Southern Rate Conf. v. United States, 471 U.S. 48 (1985)

Argued: November 26, 1984
Decided: March 27, 1985
Syllabus

U.S. Supreme Court

Southern Rate Conf. v. United States, 471 U.S. 48 (1985)

Southern Motor Carriers Rate Conference, Inc. v. United States

No. 82-1922

Argued November 26, 1984

Decided March 27, 1985

471 U.S. 48

Syllabus


Opinions

U.S. Supreme Court

Southern Rate Conf. v. United States, 471 U.S. 48 (1985) Southern Motor Carriers Rate Conference, Inc. v. United States

No. 82-1922

Argued November 26, 1984

Decided March 27, 1985

471 U.S. 48

CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE

ELEVENTH CIRCUIT

Syllabus

Petitioner Southern Motor Carriers Rate Conference and petitioner North Carolina Motor Carriers Association (petitioners), "rate bureaus" composed of motor common carriers operating in North Carolina, Georgia, Tennessee, and Mississippi, submit, on behalf of their members, joint rate proposals to the Public Service Commission in each State. This collective ratemaking is authorized, but not compelled, by the respective States. The United States, contending that petitioners' collective ratemaking violates the federal antitrust laws, filed an action in Federal District Court to enjoin it. Petitioners responded that their conduct was immune from the federal antitrust laws by virtue of the "state action" doctrine of Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341. The District Court entered a summary judgment in the Government's favor. The Court of Appeals affirmed, holding that compulsion is a threshold requirement to a finding of Parker immunity. The court reasoned that the two-pronged test of California Retail Dealers Assn. v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc., 445 U. S. 97, for determining whether state regulation of private parties is shielded from the federal antitrust laws -- the challenged restraint must be one clearly articulated and affirmatively expressed as a state policy, and the State must supervise actively any private anticompetitive conduct -- is inapplicable to suits against private parties; that even if Midcal is applicable, private conduct that is not compelled cannot be taken pursuant to a "clearly articulated state policy" within the meaning of Midcal's first prong; and that, because Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U. S. 773, which held that a State Bar, acting alone, could not immunize from the federal antitrust laws its anticompetitive conduct in fixing minimum fees for lawyers -- was cited with approval in Midcal, the Midcal Court endorsed the continued validity of a "compulsion requirement."

Held: Petitioners' collective ratemaking activities, although not compelled by the respective States, are immune from federal antitrust liability under the state action doctrine. The Midcal test should be used to determine whether the private rate bureaus' collective ratemaking activities are protected under the federal antitrust laws. Moreover, the actions of a private party can be attributed to a "clearly articulated state

Page 471 U. S. 49

policy," within the meaning of the Midcal test's first prong, even in the absence of compulsion. The anticompetitive conduct is taken pursuant to a "clearly articulated state policy" under the first prong of the Midcal test. Here, North Carolina, Georgia, and Tennessee statutes expressly permit collective ratemaking. Mississippi, while not expressly approving of collective ratemaking, has clearly articulated its intent to displace price competition among common carriers with a regulatory structure. Because the Government conceded that there was adequate state supervision, both prongs of the Midcal test are satisfied. Pp. 471 U. S. 55-66.

702 F.2d 532, reversed.

POWELL, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which BURGER, C.J., and BRENNAN, MARSHALL, BLACKMUN, REHNQUIST, and O'CONNOR, JJ., joined. STEVENS, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which WHITE, J., joined, post p. 471 U. S. 66.

Page 471 U. S. 50

JUSTICE POWELL delivered the opinion of the Court.

Southern Motor Carriers Rate Conference, Inc. (SMCRC), and North Carolina Motor Carriers Association, Inc. (NCMCA), petitioners, are "rate bureaus" composed of motor common carriers operating in four Southeastern States. The rate bureaus, on behalf of their members, submit joint rate proposals to the Public Service Commission in each State for approval or rejection. This collective ratemaking is authorized, but not compelled, by the States in which the rate bureaus operate. The United States, contending that collective ratemaking violates the federal antitrust laws, filed this action to enjoin the rate bureaus' alleged anticompetitive practices. We here consider whether the petitioners' collective ratemaking activities, though not compelled by the States, are entitled to Sherman Act immunity under the "state action" doctrine of Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341 (1943).

I A

In North Carolina, Georgia, Mississippi, and Tennessee, Public Service Commissions set motor common carriers' rates for the intrastate transportation of general commodities. [Footnote 1] Common carriers are required to submit proposed rates to the relevant Commission for approval. [Footnote 2] A proposed

Page 471 U. S. 51

rate becomes effective if the state agency takes no action within a specified period of time. If a hearing is scheduled, however, a rate will become effective only after affirmative agency approval. [Footnote 3] The State Public Service Commissions thus have and exercise ultimate authority and control over all intrastate rates.

In all four States, common carriers are allowed to agree on rate proposals prior to their joint submission to the regulatory agency. [Footnote 4] By reducing the number of proposals, collective ratemaking permits the agency to consider more carefully each submission. In fact, some Public Service Commissions have stated that, without collective ratemaking, they would be unable to function effectively as rate-setting bodies. [Footnote 5] Nevertheless, collective ratemaking is not compelled by any of the States; every common carrier remains free to submit individual rate proposals to the Public Service Commissions. [Footnote 6]

Page 471 U. S. 52

As indicated above, SMCRC and NCMCA are private associations composed of motor common carriers operating in North Carolina, Georgia, Mississippi, and Tennessee. [Footnote 7] Both organizations have committees that consider possible rate changes. [Footnote 8] If a rate committee concludes that an intrastate rate should be changed, a collective proposal for the changed rate is submitted to the State Public Service Commission. Members of the bureau, however, are not bound by the joint proposal. Any disapproving member may submit an independent rate proposal to the state regulatory Commission. [Footnote 9]

B

On November 17, 1976, the United States instituted this action against SMCRC and NCMCA in the United States District Court for the Northern District of Georgia. [Footnote 10] The

Page 471 U. S. 53

United States charged that the two rate bureaus had violated § 1 of the Sherman Act by conspiring with their members to fix rates for the intrastate transportation of general commodities. The rate bureaus responded that their conduct was exempt from the federal antitrust laws by virtue of the state action doctrine. See Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341 (1943). [Footnote 11] They further asserted that their collective ratemaking activities did not violate the Sherman Act, because the rates ultimately were determined by the appropriate state agencies. The District Court found the rate bureaus' arguments meritless, and entered a summary judgment in favor of the Government. 467 F. Supp. 471 (1979). The defendants were enjoined from engaging in collective ratemaking activities with their members.

The Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit (Unit B, now the Eleventh Circuit), sitting en banc, affirmed the judgment of the District Court. 702 F.2d 532 (1983). [Footnote 12] Relying primarily on Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U. S. 773 (1975), the court held that the rate bureaus' challenged conduct, because it was not compelled by the State, was not entitled to Parker immunity. The two-pronged test set forth in California Retail Liquor Dealers Assn. v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc., 445 U. S. 97 (1980), was irrelevant, the court reasoned, for in that case a public official was the

Page 471 U. S. 54

named defendant. [Footnote 13] 702 F.2d at 539. The Court of Appeals further held that, even if Midcal were applicable to a private party's claim of state action immunity, the rate bureaus were not shielded from liability under the Sherman Act. The court concluded that only if the anticompetitive acts of a private party are compelled can a State's policy be held "clearly articulated and affirmatively expressed" within the meaning of Midcal. 702 F.2d at 539.

After finding the rate bureaus not entitled to Parker immunity, the Court of Appeals held that their collective ratemaking activities violated the Sherman Act. 672 F.2d 469, 481 (1982). [Footnote 14] It rejected the rate bureaus' contention that, because the regulatory agencies had ultimate authority and control over the rates charged, the federal antitrust laws were not violated. The Court of Appeals found that "joint ratesetting . . . reduce[d] the amount of independent rate filing that otherwise would characterize the market process," and thus raised the prices charged for intrastate transportation of general commodities. Id. at 478. This "naked price restraint," the court reasoned, is per se illegal. Ibid.

Four judges strongly dissented. They argued that Midcal was applicable to a private party's claim of state action immunity. The success of an antitrust action should depend upon the activity challenged, rather than the identity of the defendant. 702 F.2d at 543-544. After asserting that Midcal provided the relevant test, the dissenters concluded that the lack of compulsion was not dispositive. Even in the absence of compulsion, a "state can articulate a clear and express policy." Id. at 546. The dissent further concluded that a per se compulsion requirement denies States needed flexibility in the formation of regulatory programs, and thus is

Page 471 U. S. 55

inconsistent with the principles of federalism that Congress intended to embody in the Sherman Act. [Footnote 15]

We granted certiorari, [Footnote 16] 467 U.S. 1240 (1984), to decide whether petitioners' collective ratemaking activities, though not compelled by the States in which they operate, are entitled to Parker immunity. [Footnote 17]

II In Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. at 317 U. S. 341, this Court held that the Sherman Act was not intended to prohibit States from imposing restraints on competition. [Footnote 18] There, a raisin producer

Page 471 U. S. 56

filed an action against the California Director of Agriculture to enjoin the enforcement of the State's Agricultural Prorate Act. Under that statute, a cartel of private raisin producers was created in order to stabilize prices and prevent "economic waste." Id. at 317 U. S. 346. The Court recognized that the State's program was anticompetitive, and it assumed that Congress, "in the exercise of its commerce power, [could] prohibit a state from maintaining [such] a stabilization program. . . ." Id. at 317 U. S. 350. Nevertheless, the Court refused to find in the Sherman Act "an unexpressed purpose to nullify a state's control over its officers and agents. . . ." Id. at 317 U. S. 351.

Although Parker involved an action against a state official, the Court's reasoning extends to suits against private parties. The Parker decision was premised on the assumption that Congress, in enacting the Sherman Act, did not intend to compromise the States' ability to regulate their domestic commerce. [Footnote 19] If Parker immunity were limited to the actions of public officials, this assumed congressional purpose would be frustrated, for a State would be unable to implement programs that restrain competition among private parties. A plaintiff could frustrate any such program merely by filing suit against the regulated private parties, rather than the

Page 471 U. S. 57

state officials who implement the plan. We decline to reduce Parker's holding to a formalism that would stand for little more than the proposition that Porter Brown sued the wrong parties. Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U. S. 579, 428 U. S. 616-617, n. 4 (1976) (Stewart, J., dissenting).

The circumstances in which Parker immunity is available to private parties, and to state agencies or officials regulating the conduct of private parties, are defined most specifically by our decision in California Retail Liquor Dealers Assn. v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc., 445 U.S. at 445 U. S. 97. See Hallie v. Eau Claire, ante at 471 U. S. 46, n. 10. In Midcal, we affirmed a state court injunction prohibiting officials from enforcing a statute requiring wine producers to establish resale price schedules. We set forth a two-pronged test for determining whether state regulation of private parties is shielded from the federal antitrust laws. First, the challenged restraint must be "one clearly articulated and affirmatively expressed as state policy.'" 445 U.S. at 445 U. S. 105, quoting Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light Co., 435 U. S. 389, 435 U. S. 410 (1978) (opinion of BRENNAN, J.). Second, the State must supervise actively any private anticompetitive conduct. 445 U.S. at 445 U. S. 105. [Footnote 20] This supervision requirement prevents the State from frustrating the national policy in favor of competition by casting a "gauzy cloak of state involvement" over what is essentially private anticompetitive conduct. Id. at 445 U. S. 106. [Footnote 21]

Page 471 U. S. 58

III The Midcal test does not expressly provide that the actions of a private party must be compelled by a State in order to be protected from the federal antitrust laws. The Court of Appeals, however, held that compulsion is a threshold requirement to a finding of Parker immunity. It reached this conclusion by finding that: (i) Midcal is inapplicable to suits brought against private parties; (ii) even if Midcal is applicable, private conduct that is not compelled cannot be taken pursuant to a "clearly articulated state policy," within the meaning of Midcal's first prong; and (iii) because Goldfarb was cited with approval in Midcal, the Midcal Court endorsed the continued validity of a "compulsion requirement." We consider these points in order.

A

The Court of Appeals held that Midcal, that involved a suit against a state agency, is inapplicable where a private party is the named defendant. Midcal, however, should not be given such a narrow reading. In that case, we were concerned, as we are here, with state regulation restraining competition among private parties. Therefore, the two-pronged test set forth in Midcal should be used to determine whether the private rate bureaus' collective ratemaking activities are protected from the federal antitrust laws. The success of an antitrust action should depend upon the nature of the activity challenged, rather than on the identity of the

Page 471 U. S. 59

defendant. See Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., supra, at 428 U. S. 604 (BURGER, C.J., concurring in part and concurring in judgment); Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light Co., supra, at 435 U. S. 420 (BURGER, C.J., concurring in part and concurring in judgment).

B

The Court of Appeals held that, even if Midcal were applicable here, the rate bureaus would not be immune from federal antitrust liability. According to that court, the actions of a private party cannot be attributed to a clearly articulated state policy, within the meaning of the Midcal test's first prong, "when it is left to the private party to carry out that policy or not as he sees fit." 702 F.2d at 539. In the four States in which petitioners operate, all common carriers are free to submit proposals individually. The court therefore reasoned that the States' policies are neutral with respect to collective ratemaking, and that these policies will not be frustrated if the federal antitrust laws are construed to require individual submissions.

In reaching its conclusion, the Court of Appeals assumed that, if anticompetitive activity is not compelled, the State can have no interest in whether private parties engage in that conduct. This type of analysis ignores the manner in which the States in this case clearly have intended their permissive policies to work. Most common carriers probably will engage in collective ratemaking, as that will allow them to share the cost of preparing rate proposals. If the joint rates are viewed as too high, however, carriers individually may submit lower proposed rates to the Commission in order to obtain a larger share of the market. Thus, through the self-interested actions of private common carriers, the States may achieve the desired balance between the efficiency of collective ratemaking and the competition fostered by individual submissions. Construing the Sherman Act to prohibit collective rate proposals eliminates the free choice necessary to ensure that these policies function in the manner intended

Page 471 U. S. 60

by the States. The federal antitrust laws do not forbid the States to adopt policies that permit, but do not compel, anticompetitive conduct by regulated private parties. As long as the State clearly articulates its intent to adopt a permissive policy, the first prong of the Midcal test is satisfied. [Footnote 22]

C

In Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U. S. 773 (1975), this Court said that

"[t]he threshold inquiry in determining if an anticompetitive activity is state action of the type the Sherman Act was not meant to proscribe is whether the activity is required by the State acting as sovereign."

Id. at 421 U. S. 790. Midcal cited Goldfarb with approval. 445 U.S. at 445 U. S. 104. On the basis of this citation, the Court of Appeals reasoned that Midcal did not eliminate the "compulsion requirement" of Goldfarb.

Goldfarb, however, is not properly read as making compulsion a sine qua non to state action immunity. In that case, the Virginia State Bar, a state agency, compelled Fairfax County lawyers to adhere to a minimum fee schedule. 421 U.S. at 421 U. S. 776-778. The Goldfarb Court therefore was not concerned with the necessity of compulsion -- its presence in the case was not an issue. The focal point of the Goldfarb opinion was the source of the anticompetitive policy, rather than whether the challenged conduct was compelled. The Court held that a State Bar, acting alone, could not immunize its anticompetitive conduct. Instead, the Court held that private parties were entitled to Parker immunity only if the State "acting as sovereign" intended to displace competition. 421 U.S. at 421 U. S. 790; see Lafayette v. Louisiana Power

Page 471 U. S. 61

& Light Co., 435 U.S. at 435 U. S. 410 (opinion of BRENNAN, J.) ("Goldfarb . . . made it clear that, for purposes of the Parker doctrine, not every act of a state agency is that of the State as sovereign").

Although Goldfarb did employ language of compulsion, it is beyond dispute that the Court would have reached the same result had it applied the two-pronged test later set forth in Midcal. As stated above, Virginia, "as sovereign," did not have a "clearly articulated policy" designed to displace price competition among lawyers. In fact, the Supreme Court of Virginia had explicitly directed lawyers not "to be controlled" by minimum fee schedules. Goldfarb, supra, at 421 U. S. 789, n.19. Although we recognize that the language in Goldfarb is not without ambiguity, we do not read that opinion as making compulsion a prerequisite to a finding of state action immunity.

D

The Parker doctrine represents an attempt to resolve conflicts that may arise between principles of federalism and the goal of the antitrust laws, unfettered competition in the marketplace. A compulsion requirement is inconsistent with both values. It reduces the range of regulatory alternatives available to the State. At the same time, insofar as it encourages States to require, rather than merely permit, anticompetitive conduct, a compulsion requirement may result in greater restraints on trade. We do not believe that Congress intended to resolve conflicts between two competing interests by impairing both more than necessary.

In summary, we hold Midcal's two-pronged test applicable to private parties' claims of state action immunity. Moreover, a state policy that expressly permits, but does not compel, anticompetitive conduct may be "clearly articulated" within the meaning of Midcal. [Footnote 23] Our holding today does not

Page 471 U. S. 62

suggest, however, that compulsion is irrelevant. To the contrary, compulsion often is the best evidence that the State has a clearly articulated and affirmatively expressed policy to displace competition. See Hallie v. Eau Claire, ante at 471 U. S. 45-46; 1 P. Areeda & D. Turner, Antitrust Law � 212.5, p. 62 (Supp.1982) (compulsion is "powerful evidence" of existence of state policy). Nevertheless, when other evidence conclusively shows that a State intends to adopt a permissive policy, the absence of compulsion should not prove fatal to a claim of Parker immunity.

IV A

Our holding that there is no inflexible "compulsion requirement" does not suggest necessarily that petitioners' collective ratemaking activities are shielded from the federal antitrust laws. A private party may claim state action immunity only if both prongs of the Midcal test are satisfied. Here the Court of Appeals found, and the Government concedes, that the State Public Service Commissions actively supervise the collective ratemaking activities of the rate bureaus. Therefore, the only issue left to resolve is whether the petitioners' challenged conduct was taken pursuant to a clearly articulated state policy.

The Public Service Commissions in North Carolina, Georgia, Mississippi, and Tennessee permit collective ratemaking. See n 4, supra. Acting alone, however, these agencies

Page 471 U. S. 63

could not immunize private anticompetitive conduct. In Goldfarb, the State Bar -- a special type of "state agency" -- prohibited lawyers from charging fees lower than those set forth in schedules published by the local bar. Nevertheless, this Court held that the local lawyers were not immune from antitrust liability, because their anticompetitive conduct was not required by the State as sovereign. 421 U.S. at 421 U. S. 790. Parker immunity is available only when the challenged activity is undertaken pursuant to a clearly articulated policy of the State itself, such as a policy approved by a state legislature, see New Motor Vehicle Bd. of Cal. v. Orrin W. Fox Co., 439 U. S. 96 (1978), or a State Supreme Court, Bates v. State Bar of Arizona, 433 U. S. 350 (1977).

In this case, therefore, the petitioners are entitled to Parker immunity only if collective ratemaking is clearly sanctioned by the legislatures of the four States in which the rate bureaus operate. North Carolina, Georgia, and Tennessee have statutes that explicitly permit collective ratemaking by common carriers. [Footnote 24] The rate bureaus' challenged actions, at least in these States, are taken pursuant to an express and clearly articulated state policy. Mississippi's legislature, however, has not specifically addressed collective ratemaking. We therefore must consider whether, in the absence of a statute expressly permitting the challenged conduct, the first prong of the Midcal test can be satisfied.

B

The Mississippi Motor Carrier Regulatory Law of 1938, Miss.Code Ann. § 77-7-1 et seq. (1972 and Supp.1984), gives the State Public Service Commission authority to regulate common carriers. The statute provides that the Commission is to prescribe "just and reasonable" rates for the intrastate transportation of general commodities. § 77-7-221. The legislature thus made clear its intent that intrastate rates

Page 471 U. S. 64

would be determined by a regulatory agency, rather than by the market. The details of the inherently anticompetitive rate-setting process, however, are left to the agency's discretion. The State Commission has exercised its discretion by actively encouraging collective ratemaking among common carriers. See Response of the State of Mississippi and the Mississippi Public Service Comm'n as Amici Curiae in District Court, No. 76-1909A (ND Ga.1977), p. 11. We do not believe that the actions petitioners took pursuant to this regulatory program should be deprived of Parker immunity.

A private party acting pursuant to an anticompetitive regulatory program need not "point to a specific, detailed legislative authorization" for its challenged conduct. Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light Co., 435 U.S. at 435 U. S. 415 (opinion of BRENNAN, J.). As long as the State, as sovereign, clearly intends to displace competition in a particular field with a regulatory structure, the first prong of the Midcal test is satisfied. In Goldfarb, the Court held that Parker immunity was unavailable only because the State, as sovereign, did not intend to do away with competition among lawyers. 421 U.S. at 421 U. S. 790. Similarly, in Cantor, the anticompetitive acts of a private utility were held unprotected because the Michigan Legislature had indicated no intention to displace competition in the relevant market. 428 U.S. at 428 U. S. 584-585.

If more detail than a clear intent to displace competition were required of the legislature, States would find it difficult to implement through regulatory agencies their anticompetitive policies. Agencies are created because they are able to deal with problems unforeseeable to, or outside the competence of, the legislature. Requiring express authorization for every action that an agency might find necessary to effectuate state policy would diminish, if not destroy, its usefulness. Cf. Hallie v. Eau Claire, ante at 471 U. S. 44 (requiring explicit legislative authorization of anticompetitive activity would impose "detrimental side effects upon municipalities' local autonomy"). Therefore, we hold

Page 471 U. S. 65

that, if the State's intent to establish an anticompetitive regulatory program is clear, as it is in Mississippi, [Footnote 25] the State's failure to describe the implementation of its policy in detail will not subject the program to the restraints of the federal antitrust laws.

C

In summary, we hold that the petitioners' collective ratemaking activity is immune from Sherman Act liability. This anticompetitive conduct is taken pursuant to a "clearly articulated state policy." The legislatures of North Carolina, Georgia, and Tennessee expressly permit motor common carriers to submit collective rate proposals to Public Service Commissions, which have the authority to accept, reject, or modify any recommendation. Mississippi, the fourth State in which the petitioners operate, has not expressly approved of collective ratemaking, but it has articulated clearly its intent to displace price competition among common carriers with a regulatory structure. Anticompetitive conduct taken pursuant to such a regulatory program satisfies the first

Page 471 U. S. 66

prong of the Midcal test. The second prong of the Midcal test likewise is met, for the Government has conceded that the relevant States, through their agencies, actively supervise the conduct of private parties.

V We conclude that the petitioners' collective ratemaking activities, although not compelled by the States, are immune from antitrust liability under the doctrine of Parker v. Brown. Accordingly, the judgment of the Court of Appeals is reversed.

It is so ordered.

[Footnote 1]

N.C.Gen.Stat. § 62-130(a) (1982); Ga.Code Ann. § 46-7-18 (Supp.1984); Miss.Code Ann. § 77-7-217 (1972); Tenn.Code Ann. § 65-15-106(a) (Supp.1984).

The Interstate Commerce Commission has the power to fix common carriers' rates for the interstate transportation of general commodities. 49 U.S.C. § 10704. The Interstate Commerce Act, however, expressly reserves to the States the regulation of common carriers' intrastate rates, even if these rates affect interstate commerce. 49 U.S.C. § 10521(b).

[Footnote 2]

N.C.Gen.Stat. § 62-134(a) (1982); Ga.Code Ann. § 46-2-25(a) (1982); Miss.Code Ann. §§ 77-7-211 and 77-7-215 (1972); Tenn.Code Ann. 65-5-202 (1982).

[Footnote 3]

N.C.Gen.Stat. § 62-134(b) (1982); Ga.Code Ann. § 46-2-25(b) (1982); Miss.Code Ann. §§ 77-7-217 and 77-7-219 (1972); Tenn.Code Ann. § 65-5-203(a) (Supp.1984).

[Footnote 4]

N.C.Gen.Stat. § 62-152.1(b) (1982); Ga.Code Ann. § 46-7-18 (Supp.1984), Ga.Pub.Serv.Comm'n Rule 1-3-1-.14 (1983); Response of the State of Mississippi and the Mississippi Public Service Comm'n as Amici Curiae in No. 76-1909A (ND Ga.1977), p. 11; Tenn.Code Ann. § 65-15119 (Supp.1984), Tenn.Pub.Serv.Comm'n Rule 1220-2-1-.40, Rules, Regulations and Statutes Governing Motor Carriers, p. 29 (1974).

[Footnote 5]

See, e.g., Response of the State of Mississippi and the Mississippi Public Service Comm'n, supra, at 15-16.

Moreover, the uniformity in prices that collective ratemaking tends to produce is considered desirable by the legislature of at least one State and the Public Service Commission of another. See N.C.Gen.Stat. § 62-152.1(b) (1982); Miss.Pub.Serv.Comm'n Rule 39D(4), Rules of Practice and Procedure and General Rules and Regulations under the Miss. Motor Carrier Act of 1938, as amended, p. 37 (1972).

[Footnote 6]

N.C.Gen.Stat. § 62-152.1(e) (1982); Ga.Pub.Serv.Comm'n Rule 1-3-1-.14, supra; Response of the State of Mississippi and the Mississippi Public Service Comm'n, supra, at 11; Tenn.Pub.Serv.Comm'n Rule 1220-2-1-.40, supra.

[Footnote 7]

At the time this action was filed, SMCRC represented its common carrier members before Public Service Commissions in North Carolina, Georgia, Mississippi, Tennessee, and Alabama. SMCRC, however, is no longer active before the Alabama Public Service Commission. Brief for Petitioners 3, n. 2. NCMCA represents its members before the regulatory agency in North Carolina.

[Footnote 8]

SMCRC has a separate rate committee for each of the States in which its members operate -- North Carolina, Georgia, Mississippi, and Tennessee. NCMCA, which is concerned solely with matters before the North Carolina Public Service Commission, has only one rate committee.

[Footnote 9]

In addition to providing a forum for their members to discuss rate proposals, the rate bureaus:

"[(i)] publish tariffs and supplements containing the rates on which the carriers agree; and [(ii)] provide counsel, staff experts, and facilities for the preparation of cost studies, other exhibits and testimony for use in support of proposed rates at hearings held by the regulatory commissions."

702 F.2d 532, 534 (1983).

[Footnote 10]

Motor Carriers Traffic Association, Inc. (MCTA), another rate bureau operating in North Carolina, also was named as a defendant. MCTA did not appeal from the District Court's judgment, and is not a party before this Court.

The District Court permitted the National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC), an organization composed of state agencies, to intervene as a defendant. See Fed.Rule Civ.Proc. 24(a). Throughout this litigation, the NARUC has represented the interests of the Public Service Commissions of those States in which the defendant rate bureaus operate.

[Footnote 11]

The defendants also contended that their collective ratemaking activities were protected by the Noerr-Pennington doctrine. See Eastern Railroad Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U. S. 127 (1961); Mine Workers v. Pennington, 381 U. S. 657 (1965). Both the District Court and the Court of Appeals rejected this defense, and we do not address it. See n. 17 infra.

[Footnote 12]

A panel of that court, with one judge dissenting, had affirmed the District Court's judgment. United States v. Southern Motor Carriers Rate Conference, Inc., 672 F.2d 469 (1982).

[Footnote 13]

In this case, the Government elected, without explanation, not to name as defendants the state Public Service Commissions that regulated the motor common carriers' intrastate rates.

[Footnote 14]

The en banc Court of Appeals reinstated the part of the panel's opinion that addressed the Sherman Act violation. 702 F.2d at 542.

[Footnote 15]

Judge Clark's separate dissenting opinion criticized the majority for ignoring "the Interstate Commerce Act, public policy, history, and fairness." Id. at 548.

[Footnote 16]

The joint petition for a writ of certiorari was filed by SMCRC, NCMCA, and the NARUC.

[Footnote 17]

Although we granted certiorari on the Noerr-Pennington issue as well, see n 11, supra, our disposition of this case makes it unnecessary to consider the applicability of that doctrine to the petitioners' collective ratemaking activities.

[Footnote 18]

JUSTICE STEVENS, noting that "[i]mplied antitrust immunities . . . are disfavored . . . ," post at 471 U. S. 67, cites United States v. South-Eastern Underwriters Assn., 322 U. S. 533 (1944), for the proposition that "if exceptions are to be written into the Sherman Act, they must come from Congress, and not this Court." Id. at 322 U. S. 561. The dissent apparently finds some significance in the fact that no federal statute expressly exempts the petitioners' collective ratemaking activities from the antitrust laws. See post at 471 U. S. 70.

The dissent's argument on this point, of course, does not suggest that compulsion should be a prerequisite to a finding of state action immunity. Instead, the logical result of its reasoning would require us to overrule Parker v. Brown and its progeny, for the state action doctrine is an implied exemption to the antitrust laws. After over 40 years of congressional acquiescence, we are unwilling to abandon the Parker doctrine.

JUSTICE STEVENS relies primarily upon United States v. South-Eastern Underwriters, supra, and Georgia v. Pennsylvania R. Co., 324 U. S. 439 (1945), in the first section of his dissent. Neither of these cases, however, has any bearing on the scope of Parker immunity. In South-Eastern Underwriters, supra, the Court held only that the "business of insurance is interstate commerce," Group Life & Health Ins. Co. v. Royal Drug Co., 440 U. S. 205, 440 U. S. 217 (1979), and thus is subject to the Sherman Act's proscriptions. The Court did not suggest that, because of congressional silence, state regulation could not immunize insurance companies from the federal antitrust laws. Instead, it reasoned that Parker did not protect the insurance companies, because

"no states authorize combinations of insurance companies to coerce, intimidate, and boycott competitors and consumers in the manner . . . [there] alleged."

322 U.S. at 322 U. S. 562. In Georgia v. Pennsylvania R. Co., supra, the Court was concerned with whether Congress intended to immunize a federal regulatory program from the antitrust laws. See n 21, infra.

[Footnote 19]

In holding that the States were free to regulate "domestic commerce," the Parker Court relied upon congressional silence. There are, however, some statements in the legislative history that affirmatively express a desire not "to invade the legislative authority of the several States. . . ." H.R.Rep. No. 1707, 51st Cong., 1st Sess., 1 (1890). See Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U. S. 579, 428 U. S. 632 (1976) (Stewart, J., dissenting).

[Footnote 20]

As we hold today in Hallie v. Eau Claire, ante at 471 U. S. 46, the second prong of the Midcal test is inapplicable to municipalities. Although its anticompetitive conduct must be taken pursuant to a clearly articulated state policy, a municipality need not be supervised by the State in order to qualify for Parker immunity. See ante at 471 U. S. 46.

[Footnote 21]

The dissent argues that a state regulatory program is entitled to Parker immunity only if an antitrust exemption is "necessary . . . to make the [program] work. . . .'" Post at 471 U. S. 74 (quoting Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., supra, at 428 U. S. 597). This argument overlooks the fact that, with the exception of a questionable dictum in Cantor, supra, the dissent's proposed test has been used only in deciding whether Congress intended to immunize a federal regulatory program from the Sherman Act's proscriptions. See, e.g., Silver v. New York Stock Exchange, 373 U. S. 341, 373 U. S. 357 (1963). In this context, if the federal courts wrongly conclude that an antitrust exemption is "unnecessary," Congress can correct the error. As the dissent recognizes, however, the Supremacy Clause would prevent state legislatures from taking similar remedial action. Post at 471 U. S. 67. Moreover, the proposed test would prompt the "kind of interference with state sovereignty . . . that . . . Parker was intended to prevent." 1 P. Areeda & D. Turner, Antitrust Law � 214, p. 88 (1978). Therefore, we hold that state action immunity is not dependent on a finding that an exemption from the federal antitrust laws is "necessary."

[Footnote 22]

Under the Interstate Commerce Act, motor common carriers are permitted, but not compelled, to engage in collective interstate ratemaking. 49 U.S.C. §§ 10706(b)(2) and 10706(d)(2)(C). It is clear, therefore, that Congress has recognized the advantages of a permissive policy. We think it unlikely that Congress intended to prevent the States from adopting virtually identical policies at the intrastate level.

[Footnote 23]

Contrary to the Government's arguments, our holding here does not suggest that a State may "give immunity to those who violate the Sherman Act by authorizing them to violate it." Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. at 317 U. S. 351; see Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers Corp., 341 U. S. 384 (1951). A clearly articulated permissive policy will satisfy the first prong of the Midcal test. The second prong, however, prevents States from "casting . . . a gauzy cloak of state involvement over what is essentially a private price-fixing arrangement." Midcal, 445 U.S. at 445 U. S. 106. This active supervision requirement ensures that a State's actions will immunize the anticompetitive conduct of private parties only when the "state has demonstrated its commitment to a program through its exercise of regulatory oversight." See 1 P. Areeda & D. Turner, Antitrust Law § 213a, p. 73 (1978).

[Footnote 24]

N.C.Gen.Stat. § 62-152.1(b) (1982); Ga.Code Ann. § 46-7-18 (1982 and Supp.1984); Tenn.Code Ann. § 65-15-119 (1982).

[Footnote 25]

The Mississippi statute stands in sharp contrast to the Colorado Home Rule Amendment, which we considered in Community Communications Co. v. Boulder, 455 U. S. 40 (1982). In Boulder, the State Constitution gave municipalities extensive powers of self-government. Id. at 455 U. S. 43-44. Pursuant to this authority, the city of Boulder prohibited a cable television company from expanding its operations. The Court held that, because the Home Rule Amendment did not evidence an intent to displace competition in the cable television industry, id. at 455 U. S. 55, Boulder's anticompetitive ordinance was not enacted pursuant to a clearly articulated state policy. This holding was premised on the fact that Boulder, as a "home rule municipality," was authorized to elect free-market competition as an alternative to regulation. Id. at 455 U. S. 56.

In this case, on the other hand, the Mississippi Public Service Commission is not authorized to choose free-market competition. Instead, it is required to prescribe rates for motor common carriers on the basis of statutorily enumerated factors. Miss.Code Ann. § 77-7-221 (1972). These factors bear no discernible relationship to the prices that would be set by a perfectly efficient and unregulated market. Therefore, the Mississippi statute clearly indicates that the legislature intended to displace competition in the intrastate trucking industry with a regulatory program.

JUSTICE STEVENS, with whom JUSTICE WHITE joins, dissenting.

The term "price-fixing" generally refers to a process by which competitors agree upon the prices that will prevail in the market for the goods or services they offer. Such behavior is not essential to every public program for regulating industry. In this case, for example, four Southern States have established programs for evaluating the reasonableness of rates that motor carriers propose to charge for intrastate transport, but the States do not require price-fixing by motor carriers. They merely tolerate it.

Reasoning deductively from a dictum in California Retail Liquor Dealers Assn. v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc., 445 U. S. 97, 445 U. S. 105 (1980), the Court holds that Congress did not intend to prohibit price-fixing by motor carrier rate bureaus -- at least when such conduct is prompted, but not required, by a State Public Service Commission. The result is inconsistent with the language [Footnote 2/1] and policies of the Sherman Act, and this Court's precedent. The Sherman Act only would interfere with the regulatory process if the States compelled price

Page 471 U. S. 67

fixing that is unlawful under federal law. In that situation, the regulated carriers would face conflicting obligations under state and federal law, and the success of the States' regulatory programs would be threatened. Except under those circumstances, immunity from the antitrust laws under the state action doctrine is not available for private persons. [Footnote 2/2]

I "Whatever may be its peculiar problems and characteristics, the Sherman Act, so far as price-fixing agreements are concerned, establishes one uniform rule applicable to all industries alike: [Footnote 2/3]"

agreements and combinations tampering with competitive price structures are unlawful. State legislatures, whose powers are limited by the Supremacy Clause, [Footnote 2/4] may not expressly modify the obligations of any person under this federal law. Only Congress, expressly or by implication, may authorize price-fixing, and has done so in particular industries or compelling circumstances. Implied antitrust immunities, however, are disfavored [Footnote 2/5] and any exemptions

Page 471 U. S. 68

from the antitrust laws are to be strictly construed. [Footnote 2/6] These "canon[s] of construction . . . reflec[t] the felt indispensable role of antitrust policy in the maintenance of a free economy." United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U. S. 321, 374 U. S. 348 (1963).

Applying these principles, this Court has consistently embraced the view that "[r]egulated industries are not per se exempt from the Sherman Act." Georgia v. Pennsylvania R. Co., 324 U. S. 439, 324 U. S. 456 (1945). For many years prior to the enactment of the Sherman Act, state agencies regulated the business of insurance, but we rejected the view that these programs of public scrutiny supported "our reading into the Act an exemption" allowing insurance businesses to fix premium rates and agents' commissions. United States v. South-Eastern Underwriters Assn., 322 U. S. 533, 322 U. S. 559 (1944). In South-Eastern Underwriters, the Court tersely observed that "if exceptions are to be written into the Act, they must come from Congress, not this Court." Id. at 322 U. S. 561. Thereafter, in the McCarran-Ferguson Act of 1945, 59 Stat. 33, Congress decided, as a matter of policy, that the Sherman Act's prohibition of price-fixing "shall [only] be applicable to the business of insurance to the extent that such business is not regulated by State Law." 15 U.S.C. § 1012(b).

Consistent with its treatment of the insurance business in South-Eastern Underwriters, this Court has repeatedly held that collusive price-fixing by railroads is unlawful even though the end result is a reasonable charge approved by a public rate commission. [Footnote 2/7] Georgia v. Pennsylvania R. Co.,

Page 471 U. S. 69

324 U.S. at 324 U. S. 455-463.; United States v. Tans-Missouri Freight Assn., 166 U. S. 290, 166 U. S. 337-340 (1897). In the Pennsylvania Railroad case, the Court explained why this is so:

"The fact that the rates which have been fixed may or may not be held unlawful by the [Interstate Commerce] Commission is immaterial to the issue before us. . . . [E]ven a combination to fix reasonable and nondiscriminatory rates may be illegal. [Keogh v. Chicago & Northwestern R. Co., 260 U. S. 156, 260 U. S. 161 (1922)]. The reason is that the Interstate Commerce Act does not provide remedies for the correction of all the abuses of ratemaking which might constitute violations of the anti-trust laws. Thus a 'zone of reasonableness exists between maxima and minima within which a carrier is ordinarily free to adjust its charges for itself.' United States v. Chicago, M., St. P. & P. R. Co., 294 U. S. 499, 294 U. S. 506 [1935]. Within that zone, the Commission lacks power to grant relief even though the rates are raised to the maxima by a conspiracy among carriers who employ

Page 471 U. S. 70

unlawful tactics. . . . Damage must be presumed to flow from a conspiracy to manipulate rates within that zone."

324 U.S. at 324 U. S. 460-461. Collusive price-fixing by regulated carriers causes upward pressure on rates within the zone of reasonableness, and such combinations and conspiracies are generally actionable under the Sherman Act on the theory of the Pennsylvania Railroad case.

Congress reacted to the Pennsylvania Railroad decision much as it reacted to the South-Eastern Underwriters decision. It decided, as a matter of policy, that some price-fixing should be permitted in the transportation industry, and enacted the Reed-Bulwinkle Act of 1948 to effectuate that policy choice. [Footnote 2/8] In the Motor Carrier Act of 1980, [Footnote 2/9] however, Congress sharply curtailed the availability of this antitrust exemption. Collective ratemaking is still permitted in limited circumstances, but rate bureaus must comply with strict procedural requirements. See 471 U.S. 48fn2/19|>n.19, infra.

The defendants have stipulated that their price-fixing arrangements are identical to those followed by the Carrier Rate Committees in the Pennsylvania Railroad case which were declared unlawful under the Sherman Act. See App. 40-41. They also acknowledge that neither the Reed-Bulwinkle Act nor any other federal statute expressly exempts their price-fixing from the antitrust laws. Nevertheless, they contend that Congress would not have intended to prohibit collective ratemaking by intrastate motor carriers when it is permitted, but not required, by state law.

Page 471 U. S. 71

II The basis for the defendants' claim of implied immunity from the antitrust laws is the state action doctrine of Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341 (1943). This Court, however, has repeatedly recognized that private entities may not claim the state action immunity unless their unlawful conduct is compelled by the State.

In the Parker case, this Court held that the Sherman Act does not reach "state action or official action directed by a state." Id. at 317 U. S. 351. The case involved price-fixing that was mandated by a California statute in the furtherance of a price-support program for raisin farmers. The Court held that the price-fixing was not prohibited by the Sherman Act:

"[T]he prorate program here was never intended to operate by force of individual agreement or combination. It derived its authority and its efficacy from the legislative command of the state, and was not intended to operate or become effective without that command. We find nothing in the language of the Sherman Act or in its history which suggests that its purpose was to restrain a state or its officers or agents from activities directed by its legislature."

Id. at 317 U. S. 350-351. Under Parker, private anticompetitive conduct must be "directed" by the State to be eligible for the state action immunity.

In a later case involving price-fixing by attorneys through minimum fee schedules, the Court unanimously stated:

"The threshold inquiry in determining if an anticompetitive activity is state action of the type the Sherman Act was not meant to proscribe is whether the activity is required by the State acting as sovereign. Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. at 317 U. S. 350-352; Continental Co. v. Union Carbide, 370 U. S. 690, 370 U. S. 706-707 (1962)."

Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U. S. 773, 421 U. S. 790 (1975). In Goldfarb, no state statute or Supreme Court rule required the defendant County Bar Association to

Page 471 U. S. 72

adopt the minimum fee schedule, and this Court concluded that this

"is not state action for Sherman Act purposes. It is not enough that, as the County Bar puts it, anticompetitive conduct is 'prompted' by state action; rather, anticompetitive activities must be compelled by direction of the State acting as a sovereign."

Id. at 421 U. S. 791.

In Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U. S. 579 (1976), the Court was also unanimous in its understanding that sovereign compulsion was a prerequisite for state action immunity. [Footnote 2/10] The opinion for the Court observed that it has long been settled "that state authorization, approval, encouragement, or participation in restrictive private conduct confers no antitrust immunity." Id. at 428 U. S. 592-593 (footnotes omitted). [Footnote 2/11] The dissenting Justices agreed: "private conduct, if it is to come within the state action exemption, must be not merely prompted' but `compelled' by state action." Id. at 428 U. S. 637 (Stewart, J., dissenting, joined by POWELL and REHNQUIST, JJ.).

In Cantor, the Court only divided on the question whether the compulsion requirement alone was sufficient to confer antitrust immunity. The dissent argued that Congress would not have intended to penalize Detroit Edison for engaging in a light bulb distribution program that had been approved by the Michigan Public Service Commission and that could not be discontinued without approval of the Commission. Id. at 428 U. S. 614-615. The Court, on the other hand, acknowledged that continuation of the light bulb program was ostensibly required by the State, but went on to consider

Page 471 U. S. 73

whether an antitrust exemption for this conduct was fundamental to the State's regulatory program. Since Michigan's statutes only expressed an interest in regulating the electricity market, and not the light bulb market, the Court concluded that,

"[r]egardless of the outcome of this case, Michigan's interest in regulating its utilities' distribution of electricity will be almost entirely unimpaired."

Id. at 428 U. S. 598. Because the State had not articulated any intention to regulate the light bulb market, and the idea for the distribution program had come from the private utility, the State's requirement that the program continue was not sufficient to establish state action immunity from the antitrust laws.

The Court's unanimous decision in California Retail Liquor Dealers Assn. v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc., 445 U. S. 97 (1980), signaled no departure from settled principles in this area. In discussing the principles of law applicable to state action immunity, the Court quoted extensively from the language in Parker and Goldfarb [Footnote 2/12] that recognized the compulsion requirement. In any case, it was quite clear in Midcal that the California statutes required the unlawful resale price maintenance activities. Thus, this Court had no occasion in that case to explore the contours of the compulsion requirement. The references, in the Midcal opinion, to "clearly articulated and affirmatively expressed" policies and "actively supervised" activities merely restated the standards to be applied in evaluating whether conduct ostensibly compelled by the State is entitled to the state action immunity. These requirements limited the scope of the

Page 471 U. S. 74

state action immunity for private entities; they did not expand the immunity to protect conduct that is merely prompted by the State. [Footnote 2/13]

III Today the Court abandons the settled view that a private party is not entitled to state action immunity unless the State compelled him to act in violation of federal law. Hereafter, a State may exempt price-fixing from the federal antitrust laws if it clearly articulates its intention to supplant competition with regulation in the relevant market, and if it actively supervises the unlawful conduct by evaluating the reasonableness of the prices charged. The Court justifies this change in the law by finding it more consistent with "principles of federalism and the goal of the antitrust laws, unfettered competition in the marketplace." Ante at 471 U. S. 61. I believe these conclusions are unsound.

Deference to State Regulatory Programs

The Court's reliance today on vague "principles of federalism" obscures our traditional disfavor for implied exemptions to the Sherman Act. We have only authorized exemptions from the Sherman Act for businesses regulated by federal law when "that exemption was necessary in order to make the regulatory Act work and even then only to the minimum extent necessary.'" [Footnote 2/14] No lesser showing of repugnancy

Page 471 U. S. 75

should be sufficient to justify an implied exemption based on a state regulatory program.

Any other view separates the state action exemption from the reason for its existence. The program involved in the Parker case was designed to enhance the market price of raisins by regulating both output and price. [Footnote 2/15] In other words, the state policy was one that replaced price competition with economic regulation. Price support programs like the one involved in Parker cannot possibly succeed if every individual producer is free to participate or not participate in the program at his option. In Parker, the challenged price-fixing was the heart of California's support program for agriculture; without immunity from the Sherman Act, the State would have had to abandon the project.

In this case, the common denominator in the States' regulatory programs for motor carriers is their reservation of the power to evaluate the reasonableness of proposed rates and

Page 471 U. S. 76

terms of carriage. [Footnote 2/16] In these programs,

"no State requires that all rates among competing carriers for identical service be uniform, [and] no State requires, either by statute or regulation, or other express legislative or administrative mandate, that rates proposed by carriers be formulated by rate conferences."

467 F. Supp. 471, 477 (ND Ga.1979). When, as here, state regulatory policies are permissive, rather than mandatory, there is no necessary conflict between the antitrust laws and the regulatory systems; the regulated entity may comply with the edicts of each sovereign. Indeed, it is almost meaningless to contemplate a "regulatory" policy that gives every regulated entity carte blanche to excuse itself from the consequences of the regulation. Even a policy against speeding could not be enforced if every motorist could drive as fast as he chose. When a State declares that a regulated entity need not follow a regulatory procedure, it as much as admits that this element is inconsequential to the ultimate success of the regulatory program. [Footnote 2/17]

Page 471 U. S. 77

As I have noted, the Reed-Bulwinkle Act [Footnote 2/18] authorizes collective ratemaking by interstate carriers under some circumstances. The Court doubts whether "Congress intended to prevent the States from adopting virtually identical policies at the intrastate level." Ante at 471 U. S. 60, n. 22. The Reed-Bulwinkle exemption, however, has been abolished for single-line rate requests, and to the extent that it still applies to general rate requests, the rate bureaus must follow stringent procedural safeguards which channel their conduct into useful informational tasks, and thereby diminish the threat of anticompetitive misconduct. [Footnote 2/19] Even if there were sound policy reasons [Footnote 2/20] for extending the Reed-Bulwinkle exemption,

Page 471 U. S. 78

as amended, to a state regulatory program that did not contain comparable procedural safeguards,

"[t]hese considerations are . . . not for us. . . . Congress is the body to amend [the statute], and not this court, by a process of judicial legislation wholly unjustifiable."

United States v. Trans-Missouri Freight Assn., 166 U.S. at 166 U. S. 340.

The Policy of Competition

The Court embraces the defendants' specious argument that

"insofar as it encourages States to require, rather than merely permit, anticompetitive conduct, a compulsion requirement may result in greater restraints on trade."

Ante at 471 U. S. 61. The Court finds this "result" inconsistent with the policies of the Sherman Act. This argument is seriously flawed.

On a practical level, the Court's argument assumes that a decision for the Government today would cause the States to rush into enactment legislation compelling price-fixing in the motor carrier industry. Moreover, the Court's argument assumes that a Congress that only recently has acted to increase competition in the interstate motor carrier field would remain silent in the face of anticompetitive legislation at the intrastate level. These assumptions are wholly speculative.

On a more theoretical level, the Court ignores the anticompetitive effect of the collective ratemaking practices challenged in this litigation. [Footnote 2/21] The Court of Appeals correctly observed that

"[c]ollective [rate] formulation clearly tampers with the price structure for intrastate commodities; the rate

Page 471 U. S. 79

bureau arrangement substitutes concerted pricing decisions among competing carriers for the influence of impersonal market forces on proposed rates."

672 F.2d 469, 478 (CA5, Unit B, now CA11, 1982). The increased rates for transportation caused by this behavior are especially grave in a basic industry, like transportation, where the ripple effects of the increased rates are magnified as raw materials, semifinished and finished goods are transported at various stages of production and distribution.

Active supervision of the rate bureau process -- like that provided in the Motor Carrier Act of 1980 -- might minimize the anticompetitive effects of collective ratemaking. To the extent that the State Regulatory Commissions are structured like the ICC in the Pennsylvania Railroad case, however, they only have the power to reject the rates proposed by the carriers if those rates fall outside the "zone of reasonableness." Unless the Commissions "actively supervise" the price-fixing process itself, they cannot eliminate the upward pressure on rates caused by collusive ratemaking. [Footnote 2/22] Unfortunately, the nature of the "active supervision" of those carriers who take part in collective ratemaking is not fully disclosed by the record. [Footnote 2/23]

IV Whether it is wise or unwise policy for the Federal Government to seek to enforce the Sherman Act in this case is not a question that this Court is authorized to consider. The District Court and the Court of Appeals correctly applied established precedent in holding that the Government is entitled

Page 471 U. S. 80

to an injunction against the defendants' price-fixing. Such price-fixing is unlawful unless it is expressly authorized by statute, or required by a State's regulatory program. Today the Court authorizes collective ratemaking by intrastate motor carriers even though the State has only permitted it in a program regulating the reasonableness of prices in the industry. Immunity of this type was rejected by the Court in the South-Eastern Underwriters and Pennsylvania Railroad cases, but today, under the shroud of the state action doctrine, [Footnote 2/24] it is resurrected.

Accordingly, I respectfully dissent.

[Footnote 2/1]

"Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal."

15 U.S.C. § 1.

[Footnote 2/2]

Of course, public agencies like municipalities need only establish that their anticompetitive conduct is taken pursuant to a clearly articulated and affirmatively expressed state policy. Hallie v. Eau Claire, ante at 471 U. S. 46-47. The less stringent requirement reflects the presumption "that the municipality acts in the public interest." Ante at 471 U. S. 45; cf. Affiliated Capital Corp. v. City of Houston, 735 F.2d 1555, 1571-1572 (CA5 1984) (en banc) (Higginbotham, J., concurring), cert. pending, No. 84-951.

[Footnote 2/3]

United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U. S. 150, 310 U. S. 222 (1940); see also Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U. S. 773, 421 U. S. 785 (1975); United States v. McKesson & Robbins, Inc., 351 U. S. 305, 351 U. S. 309-310 (1956); United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc., 334 U. S. 131, 334 U. S. 143 (1948).

[Footnote 2/4]

"This Constitution, and the Laws of the United States which shall be made in Pursuance thereof . . . shall be the supreme Law of the Land; and the Judges in every State shall be bound thereby, any Thing in the Constitution or Laws of any State to the Contrary notwithstanding."

U.S.Const., Art. VI, cl. 2.

[Footnote 2/5]

E.g., National Gerimedical Hospital and Gerontology Center v. Blue Cross of Kansas City, 452 U. S. 378, 452 U. S. 388-389 (1981); United States v. National Assn. of Securities Dealers, Inc., 422 U. S. 694, 422 U. S. 719-720 (1975).

[Footnote 2/6]

E.g., Group Life & Health Insurance Co. v. Royal Drug Co., 440 U. S. 205, 440 U. S. 231 (1979); Abbott Laboratories v. Portland Retail Druggists Assn., Inc., 425 U. S. 1, 425 U. S. 11 (1976).

[Footnote 2/7]

"In [Keogh v. Chicago & Northwestern R. Co., 260 U. S. 156 (1922)], the suit was one for damages under the Sherman Act. The charge was that the defendant carriers had formed a rate bureau or committee to secure agreement in respect to freight rates among the constituent railroad companies which would otherwise be competing carriers. As we have seen, the Court held that damages could not be recovered. But Mr. Justice Brandeis, speaking for a unanimous Court, stated that a conspiracy to fix rates might be illegal though the rates fixed were reasonable and nondiscriminatory. He said . . . :"

"All the rates fixed were reasonable and nondiscriminatory. That was settled by the proceedings before the Commission. . . . But under the Anti-Trust Act, a combination of carriers to fix reasonable and nondiscriminatory rates may be illegal; and if so, the Government may have redress by criminal proceedings under § 3, by injunction under § 4, and by forfeiture under § 6. That was settled by United States v. Trans-Missouri Freight Association, 166 U. S. 290 [1897], and United States v. Joint Traffic Association, 171 U. S. 505 [1898]. The fact that these rates had been approved by the Commission would not, it seems, bar proceedings by the Government."

"[260 U.S. at 260 U. S. 161-162]."

Georgia v. Pennsylvania R. Co., 324 U. S. 439, 324 U. S. 457-458 (1945). Although the Court in Pennsylvania Railroad was divided on the question whether Georgia could pursue its antitrust remedy by invoking this Court's original jurisdiction, the dissenting Justices recognized that the United States could obtain an injunction against the alleged price-fixing in an appropriate forum. See id. at 324 U. S. 484, 324 U. S. 489 (Stone, C.J., dissenting). It is, of course, the United States that seeks relief in the case now before us.

[Footnote 2/8]

"Parties to any agreement approved by the Commission under this section and other persons are . . . hereby relieved from the operation of the antitrust laws with respect to the making of such agreement, and with respect to the carrying out of such agreement in conformity with its provisions and in conformity with the terms and conditions prescribed by the Commission."

62 Stat. 473. The current version of the exemption is codified at 49 U.S.C. § 10706(b)(2).

[Footnote 2/9]

94 Stat. 803, 49 U.S.C. §§ 10706(b)(3)(B) (D).

[Footnote 2/10]

See, e.g., Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U.S. at 428 U. S. 609 (BLACKMUN, J., concurring in judgment).

[Footnote 2/11]

For the proposition stated, the Court relied on Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U.S. at 421 U. S. 791; Continental Co. v. Union Carbide, 370 U. S. 690, 370 U. S. 706-707 (1962); Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341, 317 U. S. 351 (1943); Union Pacific R. Co. v. United States, 313 U. S. 450, 313 U. S. 467-468 (1941); and Northern Securities Co. v. United States, 193 U. S. 197, 193 U. S. 346 (1904).

[Footnote 2/12]

"Several recent decisions have applied Parker's analysis. In Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U. S. 773 (1975), the Court concluded that fee schedules enforced by a state bar association were not mandated by ethical standards established by the State Supreme Court. The fee schedules therefore were not immune from antitrust attack."

"It is not enough that . . . anticompetitive conduct is 'prompted' by state action; rather, anticompetitive activities must be compelled by direction of the State acting as a sovereign."

"Id. at 421 U. S. 791."

445 U.S. at 445 U. S. 104.

[Footnote 2/13]

As in Cantor, the Court concluded in the Midcal case that the State's ostensible compulsion of the resale price maintenance program was not alone sufficient to confer state action immunity. The State neither set the prices nor reviewed their reasonableness, nor did it monitor market conditions and evaluate the effectiveness of the program. Under those conditions, the

"State simply authorizes price setting and enforces the prices set by private parties. . . . The national policy in favor of competition cannot be thwarted by casting such a gauzy cloak of state involvement over what is essentially a private price-fixing arrangement."

445 U.S. at 445 U. S. 105-106.

[Footnote 2/14]

Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U.S. at 428 U. S. 597 (quoting Silver v. New York Stock Exchange, 373 U. S. 341, 373 U. S. 357 (1963)). In United States v. National Assn. of Securities Dealers, the Court pointed out that

"[i]mplied antitrust immunity is not favored, and can be justified only by a convincing showing of clear repugnancy between antitrust laws and the regulatory system. See, e.g., United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.S. at 374 U. S. 348; United States v. Borden Co., 308 U. S. 188, 308 U. S. 197-206 (1939)."

422 U.S. at 422 U. S. 719-720; see also nn. 471 U.S. 48fn2/5|>5, 471 U.S. 48fn2/6|>6, supra. These cases are, of course, consistent with the "cardinal rule," applicable to legislation generally, that repeals by implication are not favored. Posadas v. National City Bank, 296 U. S. 497, 296 U. S. 503 (1936).

[Footnote 2/15]

"The California Agricultural Prorate Act authorizes the establishment, through action of state officials, of programs for the marketing of agricultural commodities produced in the state, so as to restrict competition among the growers and maintain prices in the distribution of their commodities to packers. The declared purpose of the Act is to 'conserve the agricultural wealth of the State' and to 'prevent economic waste in the marketing of agricultural products' of the state."

317 U.S. at 317 U. S. 346.

"The declared objective of the California Act is to prevent excessive supplies of agricultural commodities from 'adversely affecting' the market, and although the statute speaks in terms of 'economic stability' and 'agricultural waste,' rather than of price, the evident purpose and effect of the regulation is to 'conserve agricultural wealth of the state' by raising and maintaining prices, but 'without permitting unreasonable profits to producers.'"

Id. at 317 U. S. 355.

[Footnote 2/16]

See Ga.Code Ann. §§ 46-2-25(b), 46-7-18 (Supp.1984); Miss.Code Ann. §§ 77-7-217, 77-7-221 (1972); N.C.Gen.Stat. §§ 62-134(b), 62-146, 62-147 (1982); Tenn.Code Ann. §§ 65-5-203, 65-15-119 (1982).

[Footnote 2/17]

By consolidating petitions for rate modifications, collective ratemaking arguably preserves the resources of the state regulatory Commissions and promotes simplicity and uniformity in the intrastate rate structure. See App. 60-61, 83-84, 90-91. Under the statutes governing the state regulatory programs, however, the carriers may, at any time, decline to participate in collective ratemaking, and deprive the States of these purported advantages. Ante at 471 U. S. 51. That being so, it is difficult for the States to argue that these facets of their regulatory systems are essential to the program's success. Brief for State of Iowa et al. as Amici Curiae 6 ("The authorization of the price-fixing agreement, collective ratemaking, by the states serves no cognizable state interest").

The States also contend that the defendants provide a valuable information-gathering service for motor carriers. App. 60-61, 84, 90. The District Court's final judgment, however, would not have interfered with this function. Id. at 99 ("Each defendant may provide statistical and other economic data and advice to any carrier wishing to avail itself of defendants' expertise").

[Footnote 2/18]

See 471 U.S. 48fn2/8|>n. 8, supra.

[Footnote 2/19]

Under the exemption, as amended, the ratemaking conferences, among other things, must disclose the names of their members and affiliates of their members, 49 U.S.C. § 10706(b)(3)(A); the organization must limit discussion and voting to allowed subjects and parties, § 10706(b)(3)(B)(i);

"the organization may not file a protest or complaint with the Commission against any tariff item published by or for the account of any motor carrier,"

§ 10706(b)(3)(B)(iii);

"the organization may not permit one of its employees or any employee committee to docket or act upon any proposal effecting a change in any tariff item,"

§ 10706(b)(3)(B)(iv);

"upon request, the organization must divulge to any person the name of the proponent of a rule or rate docketed with it, must admit any person to any meeting at which rates or rules will be discussed or voted upon, and must divulge to any person the vote cast by any member carrier on any proposal before the organization,"

§ 10706(b)(3)(B)(v); and the organization shall make a final disposition of rate proposals within 120 days, § 10706(b)(3)(B)(vii). See generally ICC v. American Trucking Assn., Inc., 467 U. S. 354 (1984).

[Footnote 2/20]

In the legislative history of the 1980 Motor Carrier Act, however, Congress suggested otherwise:

"During the course of its hearings, the Committee heard a good deal of criticism of the rate bureau process. . . . The disadvantage is that the system inherently tends to result in rates that will be compensatory for even the least efficient motor carrier participating in the rate discussions. When this happens, consumers lose the benefit of price competition that would occur if more efficient carriers were able to offer more attractive rates. Another serious problem has been the closed nature of the rate bureau proceedings. Voting upon specific rate proposals is done behind closed doors."

S.Rep. No. 96-641, p. 13 (1980). See also H.R.Rep. No. 96-1069, p. 27 (1980).

[Footnote 2/21]

"It has been held too often to require elaboration now that price-fixing is contrary to the policy of competition underlying the Sherman Act, and that its illegality does not depend on a showing of unreasonableness, since it is conclusively presumed to be unreasonable."

United States v. McKesson & Robbins, Inc., 351 U.S. at 351 U. S. 309-310.

[Footnote 2/22]

The Court of Appeals, however, found that the State Commissions' scrutiny of the reasonableness of proposed rates satisfies the active supervision requirement. 702 F.2d 532, 539, n. 12 (CA5, Unit B, now CA11, 1983) (en banc).

[Footnote 2/23]

Some of the States' statutes and implementing regulations indicate that the process of collective ratemaking is being supervised on a limited basis. See, e.g., N.C.Gen.Stat. § 62-152.1(c) (1982); Ga.Pub.Serv.Comm'n Rule 1-3-1-.14 (1983); Tenn.Pub.Serv.Comm'n Rule 1220-2-1-.40 (1974).

[Footnote 2/24]

Since the Court does not reach it, ante at 471 U. S. 53, n. 11, 471 U. S. 55, n. 17, I do not address the merits of the Noerr-Pennington question. See Mine Workers v. Pennington, 381 U. S. 657 (1965); Eastern Railroad Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U. S. 127 (1961).