Association, et al. filed.
Sep 9, 2020 Motion to extend the time to file a response is granted and the time is extended to and including October 23, 2020.
Sep 8, 2020 Motion to extend the time to file a response from September 24, 2020 to October 23, 2020, submitted to The Clerk.
Sep 8, 2020 Blanket Consent filed by Respondent, Arkansas Teacher Retirement System, et al.
Aug 25, 2020 Blanket Consent filed by Petitioner, Goldman Sachs Group, Inc., et al.
Aug 21, 2020 Petition for a writ of certiorari filed. (Response due September 24, 2020)